Nexus between fiscal deficit and economic growth in India--an empirical investigation.
Kaur, Gurleen ; Ahmed, Neetu
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Introduction
Fiscal policy of a country is intimately linked with overall
economic strategy and also feeds into economic trends and consequently
influences the monetary policy. When the government's receipts are
greater than its spending, it has a surplus. If the government spends
more than it receives it runs a deficit. To meet the additional
expenditures, it needs to borrow from domestic or foreign sources, draw
upon its foreign exchange reserves or print an equivalent amount of
money. This tends to influence other economic variables. Basic economic
knowledge regards inflation as a by product of excessive printing of
money. If the government borrows too much from abroad it leads to a debt
crisis. If it draws down on its foreign exchange reserves, a balance of
payments crisis may arise. Excessive domestic borrowing by the
government may lead to higher real interest rates and the domestic
private sector being unable to access funds resulting in the
'crowding out' of private investment. Sometimes a combination
of these can occur. In any case, the impact of a large deficit on long
run growth and economic well-being is negative. Therefore, there is
broad agreement that it is not prudent for a government to run an unduly
large deficit. However, in case of developing countries, where the need
for infrastructure and social investments may be substantial, it is
sometimes argued that running surpluses at the cost of long-term growth
might also not be wise (Fischer and Easterly, 1990). The challenge then
for most developing country governments is to meet infrastructure and
social needs while managing the government's finances in a way that
the deficit or the accumulating debt burden is not too great.
The Indian economy has tripled in size over the last decade. Its
GDP growth, savings and investment rates have reached historic highs,
and now far exceed the average rates for emerging markets. Yet, the
general government's budget deficit ratio is close to levels of a
decade ago, and far higher than that of similarly rated countries.
Indian union budget of 2012 came out with the most significant
macroeconomic challenge with a fiscal deficit of 5.9 percent which is
significantly higher than 4.6 percent fiscal deficit of 2011. A 1.3
percent increase in fiscal deficit is very high. In simple language it
means, the amount of money the government is spending compared to what
it is collecting has gone up to a gap of 5.9 percent of the total. This
will put significant pressure on the Government of India, as it will
have to borrow this amount in the markets, resulting in further
worsening of the debt scenario.
High fiscal deficits typically cause three problems--a balance of
payments crisis, high interest rates (because of crowding out) and high
inflation (with currency depreciation being a key contributor). India
suffered all three problems in 1991. The fiscal policy of 2012-13 has
been calibrated with two fold objectives - first, to aid economy in
growth revival; and second, to bring down the deficit from 2011-12 level
so as to leave space for private sector credit as the investment cycle
picks up.
Now, fiscal deficits of even 5 percent of GDP have bankrupted
countries like Argentina. How does India survive, indeed thrive? In the
light of the worrisome account of the Indian economy, stated above, the
objective of this paper is to examine the long--term relationship
between fiscal deficit and economic performance of the Indian economy
during the period 1971-72 to 2010-11 .The impact of debt and fiscal
deficit on growth that arises from their effect on saving and investment
are critical in examination of sustainability of debt and deficit.
(Rangarajan and Srivastava, 2004) The present paper therefore considers
a Log Linear regression model with the natural logarithmic of real GDP
(at factor cost) as the dependent variable, and the natural logarithms
of the explanatory variables viz., Gross fiscal deficit (henceforth
GFD), Gross domestic capital formation (henceforth GDCF) and Gross
domestic savings (henceforth GDS).
This paper is organized in five sections: The first section is the
introduction, while second section summarizes the theoretical debate on
the relationship between fiscal deficit, investment and growth. The
third section discusses the trends in the fiscal deficits and the
variables taken in the Indian context while the empirical analysis of
India's case is provided in the fourth section with an
interpretation of the results. Finally, the fifth section contains the
conclusion and recommendations.
Literature Review
At the outset, it is important to clarify certain basic concepts.
There are various ways to represent and interpret a government's
deficit. The simplest is the revenue deficit which is just the
difference between revenue receipts and revenue expenditures.
Revenue Deficit = Revenue Expenditure--Revenue Receipts (that is
Tax + Non-tax Revenue (i)
A more comprehensive indicator of the government's deficit is
the fiscal deficit. This is the sum of revenue and capital expenditure
less all revenue and capital receipts other than loans taken. This gives
a more holistic view of the government's funding situation since it
gives the difference between all receipts and expenditures other than
loans taken to meet such expenditures.
