The use of the HIV test: a conflict choice approach.
Broyles, Robert W. ; Mwachofi, Ari ; Khaliq, Amir A. 等
INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND
Approximately 1.5 million Americans have been infected with HIV
since 1981 and 950,000 are currently living with HIV/AIDS. CDC estimates
that from 2003 to 2007 there were 1,051,875 people living with AIDS in
the US. CDC also reports that from 2004-2007, HIV diagnoses increased
15% in the 34 states (Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, 2009).
Although improvements in the treatment of the disease have lowered
mortality, HIV remains the fifth leading cause of death among Americans
between the ages of 25 and 44.
Previous research focused on variation in the quality of care
provided to infected individuals, the sources of financing care,
treatment protocols, patient compliance and the presence of coexisting
conditions (CDC, 2004; Cohen, Berk, et al, 2001; Kilbourne, Anderson,
Asch et al, 2002; Goldman, Leibowitz, Joyce et al, 2003; Dobalian, Tsao
& Duncan, 2004; Landon, Wilson, Cohn et al, 2003; Landon, Wilson,
Wenger et al, 2002; London, Wilson, Wenger et al, 2002; Hsiao, Wond,
Kanouse et al, 2003; McInnes, Malitz et al, 2004; Doblian, Anderson
& Stein, 2003; Tucker, Burnam & Sherbourne, 2003). Other studies
document delays in HIV diagnoses resulting in missed opportunities for
early treatment (Sherbourne, Fprge, & Kung, 2005). Although multiple
dimensions of the epidemic have been explored, the distribution of
diagnostic procedures or HIV tests relative to differential risk has not
been explored using multivariate techniques.
The distribution of diagnostic procedures is appropriate if those
who are at greatest risk make greater use of tests. Conversely, if the
distribution of HIV tests is inconsistent with differential risk,
utilization patterns might be improved by modifying interventions
designed to prevent transmission of the virus.
Of particular importance to this study is the finding that
approximately one-third of those infected in the U.S. are unaware of
their HIV infection (U.S. Census Bureau, 2003). For instance revised
estimate indicate that 232,700 persons in the US were living with
undiagnosed HIV infection at the end of 2006 (CDC, 2008). Since no cure
for HIV/AIDS exists, prevention is a critical factor in controlling the
epidemic. Previous research indicates the likelihood that those who test
positively modify their behavior to reduce transmitting the disease
(CDC, 2008; CDC 2003).
THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
A number of models are used to explain the demand for health
services and decisions to consume preventive or early detection
services. The Theory of Consumer Behavior (TCB), the Investment Theory
of Demand (ITD), and the Health Belief Model (HBM) are among the most
prominent of these approaches. The TCB is frequently adopted as a frame
of reference to examine factors that influence the use of health
services. The ITD posits that the demand for health care is derived from
a demand for health. The theory employs the neo-classical framework of
reference to explain consumer behavior and the health production
function. The HBM focuses on perceived susceptibility, severity,
benefits and barriers as the primary determinants of health care
utilization.
As summarized below, the, TCB, the ITD, and the HBM are separate
models that employ different conceptual frames of reference to study
demand and use of health care. This paper integrates the three
approaches into a single model that might be applied to a wide spectrum
of health behavior and use of services.
The Basic Models
The TCB assumes that the individual is limited by a budget
constraint and purchases the mix of services that maximize a defined
utility function. The individual also is presumed to possess perfect
information concerning available goods or services and the increment in
utility associated with the consumption of an additional unit of each.
In the following, let MUi represent the marginal utility or increment in
satisfaction derived from consuming an additional unit of good or
service i and [P.sub.i] represent the corresponding price for i = 1, ...
n. Subject to the constraint imposed by a constant nominal income, M, It
can be shown that utility or satisfaction is maximized when
[MU.sub.1]/[P.sub.1] = ... = MUi/[P.sub.i] = ... =
[MU.sub.n]/[P.sub.n]
If markets are competitive and health care is a normal good or
service, the model indicates that an increase in income or decline in
price results in an increase in demand and a greater use of services.
The TCB predicts that, other factors remaining constant, a decline in
income or increase in price will result in a reduction in utilization.
Conversely, the model suggests that an increase in income or a decline
in price will stimulate demand or utilization.
