The consequences of overstating fuel economy.
Beck, Corey ; Schap, David
I. Introduction
This essay examines a recent case involving contract law with
applied law and economic analysis. The principles of contract law can be
brought to the fore by examining different variations of breach of
contract. In particular, the essay looks at the consequences of Hyundai
Motor Co. overstating the fuel efficiency of its Hyundai Elantra. The
purpose of the essay is not merely to determine the appropriate
compensation owed by a company to consumers for overstating the fuel
economy of a vehicle, as in the factual case at hand. Rather, the essay
illustrates various economic doctrines and norms by applying them to
different fictionalized variations of the actual Elantra case.
Fictionalized accounts are noted as such. The series of customized
Elantras presented throughout the essay are fictional vehicles capable
of figuratively transporting the reader into the realm of economic
analysis of contract law.
Hyundai Motor Co. advertised that its Elantra model cars get 40
highway miles per gallon (MPG) as part of its "Save the
Asterisk" campaign, while in reality the Elantra only gets 35
highway MPG (Ramstad 2012). Upon discovery of the error, Hyundai Motor
Co. apologized for "procedural errors," claiming that human
error led to the incorrect calculation (Ramstad 2012). This particular
vehicle is part of a larger controversy being investigated by the EPA.
The issue of overestimating fuel economy also includes Ford Motor
Company's Ford C-Max hybrid and Toyota Motor Company's Prius V
(White 2012), but only the Elantra is considered herein. In this essay,
appropriate damages for breach of contract by Hyundai will be explored
in cases where the breach was intentional as well as in cases of
unintentional breach. Depending on the specific scenario, losses may or
may not be recoverable. The essay also explores a variety of ways to
calculate damages. Ultimately, damages should function to make the
customers whole, as if the purchased Elantra got 40 MPG.
Prior to addressing hypothetical scenarios, readers may wish to
learn more about the resolution of the actual case. Facing class-action
lawsuits covering those purchasers suffering unanticipated lower fuel
economy, Hyundai Motor Co. voluntarily offered, by way of settlement, a
variety of options to purchasers of the 2012 Elantra (and other models
and model years with similarly distorted fuel-economy boasts). Besides
receiving an apology from Hyundai Motor Co., purchasers have been
invited to choose one of several options: (1) a lump-sum payment,
expected to average $353 across consumers; or (2) a debit card in the
amount of loss due to inferior fuel economy (after reporting actual
mileage to the local Hyundai dealership), plus an additional 15% for
"inconvenience;" or (3) a dealership credit for
repairs/service equal to 150% of the lump-sum payout under option (1);
or (4) a credit toward the purchase of a new Hyundai (or Kia, as Hyundai
Motor Co. owns about a one-third stake in Kia Motors) in the amount of
200% of option (1Hirsh 2014). In a separate but not unrelated action,
Hyundai Motor Co. has rolled back its claim concerning the 2012 Elantra
fuel economy by two MPG, to 38 MPG, issuing other rollbacks as well for
various 2012 and 2013 models (EPA 2014).
II. Contract Existence
In the realm of contract law, in order to examine possible damages
from an inaccurate MPG report, it is important to first establish
whether a contract exists. One doctrine governing contract existence is
the notion of consideration (Posner 2011:123-25). Consideration has two
components: true exchange and well-defined terms. In the case of
Hyundai, there is true exchange of money for a car and there are
well-defined terms including the date of sale and the sale price. Among
the terms are that the car will get 40 MPG, and there are specified and
implied warranties that extend well into the future. Therefore, a
contract exists (as opposed to a momentary spot transaction in the
market).
III. Intentional Breach
Prior to the initial sale of the vehicle, suppose Hyundai has an
option of producing either Elantra model X or Y. Suppose that X has a
platinum input that guarantees 40 MPG while Y uses a silver input and
will not necessarily achieve 40 MPG. The cost of producing X is $11,000
per car while the cost of producing Y is $5,000 per car. To simplify
matters, suppose Hyundai knows consumers are willing and able to pay
$25,000 and $20,000 for each model respectively. Furthermore, assume X
has a pollution cost of $2,000 per car, but Y (being less fuel
efficient) has a pollution cost of $5,000 per car. These costs and their
implications are outlined in Table 1 below:
TABLE 1.
