首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月30日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Social capital and the tradeoff between environment and development.
  • 作者:Park, Hyung Jun ; Feiock, Richard C.
  • 期刊名称:International Journal of Economic Development
  • 印刷版ISSN:1523-9748
  • 出版年度:2002
  • 期号:July
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Southern Public Administration Education Foundation, Inc.
  • 摘要:Collaborative or cooperative approaches to environmental and natural resource management provide potential solutions to the dilemma of the environment development tradeoff (Lubell et al., 2002). These approaches rely on positive incentives and partnership arrangements. Transaction costs, lack of information and community involvement, and absence of trust among participants have been identified as barriers to effective intergovernmental and public/private collaboration in environmental management (Wondolleck and Yaffee, 2000; Feiock and Stream, 2001). Community social capital has been hailed as the critical resource to overcome barriers to collaboration, but the process by which social capital works has not been clearly delineated. In fact, the literature is not even clear as to just what social capital is. This essay takes the initial steps in building a theory of environmental collaboration by identifying the underlying dimensions of social capital relevant to environmental and economic development decisions. We then describe the resulting "types" of social capital and link them to environmental collaboration.
  • 关键词:Infrastructure (Economics)

Social capital and the tradeoff between environment and development.


Park, Hyung Jun ; Feiock, Richard C.


Environmental Collaboration

Collaborative or cooperative approaches to environmental and natural resource management provide potential solutions to the dilemma of the environment development tradeoff (Lubell et al., 2002). These approaches rely on positive incentives and partnership arrangements. Transaction costs, lack of information and community involvement, and absence of trust among participants have been identified as barriers to effective intergovernmental and public/private collaboration in environmental management (Wondolleck and Yaffee, 2000; Feiock and Stream, 2001). Community social capital has been hailed as the critical resource to overcome barriers to collaboration, but the process by which social capital works has not been clearly delineated. In fact, the literature is not even clear as to just what social capital is. This essay takes the initial steps in building a theory of environmental collaboration by identifying the underlying dimensions of social capital relevant to environmental and economic development decisions. We then describe the resulting "types" of social capital and link them to environmental collaboration.

Over the past decade the term social capital has received considerable attention from scholars in a variety of fields. Social capital is valuable because it provides resources to solve problems of coordination and cooperation, reduces transaction costs, and facilitates the flow of information between and among individuals in community or organization (Ostrom, 1998; Ostrom and Ahn, 2002; Feiock and Tao, 2002; Lubell et al., 2002; Lubell and Scholz, 2001;Lin, 2001). Similarly, Putnam (1993) argues that social capital makes collective works easier and, ultimately, facilitates economic and community development

The concept of social capital has become increasingly popular in a wide range of social science disciplines, but there is a lack of consensus on the meaning of term. In social science research "social capital" is used in vastly different ways. Critics have characterized research examining the impacts of social capital as '"casual empiricism", because it lacks of an obvious link between theory and measurement (Durlauf, 1999).

In order to better understand how social capital can help state and local governments reconcile environmental and development goals, we systematically define and classify social capital based on its scope and form. This allows us to identify different "types" of social capital that can shape collaboration and partnership among actors concerned with environment and economic development.

The Scope of Social Capital

The scope of social capital ranges from the micro to the macro level (Grootaert and van Bastelaer, 2001). Analysis of social capital at the micro level is usually associated with face-to face interaction between and among individuals (Turner, 1999), and those features of horizontal relationship, such as networks of indivi duals or households, and the associated norms and trust, that generat e externalities for the community as a whole(Putnam, 1993). James C oleman (1990) includes vertical as well as horizontal associations and behavior within and among organizations by expanding the unit of ob servation and introducing a vertical component to social capital (Gro otaert and van Bastelaer, 2001).

A macro-view of social capital includes the social and political environment that shapes social structure and enables norms to develop (Grootaert and van Bastelaer, 2001). This view includes the most formalized institutional relationships and structures, such as the rule of law, the political regime, the court system, and civil and political liberties. This focus on institutions draws on the work of Mancur Olson (1982) and Douglas North (1990), who have argued that such institutions have a significant effect on the pattern and rate of economic development. The phenomena related with the micro and macro level conceptualizations are complementary and their coexistence maximizes the waves of social capital on economic and social outcomes. For example, macro institutions can provide an enabling environment in which local associations can develop and flourish; local associations can sustain regional and national institutions and add a measure of stability to them (Grootaert and van Bastelaer, 2001).