The ITD posits that the demand for health care is derived from a
demand for health. Therefore the focus of the model is on disease
prevention or health promotion. The ITD regards health as a capital
asset that depreciates with the passage of time. As such, health
promoting activities are viewed as an investment in health.
The benefits that are derived from health are of two types, namely
consumption and production benefits. The consumption benefits of health
consist of physical well-being and an enhanced ability to enjoy daily
life. The production benefits are related to the ability to perform
economic and social functions. The production benefits are measured in
terms of income, suggesting that improved health enables the individual
to avoid loss of income due to illness.
The ITD assumes that the health production function exhibits
diminishing marginal returns of health inputs to health, suggesting that
the function rises from left to right at a decreasing rate.
The HBM focuses on the influence of
1. perceived susceptibility (i.e. perceptions concerning the
likelihood that the individual will contract a condition);
2. perceived severity of the condition;
3. perceived benefits of the preventive or early detection services
and
4. perceived barriers to the use of early detection or preventive
services
on health behavior. The model posits that the likelihood of using
early detection or preventive services increases if the barriers to use
decline. The barriers that are commonly cited in this context are higher
prices, lower incomes and a lack of access to care including the lack of
insurance. Similarly, the likelihood of using services increases as the
susceptibility to the condition, perceived severity of the condition and
potential benefits of use grow.
The Integrated Conflict Choice Model
As indicated, this paper relies on the integration of the TCB, the
ITD and the HBM into a single analytic frame of reference. The conflict
choice model employs as the unit of analysis the episode of care which
consists of two phases. The first is the patient initiated phase while
the second is defined as the physician or provider dominated phase.
The model proposed in this paper is limited to the patient
initiated phase and is based on the proposition that the TCB, the ITD
and the HBM collectively form the basis for the individual's
decision to seek health care. Further, the conflict choice approach
assumes that the patient initiated phase is dominated by two undesirable
choices or options. Unlike the TCB, the conflict choice model contends
that the consumption of medical services results in no direct utility or
satisfaction. Rather, the use of health care usually results in
discomfort or disutility, a feature that motivates the individual to
avoid the use of service. Accordingly, it is reasonable to assume that
the typical patient may choose to avoid using health care.
Similarly, the conflict choice model assumes that a rational
individual also prefers to avoid the disutility of illness and the
potential decline in the production function that might occur if health
care is not sought. Therefore, health care is sought to avoid the
disutility of illness and to derive an improvement in health and related
health benefits. Consequently, the individual may choose the discomfort
of illness that may accompany a decision to avoid care seeking behavior.
The integrated conflict-choice model is shown in Figure 1. The
vertical axes measure the strength of the individual's tendency to
avoid the negative consequences of seeking care (Choice A) and the
strength of the individual's tendency to avoid the disutility of
illness (Choice B) that may accompany a decision to avoid care seeking.
Shown on the lower horizontal axis is the probability that the
individual will select Choice B. In this case, the subject avoids care
seeking, an outcome that results in the risk of illness and the
potential decline in the benefits of health. The upper horizontal axis
measures the probability 1 - P(B) or P(A), the likelihood that the
individual will adopt Choice A, seek care and endure the disutility of
use.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
As indicated, the model presented in this paper assumes that the
avoidance gradients are linear. However, it is also possible that the
gradients are non-linear and rise exponentially as the individual
approaches Choice A or Choice B. Although not estimated in this paper,
it is possible to argue further that the shape or the slope of the
avoidance gradient is related to the deleterious consequences that might
occur if one of the choices is selected. For example, it is reasonable
to suppose that the slope of the gradient increases as the adverse
consequence resulting from adopting one of the choices grows.
The subject's perception of the outcome of the conflict choice
situation is measured by a subjective probability. As is well known,
subjective probabilities are applied to an event or outcome that is
unique or occurs once. Subjective probability is directly related to the
strength of the individual's belief concerning the occurrence or
nonoccurrence of the outcome in the conflict choice model.
Specifically, if the individual is prepared to offer odds of H: J
that an event or outcome will occur, the corresponding objective
probability is expressed in the form H/(H + J). For purposes of
presentation, the probability that the individual will endure the
discomfort resulting from health care or suffer a loss in the benefits
of health is measured objectively.