Costs and Implications of Producing Models X and Y
Model X Model Y
Cost of Production $11,000 $5,000
Cost of Pollution $2,000 $5,000
Revenue from Consumers $25,000 $20,000
(Revenue--Cost $25,000 - $11,000 = $20,000 - $5,000 =
of Production)
Profit $14,000 $15,000
(Revenue--Cost $25,000 - $13,000 = $20,000 - $10,000 =
of Production--
Cost of Pollution)
Value to Society $12,000 $10,000
Therefore, the total value of each X to society is $12,000 (i.e.,
the revenue minus the costs of production and pollution) and total value
of each Y to society is $10,000. It is more efficient for Hyundai to
produce model X, but Hyundai's profit is greater from producing
model Y. Hyundai decides to make and market the Y Elantra as part of its
"Save the Asterisk" campaign, despite knowing that the Y model
is not likely to actually achieve 40 MPG. Now, suppose customers notice
the difference and sue for damages based on the contract for 40 MPG. The
court may rule specific performance, breach with damages, substantial
performance or discharge the contract without assessing money damages.
Specific Performance
A specific performance ruling would require the contract to be
completed as originally agreed upon. Hyundai would need to take back the
cars and install the platinum piece thereby assuring the car achieves 40
MPG. Suppose it would cost Hyundai $10,000 per car to recall and install
the platinum pieces, and the loss to each customer for a 35 MPG
performance is $5,000. Specific performance would cost Hyundai $10,000
but only provide a $5,000 benefit. Also consider the high administration
and transaction costs society would incur. The total social cost
($10,000 plus administration costs to oversee implementation) exceeds
the $8,000 total social benefit (difference in pollution costs plus
benefit to consumers), so specific performance is not efficient in this
circumstance.
Posner (1979) holds that a contract should not be enforced through
specific performance if the cost of enforcement exceeds the gain from
enforcement. Meanwhile, Kronman (1979b: 183-87) asserts that specific
performance is primarily useful when a good passes the "uniqueness
test;" in a case of a unique good or service, specific performance
is more efficient than awarding money damages when money damages involve
a high calculation cost (most typically due to a court having to assess
a value that is highly subjective to one or both of the parties).
However, an Elantra is not a unique good because it has a developed
market and close substitutes. Therefore, the works of both authors
support the finding that specific performance in this case would be
inefficient.
Breach with Damages
The court's second option, breach with damages, would allow
the customers to keep the car that was originally purchased and force
Hyundai to compensate the customers $5,000 each (this is the loss to
each customer as defined above). Assuming that damages can be calculated
at reasonable cost, they should be set at exactly $5,000 or the amount
that would make the customer whole. If damages were to be set above
$5,000, there would be an opportunity for extortion. (1) On the other
hand, if damages are set below $5,000, consumers will not trust
advertising and the number of car purchases would decline. (2) In any
context in which intentional breach is contemplated, the ideal would be
to achieve the principle of "efficient breach," meaning breach
if and only if breach is efficient. (3)
A ruling of breach with damages in the amount of $5,000 may not be
perfectly efficient because consumers may not get compensated for any
subjective value they might attach to being more environmentally
friendly (Kronman 1979b: 186). Determining such a subjective value would
have high transaction costs. It cannot be assumed that a consumer's
subjective value is incorporated into the sale price and is therefore
compensated as part of the $5,000 in damages. A consumer might buy a car
with better fuel economy solely in order to save money from using less
gas.
Substantial Performance and Foreseeability
As Posner (2011:167) points out, "Product performance may
depend on the consumer's tastes, which may not be known to the
producer." For example, suppose a customer pays $25,000 for a
battleship grey Elantra. When the car is delivered, it is steel grey.
Because of the incorrect shade, the consumer sues for breach of
contract, strategically hoping for a ruling of specific performance.
Repainting the car will cost $1,200. Armed with a ruling of specific
performance, the buyer could indicate a willingness to instead accept
the incorrect color in exchange for a price concession of, say, $ 1,000.
The consumer has an incentive to inflate the value he or she attaches to
the car's color shade as an opportunistic ploy to obtain a large
price concession. Therefore, a court would rule substantial performance
(Posner 2011:166-67) has occurred and so deny the consumer recovery for
any alleged loss due to slight color variation, either through the
consumer opportunistically exploiting a specific performance ruling or
more directly through a court ruling of money damages. The "grey
area" in this hypothetical scenario can be compared to the case
Jacob & Youngs Inc. v. Kent, (4) where substantial performance was
ruled. Both in the hypothetical case and in Jacob & Youngs Inc. v.
Kent, a ruling of substantial performance avoids the court having to
attempt to estimate subjective loss amounts in setting money damages or,
more importantly, giving a party the opportunity to extort additional
gains through ex post opportunism via a specific performance ruling.