Fiscal Deficit = Total Expenditure (that is Revenue Expenditure +
Capital Expenditure)--(Revenue Receipts + Recoveries of Loans + Other
Capital Receipts (that is all Revenue and Capital Receipts other than
loans taken)). (ii)
"The gross fiscal deficit (GFD) of government is the excess of
its total expenditure, current and capital, including loans net of
recovery, over revenue receipts (including external grants) and non-debt
capital receipts." The net fiscal deficit is the gross fiscal
deficit reduced by net lending by government. The gross primary deficit
is the GFD less interest payments while the primary revenue deficit is
the revenue deficit less interest payments.
The governments of the world are tackling the fiscal deficit on a
war footing. The review of literature puts forward the following
contrasting viewpoints in understanding the relationship between fiscal
deficit and macroeconomic variables.
* The Keynesian Theory
Through the resulting increase in the aggregate demand, budget
deficit has a positive effect on macroeconomic activity, thereby
stimulating savings and capital formation. Increase in government
spending in an economy operating at less than full employment level,
stimulates the domestic economic activity by a greater proportion
(thought the multiplier process) and thereby crowds in private
investment. Thus the Keynesians advocate complementary relationship
between public spending and private investment only if the public sector
investment is in infrastructure, education and health that involve large
fixed costs and long gestation period. (Hussain et. Al., 2009)
* The Monetarist Theory
The neoclassical economists argue that financing of an extravagant
fiscal deficit through public borrowing can cause the interest rates to
increase and consequently Crowd out private investments. Thus, an
increase in the size of public sector spending would be at the expense
of the private sector and can adversely affect economic
growth.(Chakraborty and Chakraborty, 2006).
* The Ricardian Equivalence Theory
In particular, this theory implies that collectively the tax cuts
and spending increases financed by increasing government debt will not
have an impact on the economy. The implication of the Ricardian
Equivalence Hypothesis states that interest rates and consumption will
be unaffected by debt-financed government spending. Argued thus, fiscal
deficits will not have much impact on aggregate demand if household
spending decisions are based on the present value of their incomes that
takes into account the present value of their future tax liabilities
(Rangarajan and Srivastava, 2005)
* The 'Tax and Spend' Hypothesis
A fourth hypothesis formalised by supply side economists, is
sometimes called the "tax and spend" hypothesis. According to
which, raising taxes with a view to cutting down deficits would not work
because it would only encourage the politicians to spend more. The
result would be that while the deficit would remain the same, in the
long run the size of the private sector would be cut down. Therefore, a
tax cut, which puts pressure for contraction of government spending
leaving deficits and national savings unchanged, and which leads to an
increase in private consumption, should be considered more desirable.
While the above theoretical perspectives provide a valuable insight
for understanding the said relationship, in order to arrive at
meaningful conclusions it is important to demarcate these
interrelationships especially in the context of India. In doing so, it
becomes necessary to address the efficacy of fiscal activism in India so
as to resolve macroeconomic challenges and pave way for real growth in
the economy.
As far as Indian case is concerned, the issues pertaining to fiscal
sustainability gathered momentum only during late 1980s which marked the
beginning of the much talked about economic crisis of 1991 caused to a
greater extent because of sharp fiscal deterioration. Thus, a large body
of literature has emerged on the subject. Also, it is pertinent to note
that apart from the contributions from the individual researchers, there
has also been substantial research work contributed by the Reserve Bank
of India on the subject.
For developing countries, empirical work on budget deficits and the
macro economy has been confined largely to issues such as deficit
measurement problems in the case of Tanzania, budget deficit adjustment
problems in the case of Egypt, and the political consequences of
deficits. One paper that deserves special mention is that of V. K. R. V.
Rao. He demonstrates that the inflationary impact of government budget
deficits in developing countries depends on a set of prevailing
conditions in the economy. Important among these are the government
policies toward public investment. For example, in his model, budget
deficits resulting from greater spending on development projects will
expand the economy from the supply side and will be less inflationary
than deficits arising from increased expenditures on public consumption.
The link between fiscal deficit and growth, saving and investment
rates, inflation and current account deficits have also been examined in
many studies. The relationship between the fiscal deficit and interest
rate and the existence of crowding out are important considerations in
determining the advisability of deficit--financed expansionary fiscal
policies. Authors like Sunderarajan and Thakur (1980) and Parker (1995)
had earlier examined the issue of crowding out in the Indian context.