Consider first a situation of disequilibrium and assume the
individual assigns a probability of P(B') to the likelihood of
adopting option B and correspondingly a probability of 1- P(B') or
P(A') of selecting choice A. As indicated, the strength of the
individual's tendency to avoid choice A is measured by line segment
ac while the strength of the tendency to avoid B is represented by line
segment bc. Since line segment ac exceeds line segment bc, the
individual is influenced by a net tendency to increase the likelihood of
selecting choice B and to reduce the probability of adopting option A,
an outcome that results in a behavioral equilibrium characterized by the
probabilities P(B) and 1-P(B).
As indicated in Figure 2, a change in the position of the avoidance
gradient A alters the location of behavioral equilibrium and related
probabilities. Specifically, a shift in the avoidance gradient A from A
to A' reduces the tendency of the individual to avoid the selection
of Choice A, thereby increasing the probability that the subject will
seek service and endure the disutility of use.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Consistent with the HBM and the TCB, a decline in the barriers to
use such as a reduction in effective price, distance traveled to the
source of care or an increase in income is expected to lower the
avoidance gradient from A to A'. Similarly, consistent with the
ITD, an improvement in medical technology and related change in the
health production function is expected to increase the perceived
benefits of health and thereby lower the avoidance gradient from A to
A'. Hence, the analysis suggests that a decline in the effective
price, improved access to care, advances in medical technology and the
resulting improvement in perceived benefits increase the likelihood that
the individual will select option A, elect to use early detection or
preventive service and endure the disutility of use.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
As indicated in Figure 3 a change in the position of avoidance
gradient B from B to B' also increases the likelihood that the
individual will select Choice A. It is possible to argue that perceived
susceptibility and severity co-vary positively with the disutility of
illness and the expected magnitude of foregone benefits derived from
health. Hence, the model suggests that an increase in the perceived
severity of illness or susceptibility results in an increase in the
individual's propensity to avoid the disutility of illness and the
foregone benefits of health. For example, if the a priori likelihood of
illness increases from 2:1 to 4:1 and the perception of severity grows
from a significant disability to potential death, the avoidance gradient
B shifts upward and the likelihood the individual will use a preventive
or early detection service will increase.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Assume that the objective of policy deliberations is to develop and
implement options that stimulate the use of preventive or early
detection services. Referring to Figure 4, suppose further that the
elimination of barriers to care or an improvement in the benefits of
service lowers avoidance gradient A from A to A'. Similarly, assume
that perceived susceptibility and severity increases, resulting in a
shift of avoidance gradient B from B to B'. In this case, gradient
B' lies above and to the right of gradient A', implying that
the strength of the individual's tendency to avoid Choice B exceeds
the strength of the tendency to avoid Choice A for all probabilities.
Hence, the model suggests that an upward shift in avoidance gradient B
and a downward shift in avoidance gradient A will induce the individual
to use service and endure the direct disutility or discomfort that
accompanies the procedure.
Conversely, suppose the policy analyst introduces options that
restrict or limit the use of preventive or early detection services. In
this case, an increase in the effective price, a decline in income, a
more stringent set of other barriers to care or a decline in the
perceived benefits of care shifts avoidance gradient A upward and to the
right. Similarly, a decline in perceived susceptibility and severity
lowers avoidance gradient B in a downward direction. When combined, the
policy options reduce the probability of use and increase the likelihood
that the individual will adopt option B (i.e. avoid the use of service
and endure the disutility of illness).
THE DATA AND METHODS
As mentioned earlier, the theoretical framework of the
conflict-choice model was applied to the data derived from the responses
of 196,081 individuals who participated in the Behavioral Risk Factor
Surveillance System (BRFSS) survey in 2003. BRFSS is a well known
population survey conducted annually on risk factors and health
conditions in the general population in the U. S. Data on variables that
may influence the use of HIV test are available in the 2003 survey but
unavailable in more recent years. To test the validity of the
conflict-choice model that integrates three separate theoretical
perspectives into a single modality, a logistic regression analysis was
carried out using HIV tests as the dependent variable. As such, the use
or non-use of HIV tests is treated as a function of the integrated
conflict-choice model.
The definitions, means and standard deviations of the dependent
variable and the set of related covariates are summarized in Table 1.
Respondents who were 65 years of age or more and those who were
unwilling or unable to report their use or non-use of the HIV test were
eliminated from the study. As indicated in the table, the focus of the
logistic regression analysis is on the binary variable HIV which
identifies 86,527 individuals who reported that they used the HIV test.