In the above hypothetical situation, suppose the purchaser
indicates that the color is to be battleship grey, but for some
idiosyncratic reason the color shade sought is a major concern: if the
correct shade is not used in production, the consumer genuinely will
suffer a loss of $1,000. An example might be a film producer who has
arranged an intricate scene that will fail in the absence of just the
right color scheme and colored car. If a specific monetary damages
amount for any slight deviation from the requested color shade is not
included in the original contract, recovery for the loss will be denied
under the Foreseeability Doctrine. (5) The customer has a duty to
disclose what is at stake if the color is not battleship grey. The
so-called duty to disclose simply means that recovery for a loss will be
denied in the absence of disclosure. In this case, the $1,000 amount
must be declared in advance. Because it is not ordinary knowledge that a
different shade of grey makes a $1,000 difference to a customer, the
actual knowledge of the customer must be monetized and written into a
liquidated damages clause of the contract with that particular customer.
Short of this insertion, the $1,000 loss, although real, is not
recoverable under the Foreseeability Doctrine. The seller needs to be
informed of special circumstances in advance to make an informed
decision about whether a separate production run will be required with
accompanying additional cost or, indeed, if the contract should be
entered into at all.
Fraud and Disclosure
Another scenario to consider would be if the purchased car got zero
MPG; in other words, a case of fraud, where: "The liar makes a
positive investment in manufacturing and disseminating misinformation.
This investment is wasted from a social standpoint, so naturally the law
does not reward him for his lie" (Posner 2011:139). Legally, the
seller has a duty to disclose if the car does not run. If the seller
does not disclose the information, it is an actionable omission. Just as
an empty box of chocolates cannot be sold without disclosure (Posner
2011:141), if there are no piston rings in the car's engine the
customer should not need to look under the hood. Rather, that
information must be disclosed.
The economic rationale for disclosure is that if information were
free or extremely inexpensive for one of the parties to acquire, it
would be a waste of resources for the other party to acquire the same
information (Kronman 1979a: 114). For example, without disclosure rules,
the buyer might hire a mechanic to determine why the car does not run.
Meanwhile, Hyundai knows this information at no cost. Products that tend
to require disclosure are those that are infrequently purchased and
expensive, and those where the flawed characteristic is not
ascertainable without handling or not necessarily discoverable with
repeated use (Posner 2011:141). All of these conditions are true in an
automobile purchase. Therefore, the company must disclose if the car
gets zero MPG to prevent overinvestment in information discovery.
What should one make of a situation in which a car is purported to
get 40 MPG, yet actually only gets 35, or 38, or 39.99 MPG? Does that
constitute fraud? One aspect without which fraud is not present is
materiality: the difference between what is claimed as true and what is
actually true must be a material difference, meaning a difference of
substance/importance (American Bar Association Model Jury Instructions,
1996). Thus, 40 versus 39.99 MPG does not constitute fraud, especially
when a reasonable person would know that individual driving
characteristics easily explain any .01 difference between stated and
actual MPG. A five MPG difference between claimed and actual MPG,
however, certainly may be material, especially when viewed in terms of
total cost associated with use of the automobile over its lifespan.
Ultimately, materiality is for a judge or jury to decide in a given
case.
IV. Unintentional Breach
A breach of contract may occur not by intentional choice, but for
reasons beyond the control of the parties. These include: (a) a mutual
mistake; (b) an unforeseen change in circumstances that makes completion
of the contract impossible; or (c) a cross-purpose mistake.
Additionally, another case involving foreseeability will be explored. In
all four cases, risk assignment guides the court's ruling.
Kronman (1979a: 115) asserts that in cases of mistake the losses
incurred from a breach of contract should be borne by the least cost
avoider of the mistake. This person is the more informed and/ or more
diversified party. As previously discussed, assigning risk to the more
informed party will avoid the costs to society of duplicated information
gathering, whereas assigning risk to the more diversified party reduces
the quantum of risk and risk-associated costs. (6) With the risk spread
across a broad portfolio of contracts, there is less marginal risk to
the risk-bearing party overall.
Mutual Mistake
Assume Hyundai decides to produce the higher quality model X with
the platinum input (from the Intentional Breach section), but an
engineer accidentally used a multiplier of 0.1 instead of 0.01 somewhere
in his calculations to determine MPG. This mistake yields a calculation
of 40 MPG, and the customer purchases what he and Hyundai believe is a
40 MPG car. The inaccuracy is unknown until the EPA receives complaints
and investigates, whereupon the human error is discovered. (7) Mutual
mistake is also evident in the case of Sherwood vs. Walker. (8) The
questions that arise in both cases are: should the contract be
completed; and if not, which party should pay damages?