The Reserve Bank of India (RBI) has done significant research on
the role of fiscal policy in reviving the Indian economy (RBI 2001).
Research shows that an attempt to raise public consumption to revive
aggregate demand will crowd out both private consumption and private
investment with no long-run positive impact on output growth. More
recently, Chakraborty (2002) finds that the fiscal deficit does not put
upward pressure on the interest rate while Goyal (2004), using monthly
data argues that there is a two-way causality between fiscal deficit and
interest rates.
A number of studies have tested sustainability of public debt in
India (Buiter and Patel, 1997; Joshi and Little, 1996) and there is
overwhelming evidence that solvency of government debt cannot be taken
for granted. Thus the goal should be to stabilize or reduce the debt to
GDP ratio for which generating primary fiscal surplus would be crucial
(Rangarajan and Srivastava, 2004). They observed an adverse impact of
large structural primary deficits and interest payments on growth in
recent years.
In the context of growth, fiscal adjustment needs to be tailored to
reverse the declining trend in infrastructure investment and basic
social services and to improve the productivity of the resource used in
public sector. These measures will not only are beneficial for promoting
growth in the long run but would also be critical in ensuring the fiscal
health of the government.
Another remarkable study by Bhattacharya (2009) advocates that
higher fiscal deficit need not necessarily lead to increase in interest
rates. This happens per se since higher government expenditure leads to
higher income and hence higher savings. Ultimately the supply of credit
increases by exactly the same amount as its demand due to higher
government expenditure and so there is no reason for the price of credit
to increase.
Kumar and Soumya (2010) analysed post crisis relationship between
the fiscal deficit and economic growth. They attempted to understand
India's current fiscal situation, its likely future development,
and its impact on the economy in the context of a weak global recovery
from the current crisis. They assert that the impact of the global
crisis has been transmitted to the Indian economy through three distinct
channels, namely: the financial sector, exports, and exchange rates. The
other significant channel of impact is the slump in business and
consumer confidence leading to decrease in investment and consumption
demand. The paper provides a long-term forecast of the fiscal deficit
and public debt burden based on the past trends and suggest a set of
policy measures to get the Indian economy back on the path of sustained
rapid and inclusive growth.
Examining the relevant literature does not provide conclusive
evidence for the relationship between growth rates, fiscal deficit and
growth of savings and investment. Hence, the present study aims at
investigating the nexus between these variables so as to explore the
future policy implications of the same. Finally, a set of policy
measures are discussed which can bring the economy back to the path of
fiscal consolidation coupled with rapid and sustained economic growth.
Fiscal Deficit, Savings and Investment: Recent Trends in India
Before attempting to perform an empirical investigation, it is
essential to sneak a look into the trends in these variables in the
context of our economy.
The deficit of the centre has generally been on a downward trend
since 1986-87, but with a stop-go pattern. It went down gradually from
9.4 per cent of GDP in 1986-87 to 7.8 per cent in 1989-90, before
bouncing back to 8.3 per cent in the crisis year of 1990-91. The
stabilisation and reform initiative launched by the central government
in 1991 achieved a fair degree of success in reducing the deficit from
8.3 per cent of GDP to 5.9 per cent in 1991- 92 and further to 5.7
percent in 1992-93. But, thereafter, the fiscal consolidation of the
central government has again been characterised by an irregular pattern.
The deficit jumped back to 7.4 per cent in 1993-94, before declining in
steps to 6.0 per cent, 5.4 per cent and 4.9 per cent in the three
subsequent years.
The growth rate of fiscal deficit shows a declining trend since
1991 indicating the intention of the government to put a cap on the high
fiscal deficit. However, exceptional domestic or global pressures sway
away the government from its motive. This can be observed for the years
2008-09 and 2009-10 when government had to provide many incentives to
the industry to help them cope up with the global recessionary scenario.
Due to tight control over its expenses and implementation of FRBM Act,
the Indian government was able to bring down fiscal deficit to as low as
2.55 percent in 2007-08 but then the global recession took its toll. It
is clearly observed that during years of low fiscal deficit, the economy
was able to achieve a growth rate of GDP as high as 9.34 percent in
2007-08 before declining sharply to 6.76 percent in 2008-09. The
direction of change in the real GDP and other macroeconomic variables
under consideration (in absolute terms), during the period under review
can be seen from the following table.