For purposes of presentation, the set of covariates represent barriers
to use, perceived risk or susceptibility to contracting the disease and
the perceived benefits of early detection or prevention. In terms of the
HBM, it is assumed that all respondents were familiar with the severity
of the condition and its related health outcomes.
The perceived barriers to use are measured by a set of binary
variables that identify individuals who reported that they earned a high
income, encountered no situation in which cost prevented the use of
service and identified a usual source of care. In each case, the set of
variables represent a relatively low barrier to use and it is expected
that respondents who were well educated, earned a high income, reported
that cost did not prevent the use of medical care and identified a usual
source of service were more likely to use the HIV test than their
counterparts in the corresponding reference group.
The perceived benefits that might be derived from early detection
also are measured by a set of binary variables. As indicated in the
table, the binary variables identify those who correctly noted that
treatment may prevent the transmission of the disease to the baby during
delivery and that medical care may enable infected individuals to live
longer. In addition, it is assumed that those who attained a college
degree, those who reported that it was important or very important to
know their HIV status and those who reported a consultation with a
health professional regarding preventive measures are more likely to
perceive the benefits of early detection or prevention than their
counterparts in the corresponding reference group. Accordingly, in each
case, the set of variables represent, in varying degrees of precision,
the individual's perception of the benefits derived from the HIV
test, suggesting that the coefficients derived for this set of factors
will be positive and significant.
The final set of covariates serves as surrogates for the
individual's risk or susceptibility of contracting HIV/AIDS. As
indicated, the most direct measure of susceptibility, HIV RISK,
identifies individuals who reported the use of intravenous drugs,
treatment for a sexually transmitted or venereal disease engaged in
prostitution or participated in anal sex without the use of a condom.
Assuming that individuals are risk averse, the study examines the
proposition that the probability of using the HIV test is greater among
those who are at greatest direct risk than among their less susceptible
counterparts.
Less direct indicators of a greater comparative risk include the
individual's racial background, represented by the binary variables
BLACK and NATIVE AMERICAN. The differential risk associated with age is
measured by the binary variable that identifies those who are between 18
and 44 years of age while gender specific susceptibility is captured by
the binary variable, FEMALE. Given the differential rates of infection
cited previously, it is expected that the probability of use is greater
among members of these groups than their counterparts in the
corresponding reference category.
RESULTS
The results of the logistic regression analysis are presented in
Table 2. As indicated, the analysis correctly identified 64.2 percent of
the respondents. It should also be noted that all coefficients are
statistically significant (P < .01).
The analysis uniformly and without exception supports the
expectations derived from the conflict choice model and, in particular
the predicted influence of barriers to care, reported susceptibility and
the perceived benefits of early detection on the use of the HIV test.
The results also suggest that indicators represented by AGE RISK,
ATTITUDE and PROVIDER CONSULTATION were the
most important predictors of use. In this regard, respondents who
reported that it was important to know their health status and those who
consulted with a provider of care regarding preventive measures were
among the most likely to use the HIV test. In short, the results of the
analysis are fully consistent with the expectations derived from the
conflict choice model.
CONCLUSIONS AND QUALIFICATIONS
The results that are presented in this paper are limited by several
considerations. First, the analysis is based on cross sectional data,
suggesting that causality is neither possible nor intended. Second, data
limitations prevented an assessment of differential perceptions of
severity, a feature that exerts an unknown influence on reported
results. In addition, several of the variables represent gross
surrogates for their theoretical counter parts. In particular, the
analysis of the barriers to use would benefit from a more precise
indicator of the differential prices imposed on potential users while
the educational attainment of the individual is a proxy for the
perceived benefits of early detection and perhaps perceptions concerning
the severity of the health outcomes that accompany infection. Data
limitations prevented the assessment of other factors such as the
distance from the potential user's residence to the source of
service. Finally, the study was not able to measure the slope of the
avoidance gradient or the magnitude change in the position of avoidance
gradients. Rather the analysis was limited to an assessment of the
influence of each variable on the change in the likelihood that an
individual used the HIV test. However, given the uniformity of results
it is possible to argue that the results reported here reflect
differences in the position of the avoidance gradients.