The Forms of Social Capital

The Uphoff (2000) suggested two dimension of social capital--structural and cognitive. Structural forms of social capital concern th e roles, rules, procedures, and networks that facilitate information sh aring, and collective action and decisionmaking through established roles, social networks and other social st ructures supplemented by rules, procedures, and precedents. As such, it is a relatively objective and externally observable construct. Cogni tive social capital refers to shared norms, values, trust, attitudes, and beliefs. It is therefore a more subjective and intangible concept (Uph off , 2000).

Landry, Amara, and Lamari also classify two form of social capital: Structural and Cognitive. They measure three type of structural social capital: Network capital, Relationship capital, and Participation capital. Cognitive social capital was measured by trust capital. Krishna (2000) makes a similar distinction between institutional capital and relational capital.

The structural (Institutional) dimension of social capital includes rule of law, formal institutions and organization structures, but it also encompasses the overall pattern of relationships in an organization and its included network. This conceptualization is similar to Granovetter's (1973) notion of weak ties.

The relational dimension of social capital concerns the nature of connections between individuals. It is characterized by levels of trust, shared norms and perceived obligation, and sense of mutual identification. This conceptualization of relational social capital is similar to Granovetter's (1973) notion of strong ties. Likewise, Feiock and Tao (2002) distinguish endogenous and exogenous social capital, and examine their effects on the regional economic development partnership as one form of collective action.

A Typology of Social Capital

Whether at the micro or macro level, social capital exerts its influence on development as a result of the interactions between two distinct types of social capital--structural and cognitive. Cooperation and coordination among neighbors can be based on a personal cognitive bond that may not be reflected in a formal structural arrangement. Similarly, the existence of a community association does not necessarily testify to strong personal connections among its members, either because participation in its activities is not voluntary or because its existence has outlasted the external factor that led to its creation. Social interaction can become capital through the persistence of its effects, which can be ensured at both the cognitive and structural level(Grootaert and van Bastelaer, 2001).

We craft a typology of types of social capital framework based on these two key dimensions: its scope and its form. The framework treats social capital as a genuine asset that requires investment to accumulate and that generates a stream of benefits.

Ideally empirical investigation of social capital would examine and measure all four quadrants of Figure 1. Empirical work had generally focused on one or at most two of these quadrants. The most extensive work has been on micro level institutions or norms. Recent work (Park 2003) has used confirmatory factor analysis to empirically isolate these dimensions.

Social Capital, Environmental Collaboration, and Economic Performance

Differentiating the types of social capital may help us understand how some state and local governments are able to overcome tradeoffs between environmental and economic gains.

Lubell and Scholz (2001) suggest that reciprocity in relationships among governmental and non-governmental actors and lengthy time horizons are necessary to achieve sustainable development and to overcome collective action problems in environmental management. By extending these arguments, we contend that overcoming tradeoffs between developmental and environmental concerns requires: 1) participation in democratic political institutions; 2) social mechanisms to resolve conflicts from unharmonious development; and 3) information sharing for the diffusion of innovations. Each of these is facilitated by social capital in the community.

Specific types of social capital influence collective action and economic performance. Any form of capital-material or nonmaterial-represents an asset or a class of assets that produces a stream of benefits. The stream of benefits from social capital-or the channels through which it influences development-includes several associated elements (Grootaert and van Bastelaer 2001). First, Cognitive social capital at the micro level (i.e., endogenous social capital) such as trust, shared norms, and informal sanction reduce transaction costs. Reputations built through trust and reciprocity reduce information, monitoring, and enforcement costs and thus facilitate cooperation and collective action.

Second, Structural social capital such as associations, networks, and institutions provide an informal and formal framework to organize information sharing, coordination of activities, and collective decision- making. Participation by individuals in social networks increases the availability of information and lowers its cost. This information, especially if it relates to such things as new "green" technologies can play a critical role in increasing the returns from economic production while mitigating adverse environmental consequences.

Participation in local networks and attitudes of mutual trust make it easier for a group to reach collective decisions and implement collective action. Since property rights are often imperfectly developed and applied, collective decisions on how to manage common resources are critical to maximizing their use and yield.