Further analysis shows that the trend is not without exceptions.
The fiscal deficit fell sharply from 7.84 per cent in 1990-91 to 5.55
per cent in 1991-92. However, this does not correspond with an increase
in GDP. Rather, the GDP growth rate fell sharply from 5.29 per cent in
1990-91 to 1.43 per cent in 1991-92. This corresponds with the time when
Indian economy faced its perhaps toughest test till date and the
decision to liberalise the economy was taken. A similar exceptional
scenario is observed during 2001-02 and 2002-03 when in spite of fiscal
deficit falling from 6.1 9 per cent to 5.91 per cent, GDP growth rate
fell from 5.84 per cent to 3.84 per cent. With the exception of the year
2008-9 when the growth rate was 6.8 percent, the growth in real GDP in
2011-12 has been the lowest in nine years.
It may also be observed from Table I that the economy registered
high growth in gross capital formation during 2005-06 to 2007-08. As a
result, there was rapid increase in investment rate in the economy I
from 32.8 per cent in 2004-5 to 38.1 percent in 2007-08. The level of
investment declined in absolute terms in 2008-09 (Refer Table I)
following the slowdown in the global economy. Though it did recover
quickly in 2009-10 and 2010-11, the growth in gross (capital formation,
particularly fixed capital formation, has been substantially lower than
the growth that had been achieved in 2005-06 to 2007-08.
Methodology and Empirical Analysis
To probe the relationship between fiscal deficit, savings and
investment with the GDP, this paper analyses the Indian economy data
from 1971-72 to 2010-11. The data pertaining to GDP at factor cost (Base
2004-05 prices), fiscal deficit, Gross domestic Capital formation (Base
2004-05 prices), and Gross domestic savings (Base 2004-05) prices are
extracted from the Handbook of Statistics on Indian Economy 2010-11(RBI)
for the period of analysis.
A Log-lin regression model (log-log in this case) having the
natural log of GDP at factor cost as the dependent variable
(regressand), and natural logarithms of the variables of the explanatory
variables viz; Gross fiscal deficit (henceforth GFD), Gross domestic
capital formation (henceforth GDCF) and Gross domestic savings
(henceforth GDS) is considered for the present study.
Ln [GDP.sub.t] = f (Ln Comb.[GFD.sub.t], Ln [GDCF.sup.t], Ln
[GDS.sub.t],)
Where:
Ln Comb.GFD= Logarithm of combined gross fiscal deficit of the
central and state government at current market prices for period t
Ln GDS= Logarithm of gross domestic savings at current market
prices for period t
Ln GDCF= Logarithm of gross domestic capital formation current
market prices for period t
This relation can be expressed as the following:
Ln [GDP.sub.t], = Ln [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] Ln
Comb.[GFD.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.2] Ln [GDCF.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.3] Ln
[GDS.sub.t] + [[mu].sub.t] (iii)
In the double log model where the regressand is logarithmic and the
regressor X is time, if an independent variable change by 1 percent, on
average, the GDP changes by the magnitude of the slope coefficient of
the independent variable. The econometric time series analysis of the
said variables is done using E-views 7 as the aide. For this analysis
the study employs recent time-series econometric methods like- The ADF
unit root test for stationarity. In addition, since time-series data is
vulnerable to the problem of auto-correlation, hence, Durbin Watson test
has been undertaken for the same. Finally, the causality between two or
more time series variables is explored using the standard Granger-
causality tests.
The Durbin Watson test for autocorrelation indicates the evidence
of positive autocorrelation at 5 percent level of significance. Also the
series are non-stationary, hence ADF test has been undertaken and it is
observed that the model exhibits stationarity after taking 1 st
difference with an intercept and trend in case of Unit root testing.
The results of the regression post model correction (Table II) show
that at the 5percent level of significance, the coefficients of the
intercept, LnGDCF and LnGDS are statistically significant and there is
an absence of serial correlation. Table II further shows that fiscal
deficits had a negative, though insignificant impact on the growth of
the real GDP. This is contrary to Keynesian theory, but in conformity
with Monetarist theory, which holds that fiscal deficits lead to a fall
in the Gross Domestic Product. However, given the statistical
insignificance of this relationship, fiscal deficits of the central
government in India exhibit Ricardian equivalence. A Granger-causality
analysis has been carried out (see Table III) in order to assess whether
there is any potential predictability power of Gross fiscal deficit
& GDP for each other. The conclusion that can be drawn is that there
exists no causality between these variables hence both of them are
independent.