Although limited by several considerations, the analysis supports
several tentative conclusions. First, the results are uniformly
consistent with the expectations derived from the conflict choice model
and each coefficient was statistically significant (P< .01).
Consistent with the TCB and the HBM, the analysis clearly supports the
proposition that a decline in barriers to use tends to increase the
probability the individual used the test. Also consistent with the TCB,
the paper indicates that policies designed to stimulate the use of early
detection or preventive services should consider a reduction in price or
the elimination of the price of service. The results also indicate that
a usual source of care reduces the barrier to use. When combined with
findings concerning a consultation with a provider of care and the
individual's attitude toward the importance of securing service,
the results indicate a need to ensure that the members of the population
have access to a personal source of service.
The analysis also indicates that, if the individual seeks to avoid
the risk of an adverse outcome, the indicators of susceptibility were
among the most important predictors of the use of the HIV test. These
results indicate a need to communicate accurate information that depicts
the interrelation among risky behaviors, contracting the disease and the
potential deleterious effects on the individual's health status.
Given the importance of racial and gender effects, the analysis also
suggests that whites, males and those occupying a low socio-economic
status may represent appropriate targets for interventions designed to
ensure appropriate use of the test.
Finally, the study supports the proposition that early detection
requires the implementation of a coordinated policy option that not only
reduces barriers to service, to include price, but also emphasizes the
behaviors that contribute to susceptibility and the potential benefits
that are derived from a timely use of the test. In short, the results of
the paper clearly support the adoption of policy options that lower the
individual's tendency to avoid care seeking behavior while
simultaneously increasing the avoidance of undesirable health outcomes,
thereby improving the likelihood that the individual benefit from an
improved health status.
REFERENCES
Allen S, Serufilira A, Bogaerts J, et al. Confidential HIV testing
and condom promotion in Africa. Impact on HIV and gonorrhea rates.
Journal of the American Medical Association. 1992;268:3338-3343.
CDC. (2003). MMWR 52(15).
CDC. (2004). HIV/AIDS Surveillance Report Vol 15.
CDC. (2008). HIV Prevalence Estimates--United States, 2006. MMWR,
57(39); 1073-1076
Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. (2009). Cases of HIV
infection and AIDS in the United States and dependent areas, by
race/ethnicity, 2003-2007. HIV/AIDS Surveillance Supplemental Report 14
(No. 2)
Cohen, S. E., M.L. Berk, et al. (2001). The care of HIV-infected
adults in rural areas of the United States. Journal of Acquired Immune
Deficiency Syndrome, 28, 385-392.
Doblian, A. R. Andersen, J. Stein. (2003). The impact of HIV on
oral health and subsequent use of dental services. Journal of Public
Health Dentistry 63(2) 78-85.
Dobalian, A. J. Tsao and R. Duncan. (2004). Pain and the use of
outpatient services among persons with HIV. Medical Care 42(2) 129-138
2004
Goldman, G.P., A. Leibowitz, G. Joyce et al. (2003). Insurance
status of HIV-infected adults in the post HAART era: Evidence from the
United States. Applied Economics and Health Policy 2(2) 85-91.
Higgins D, Galavotti C, O'Reilly KR et al. (1991). Evidence
for the effects of HIV antibody counseling and testing on risk
behaviors. Journal of the American Medical Association. 266:2419-2429.
Hsiao, A. M. Wong D. Kanouse et al. (2003). Complementary and
alternative medicine use and substitution for conventional therapy by
HIV-infected patients. Journal of Acquired Immune Deficiency Syndromes
33, 157-165 2003
Kaiser Family Foundation. (June 2004) Survey of Americans on
HIV/AIDS.
Kaiser Family Foundation. (June, 2004). HIV/AIDS Policy Fact Sheet.
Kilbourne, A. M., R. M. Anderson, S. Asch et al. (2002). Response
to symptoms among a U.S. national probability sample of adults infected
with human immunodeficiency virus. Medical Care Research and Review 59
(1) 36-58.
Kuo AM, Hauloos JS, Witt MD, et al. (2005). Recognition of
Undiagnosed HIV Infection: an Evaluation of Missed Opportunities in
Predominantly Urban Minority Population. Aids Patient Care and STDs Vol
19 (4).
Landon, B., I. Wilson, S. Cohn et al.(2003). Physician
specialization and antiretroviral therapy for HIV. Journal of General
Internal Medicine 18, 233-241.