Finally, networks and attitudes reduce opportunistic behavior by community members. In settings where a certain behavior is expected from individuals for the benefit of the group, social pressures and fear of exclusion can induce these individuals to provide the expected behavior by reducing transaction costs and encouraging innovation.

Social capital contributes to sustainable economic development and growth by reducing conflict and the transaction costs of environmental management and by facilitating information sharing and the diffusion of innovation. Environmental governance systems based on partnership provide one mechanism to exploit existing social capital in its various forms and generate additional social capital resources.

References

Coleman, J. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.

Durlauf, S. N. 1999. "The Case Against Social Capital." Focus. 20(3): pp. 1-5.

Feiock, R. C. and J. Tao. 2002. "Social Capital and the Formation of Regional Partnership." Paper presented at the Decentralized Governance Symposium at Florida State University.

Feiock R. C. and C. C. Stream. 2001. "Environmental Protection and Economic Development: A False Tradeoff?" Public Administration Review. 61 (May/June): pp. 272-280.

Granovetter, Mark. 1973. "The Strength of Weak Tie." American Journal of Sociology. 78: pp. 1360-1380.

Grootaert, C. and T. V. Bastelaer. 2001. "Understanding and Measuring Social Capital." Social Capital Initiative Working Paper. 24. World Bank.

Krishhna, A. 2000. "Creating and Harnessing Social Capital." In Socia l Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Eds. P. Dasgupta and I. Seragel din. Washington D.C.: The World Bank, pp.71-93.

Landry, Rejean, Nabil Amara, and Moktar Lamari. 2001. "Social Capit al: Innovation and Public Policy". Canadian Journal of Public Researc h. 2(2): pp.73-79.

Lin, N. 2001. "Social Capital: A Theory of Social Structure and Action". New York: Cambridge University Press.

Lubell, M., M. Schneider, J. T. Scholz, and M. Mete. 2002. "Watershed Partnership and the Emergence of Collective Action Institutions." American Journal of Political Science. 46(1): pp. 148-163.

Lubell, M. and J. T. Scholz. 2001. "Cooperation, Reciprocity, and the Collective Action-Heuristic" American Journal of Political Science. 45: pp. 160-178.

North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Olson, M. 1982, The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Ostrom E. and T.K. Ahn, 2002. "Social capital and the second generation theories of collective action: An Analytical Approach to the Form of Social Capital." Paper presented at the 2002 Annual meeting of America Political Science Association.

Ostrom, E. 1998. "A Behavior Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action: Presidential Address, American Political Science Association, 1997." American Political Science Review. 92(1): pp. 1-22.

Park, H. J. 2003. "Framework of Social Capital: Analysis of Model of Social Capital Dimension Through Confirmatory Factor Analysis." Unpublished paper, Tallahassee FL.

Putnam, Robert D. (with R. Leonardi and R. Nanetti), 1993. "Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy" Princeton: NJ: Princeton University Press.

Tuner, Jonathan H. 2000. "The Formation of Social Capital". In Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Eds. P. Dasgupta and I. Serageld in, Washington DC: The World Bank. Pp.94-146.

Uphoff, N. 2000. "Understanding Social Capital: Learning from the An alysis and Experience of Participation." In Social Capital: A Multiface ted Perspective. Eds. P. Dasgupta and I. Serageldin. Washington D.C. : The World Bank, pp.215-252

Wondolleck, J. M. and S. L. Yaffee. 2000. Making Collaboration Work: Lessons from Innovation in Natural Resource Management. Washington, D.C.: Island Press.

Biographical Sketch

Hyung Jun Park (hjp6408@garnet.acns.fsu.edu) is a Ph.D. student in the Askew School of Public Administration and Policy, Florida State University.

Feiock, Richard C. (rfeiock@garnet.acns.fsu.edu) is Professor and Ph.D. Program Director of the Askew School, Florida State University.

Hyung Jun Park

and

Richard C. Feiock

Askew School of Public Administration and

Department of Political Science

Florida State University
Figure 1
Dimension of Social Capital

 Macro (Vertical)

Structura 1 Institution of the Governance, Cognitive
 state, Shared Belief (Endogeno
 Rule of law of civil &
 political liberty

 (Exogeno Local Institutions, Trust, us)
 us) Networks, Local Norms and
 Civic Engagement, Values
 Participation

 Micro (Horizontal)

Source: reorganized Grootaert and van Bastelaer(2001)
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有