Also, contrary to the expectation, GDCF exerted a negative but
significant influence on the growth of the real GDP. This suggests that
repatriation of profits made within the Indian economy back to the home
countries of the investors may have created significant leakages from
the economy.
Conclusion and Recommendations
Although fiscal deficits have been recurrent in the Indian economy
ever since 1970s, there have been relatively insignificant improvements
in the growth of the economy. The study observes that recurrent fiscal
deficits led to an accumulation of debt, which at maturity, drained from
the economy the financial resources that were required for development.
Fiscal deficits were shown empirically to be inversely related to the
growth of the real GDP. However, the study concludes that the
demonstrated statistical insignificance show that the fiscal deficits in
the Indian economy correspond to the Ricardian Equivalence Theory. Thus,
as such, fiscal deficits have little influence on the level of economic
activity.
Therefore, it can be said that the present anxiety in India about
the rising fiscal deficit is justified. Given that high deficits have an
adverse impact on India's growth, it is imperative that the
government chalks out a clear roadmap to reduce fiscal deficits if it
wants the economy to return to 9 per cent growth path. What needs to be
done is restructuring of public expenditure. Merely meeting targets
stipulated in the FRBM Act through clever accounting practices such as
the transfer of massive subsidies to oil marketing and fertiliser
companies as off budget items will not do. Neither will measures like
divestment to finance the fiscal deficit.
The study, therefore, recommends that where fiscal deficits are
necessary for correcting short-term fluctuations in the economy, the
resources so acquired should be invested in self-liquidating and
profitable ventures. Of important note in this regard are investments in
infrastructure such as power and roads, the provision of which by
private firms constitute a large proportion of their production costs.
Furthermore, curbing corruption will help to reduce fiscal deficits and
improve the performance of government budgets, as budgets are inflated
by corrupt officials for private gains.
This conclusion brings us to the hotly debated subject of
corruption and Governance reforms. Hence, what India needs now is not
the crisis oriented reforms of 1991 sort, but development driven reforms
that will not only put the economy to a high growth trajectory but also
take care of the "Inclusive Growth" which was the vision of
the XI five year plan that concluded in March 2012; it indeed continues
to be the vision of the XII five year plan as well.
References
Acharya, S. (2002). Macroeconomic management in the 1990s. Economic
and Political Weekly, 37(16), 15151538.
Bhattacharya, J. (2009). Fiscal deficit and interest rate. Economic
and Political Weekly, 44(22), 20-22.
Buiter, W.H., & U.R. Patel. (1992). Debt, deficits and
inflation: An application to the public finances of India. Journal of
Public Economics, 47, 172- 305.
Chakraborty, P., & L. S. Chakraborty. (2006). Is fiscal policy
contracyclical in India: An empirical analysis. Munich Personal RePEc
Archive- MPRA Paper No. 7604.
Chakraborty, L. (2006). Fiscal deficit, Capital formation and
Crowding Out: Evidence from India, NIPFP Working Paper 06/43.
Economic Survey, (2011-2012). Ministry of finance, Government of
India. Also available at http://www.indiabudget.nic.in/survey.asp
Fischer, S., & William, Easterly. (1990). The economics of the
government budget constraint. The World Bank Research Observer, 5(2),
127-42.
Gadong, D. T. (2010). Fiscal deficit and the growth of domestic
output in Nigeria. JOS Journal of Economics, 4(1), 154-175.
Hussain, A. Mohd. et al. (2009). Effectiveness of government
expenditure Crowding-in or Crowding- out: An empirical evidence in case
of Pakistan. European Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative
Sciences, 16, 141-147.
Joshi, V., & I.M.D. Little. (1994). India: Macroeconomics and
Political Economy: 1964-91, World Bank Comparative Economic Studies,
World Bank Publications, Washington, DC.
Kumar, R., & D. Soumya, A. (2010). Fiscal Policy Issues for
India after the Global Financial Crisis (2008-10). ADBI Working Paper,
249.
Mehra, Y, & Kaur, K. (2012). Economic growth and the challenges
of fiscal deficit. Journal of Business Thought, 3, 84-94.
Mohan, R. (2000). Fiscal correction for economic growth: Data
analysis and suggestions. Economic and Political Weekly, 35(24),
2027-36.