Landon, B., I. Wilson, N. Wenger et al. (2002). Specialty training
and specialization among physicians who treat HIV/AIDS in the United
States. Journal of General Internal Medicine 17, 12-22.
London A., C. Foote-Ardah and M. Shapiro. (2003). Use of
alternative therapists among people in care for HIV in the United
States. American Journal of Public Health 93(6) 980-987.
McCaig, L. A. Hardy and D. Winn. (1991). Knowledge about AIDS and
HIV in the US population: Influence of the local incidence of AIDS.
American Journal of Public Health 81(12) 1591-1595.
McInnes, M. F. Malitz et al.(2004). Differences in patient and
clinic characteristics at CARE Act funded HIV clinics. AIDS Care 16(7)
851-857.
Pergua, A. and M. Rivo. (1998). Racial differences in AIDS
knowledge among adults. AIDS Education Preview 4(1) 52-60.
Samet, J. M. Winter L. Grant and R. Hingson. (1997). Factors
associated with HIV testing among sexually active adolescents: a
Massachusetts survey. Pediatrics 100 (3) 371-377.
Sherbourne, C. M Fprge F-Y Kung (2003). Personal and psychosocial
characteristics associated with psychiatric conditions among women with
human immunodeficiency virus. Women's Health Issues 13, 104-110.
Tucker J., M. Burnam C. Sherbourne Substance use and mental health
correlates of nonadherence to antiretroviral medications in a sample of
human immunodeficiency virus infection. American Journal of Medicine
114, 573-580.
U.S. Census Bureau. (2003). Annual Estimates of the Population by
Sex, Race and Hispanic or Latino Origin for the United States.
ROBERT W. BROYLES
University of Oklahoma
ARI MWACHOFI
East Carolina University
AMIR A. KHALIQ
University of Oklahoma
Table 1
Definitions, Means and Standard Deviations of the
Dependent Variable and the Covariates
Variable Definition Mean (SD)
DEPENDENT VARIABLE
TEST If respondent was tested for HIV = 1; 0 .44 (.49)
otherwise
SUSCEPTIBILITY
AGERISK If respondent was between 18 and 44 =1; .54(.49)
0 otherwise
BEHAVIOR If respondent engaged in risky behavior .03(.18)
during previous year = 1; 0 otherwise
FEMALE If respondent was female = 1; 0 .59(.49)
otherwise
INDIAN If respondent was Native American = 1; 0 .01(.05)
otherwise
BLACK If respondent was African American = 1; .01(.04)
0 otherwise
SINGLE If respondent was single = 1; 0 otherwise .43(.49)
BENEFITS
IMPORTANT If respondent believed it is important .73 (.37)
or very important to know his/her HIV
status, =1; 0 otherwise
BIRTH If respondent knew that HIV may be .52 (.49)
prevented during child birth, = 1; 0
otherwise
LIFE If respondent knew that treatment for .93(.25)
HIV might prolong life, = 1; 0 otherwise
CONTACT If respondent talked to a health care .10(.30)
provider about the use of condoms to
prevent STDs, = 1;
COLLEGE 0 otherwise If respondent was college .34(.47)
educated = 1; 0 otherwise
(.30)
BARRIERS
INCOME If respondent earned an annual income of .37(48)
$50,000 or more year = 1; 0 otherwise
USUAL If respondent reported a usual source of .81(.39)
care= 1; 0 otherwise
COST If respondent reported that cost never .86(.35)
prevented use of service = 1; 0
otherwise
Table 2
Logistic Regression Analysis of the Use or Non-use
of the HIV Test
Co-variate Coefficient .95 OR CI
RISK
AGERISK .89 (a) 2.40, 2.50
BEHAVIOR .50 (a) 1.57,
1.75
FEMALE .02 (a) 1.01,1.05
INDIAN .58 (a) 1.44,2.19
BLACK .64 (a) 1.53,2.34
SINGLE
BENEFITS
IMPORTANT .83 (a) 2.22, 2.39
BIRTH .22 (a) 1.22, 1.28
LIFE .30 (a) 1.30, 1.39
CONTACT COLLEGE .78 (a) 2.10, 2.25
BARRIERS
INCOME .15 (a) 1.14, 1.89
USUAL .15 (a) 1.14, 1.20
COST .42 1.48, 1.56