Posner (2011) develops separate conclusions in addressing the
question of mutual mistake in Sherwood v. Walker and the general
doctrine itself. In the case of Sherwood v. Walker, Posner (2011:121)
asserts that the parties had the same understanding of what the contract
was. (9) Hence, the sale should have gone through because the seller was
in a position to obtain information at a lower cost than the buyer, and
the buyer took on risk (Poser 2011:129). Following that approach,
Hyundai is in the lower cost position to discover that the car does not
actually get 40 MPG. Therefore, Hyundai should pay damages equal to
$5,000 such that the customer achieves the expected benefit from owning
a 40 MPG car. Meanwhile, if the subject of a contract turns out to be
something other than what was agreed upon, the contract should be
invalid (Posner 2011:129). An example would be if the contract outlined
the terms of trade for an orange and the orange turned out to be an
apple. In that case, the purchaser might not be able to use an apple as
well as he would be able to use an orange, although they are both
fruits. Perhaps the purchaser was trying to make orange juice because he
was allergic to apple juice. An apple would not suffice! Applying this
logic to the Hyundai case, the highest valued user of a 40-MPG car might
not be the highest valued user of a 35-MPG car.
Unforeseen Change
Another case of unintentional breach can occur when circumstances
arise out of either party's control that make contract completion
impossible. Both Kronman (1979a) and Posner (1979) address
impossibility. Suppose Hyundai decides to produce model X (using the
platinum input), begins marketing and takes orders for the X model at
$25,000 each. Subsequently, before production starts, the tariff on
platinum is raised such that its use as an input becomes cost
prohibitive. This is similar to the case of Gobel v. Linn where the
original contract could not be completed and a new one was established.
(10) In both the hypothetical case and Gobel v. Linn, a contract
modification must occur as commercial impossibility (bankruptcy)
precludes completion of the original contract in its original terms.
Hyundai contacts those holding purchase contracts and informs them that
they can walk away from the original contract for sale or receive a car
with inferior gas mileage for the same $25,000 or pay $35,000 to get a
car that achieves the rated 40 MPG. Any buyer that goes through with the
sale would be unable ex post to (depending on the option selected)
decline to pay the additional $10,000 or sue for damages due to
receiving a car that achieves less than 40 MPG. An exception may occur
if Hyundai acted in bad faith by "courting" bankruptcy (Posner
2011:125).
Now suppose instead that the tariff increase will not be ruinous to
Hyundai, but merely expensive, turning what would have been profitable
transactions into unprofitable ones. Hyundai's other operations and
sales are profitable enough to ensure firm survival despite losses on
the model X sold for $25,000. In this situation Hyundai's
performance will not be excused, nor should it be. As the party that has
more information and is more diversified (as explained earlier in the
essay), Hyundai is held responsible for paying damages: Hyundai has more
information regarding the likelihood of tariff changes because it
imports many of its inputs; Hyundai is also the more diversified party
because it sells multiple models. Therefore, if a contract is
established and the customer sues, Hyundai should be ordered to pay
$5,000 in damages to make the customer whole.
Finally, if Hyundai in the face of a tariff increase were to choose
deliberately to switch to model Y (silver input) from model X (platinum
input), thereby reducing fuel economy, and attempted to conceal the fact
from consumers, Hyundai would be engaged in a fraudulent, intentional
breach, despite having no control over the tariff change. In this set of
circumstances, the analysis presented earlier in the discussion of
intentional breach would apply.
Cross-Purpose Mistake
Another unintended breach can occur in the case of a cross-purpose
mistake, wherein consideration is lacking because there are not
well-defined contract terms. Recall the two parts of consideration that
must be present for there to be a contract, namely true exchange and
well-defined terms. Dnes (2005, 100-101) carefully distinguishes between
cross-purpose mistake and mutual mistake. The famous example of a
cross-purpose mistake comes from Raffles v. Wichelhaus (11) where two
ships with the same name had different delivery dates. A cross-purpose
mistake also occurred in the more recent case of Konic International
Corp. v. Spokane Computer Services, Inc. (12) As these two cases show,
in a cross-purpose mistake, often the terms are not well defined because
the parties believe the terms are different things!