Raju, S., & J. Mukherjee. (2010). Fiscal Deficit, crowding out
and the sustainability of economic growth: The case of Indian economy.
IFRI, Europe.
Rangarajan.C., & D.K. Srivasta. (2004). Fiscal Deficits and
Government Debt in India: Implications for Growth and Stabilisation,
NIPFP Working paper 05/35, New Delhi, India.
Reserve Bank of India (2001). The Role of Fiscal Policy in
Reinvigorating Growth. Report on Currency and Finance 2000-2001. Mumbai,
India.
Reserve Bank of India (2011). Handbook of Statistics of the Indian
Economy, 2010-11, RBI, Mumbai.
Gurleen Kaur
Assistant Professor
Sri Gru Gobind Singh College of
Commerce,
University of Delhi, New Delhi.
Neetu Ahmed
Assistant Professor,
J K Business School, Gurgaon.
Table-I
GDP, GFD, GDS and GDCF of Government of India
during 1971-72 to 2010-11
Year GDP * GFD GDS GDCF
1971-72 595726 1727 7666 126468
1972-73 593828 2179 8200 125952
1973-74 620855 1733 11489 149597
1974-75 628063 2302 12949 134188
1975-76 684616 3029 14947 139028
1976-77 693173 3802 18236 157740
1977-78 744953 3680 21053 174056
1978-79 785945 5710 24849 210456
1979-80 745064 6392 25494 190094
1980-81 798486 8299 28303 200766
1981-82 843405 8666 32530 193348
1982-83 868069 10627 35574 193029
1983-84 936245 13030 40106 202803
1984-85 973332 17416 47857 218923
1985-86 1013839 21858 56213 240004
1986-87 1057585 26342 61106 241318
1987-88 1094964 27044 76087 275168
1988-89 1206212 30923 91777 313399
1989-90 1280195 35632 111704 334830
1990-91 1347855 44632 136888 391012
1991-92 1367136 36325 148553 329987
1992-93 1440467 40173 168129 361562
1993-94 1522305 60257 199980 383898
1994-95 1619652 57703 260553 468320
1995-96 1737696 60243 306396 504017
1996-97 1876271 66733 329629 501493
1997-98 1956982 88937 382735 562331
1998-99 2087774 113349 410365 563011
1999-00 2222258 104716 509873 678807
2000-01 2319004 118816 525432 655227
2001-02 2453725 140955 563180 636174
2002-03 2547863 145072 680722 742901
2003-04 2764889 123273 864099 873370
2004-05 2971464 125794 1050703 1064041
2005-06 3254216 146435 1235288 1237137
2006-07 3566011 142573 1486044 1402637
2007-08 3898958 126912 1837498 1658001
2008-09 4162509 336992 1798347 1565007
2009-10 4493743 418482 2207423 1858659
2010-11 4877482 373591 2481931 1974172
* GDP (at factor cost, constant prices) with base year 2004-2005
Note: All figures are in crores of rupees and GFD is the Gross
fiscal deficit for the central government.
Source: Handbook of Statistics on Indian Economy 201 0-11, RBI.
TABLE-II
Estimated Results
Dependent Variable: LNGDP
Method: Least Squares
Included observations: 39 after adjustments
Variable Coefficient Std. Error
LNGFD -0.013012 0.022893
LNGDCF -0.875809 0.371385
LNGDS 0.856171 0.362259
C 0.049852 0.005927
R-squared 0.151673 Mean dependent var
Adjusted R-squared 0.078959 S.D. dependent var
S.E. of regression 0.028962 Akaike info criterion
Sum squared resid 0.029357 Schwarz criterion
Log likelihood 84.90119 Hannan-Quinn criter.
F-statistic 2.085885 Durbin-Watson stat
Prob(F-statistic) 0.119802
Variable t-Statistic Prob.
LNGFD -0.568366 0.5734
LNGDCF -2.358227 0.0241
LNGDS 2.363418 0.0238
C 8.410860 0.0000
R-squared 0.052069
Adjusted R-squared 0.030177
S.E. of regression -4.148779
Sum squared resid -3.9781 57
Log likelihood -4.087561
F-statistic 2.290761
Prob(F-statistic)
TABLE-III
Pair wise Granger Causality Tests
Lags: 2
Null Hypothesis: Observations F-Statistic Prob.
LNGFD does not 37 1.19544 0.3157
Granger Cause LNGDP
LNGDP does not 0.09608 0.9087
Granger Cause LNGFD