Suppose the Elantra and the Electra are both for sale. As
previously stated, the Elantra gets 40 MPG and sells for $25,000.
Meanwhile, suppose that the Electra only gets 20 MPG (what a creative
marketing scheme), but also sells for $25,000. A customer comes in and
says he would like to purchase the "E" car. The new salesman,
unfamiliar with the differences between the two models, brings out the
Electra and the customer pays $25,000. After owning the car for a month,
the customer returns to the dealership complaining the car is not
getting 40 MPG. The car salesman points out that the customer asked to
purchase the "E" car, not the "Elantra." If the
customer brings suit in this case, the judge may find that consideration
was not present because there was no meeting of the minds and therefore
no well-defined terms. In this case, the contract would be discharged.
The Foreseeability Doctrine
Another way for a judge to determine if losses are recoverable is
to use the Foreseeability Doctrine, which holds that a loss is
recoverable if and only if it is reasonably foreseeable (Posner
2011:159). Although it was not the first such case, Hadley v. Baxendale
(13) is an example of the application of the Foreseeability Doctrine. In
order to establish if a loss is reasonably foreseeable, two kinds of
knowledge must be considered: common knowledge and special knowledge.
Common knowledge is ordinary knowledge (e.g., a red light means stop),
and the contracting parties will be assumed (i.e., imputed) to hold such
knowledge whether or not it is actually possessed. The cost of
conducting ordinary business would be needlessly increased if the
conventions of ordinary business had to be reviewed freshly in every
ordinary context, so the parties are held to a standard of possessing
what is thought to be ordinary common knowledge. In contrast, special
(extraordinary) knowledge is sometimes in play. An example of
extraordinary knowledge would be that a certain store is closed on
Tuesday mornings. Typically, if a delivery were going to be made, it
would be assumed that stores are open on weekday mornings, unless
otherwise specified. Here a legal burden is put on the party possessing
the special knowledge, which must actually be conveyed if an associated
loss is to be recoverable, since the other party could not otherwise
become aware of the special knowledge at reasonable cost. Thus, there is
one Foreseeability Doctrine (a loss is recoverable when reasonably
foreseeable), but two tests of it (foreseeability is at hand if either
it concerns common knowledge, whether or not actually possessed, or if
it concerns special knowledge that was actually conveyed). The
Foreseeability Doctrine works toward optimal conveyance of information
and risk/responsibility assignment. (14)
To illustrate the doctrine, assume the customer above bought an
Elantra instead of an Electra and bet her neighbor $100,000 that her car
would get 40 MPG. Then, the customer loses the bet and seeks damages.
The court can use the Foreseeability Doctrine to decide if the losses
are recoverable. The imputed knowledge is that the car gets 40 MPG as
advertised. If, in reality, it gets 35 MPG, the $5,000 loss incurred
from the lost five MPG is recoverable. Meanwhile, the $100,000 bet is
special knowledge that was not actually disclosed by the customer.
Therefore, the $100,000 is not a recoverable loss.
In order to support this conclusion, the court might use
Tullock's (1979:24) idea of "resolution by analogy," (15)
or Holmes' (1979:30) idea of "construction" (16) to work
out what the parties would have said if the event had been considered.
In this case, the court would conclude that Hyundai would not have
agreed to the contract if the $ 100,000 bet had been disclosed and a
model Y Elantra had been sold to the customer. The company only sells
the car for $25,000, and logically Hyundai would only agree to take on
the risk if it were certain that the car would actually get 40 MPG in
the bet context. To assure the performance, Hyundai would stipulate
certain track conditions, specify the gasoline octane level, assign a
specific representative to do the driving and take other extraordinary
measures. All such measures would involve additional costs to Hyundai,
so one would expect there to be added consideration (i.e., a higher sale
price). Absent such stipulations and added consideration, the 40-MPG
clause of the implicit contract is arguably unenforceable; certainly the
$100,000 loss associated with an undisclosed bet is not recoverable.
Holmes (1979) also advances the idea that not every circumstance
must be written into a contract because that would be prohibitively
expensive. Suppose that the customer was suing for damages not because
of a bet she made, but because her Elantra was not getting 40 MPG while
she was speeding around her neighborhood towing a yacht on a trailer.
When she brings suit, Hyundai argues it should not need to advertise
that the Elantra gets 40 MPG only when there are four seats occupied by
persons weighing less than 200 pounds each, no more than 100 pounds in
the trunk, the operator drives the speed limit, the car is not towing a
boat, the car is not traveling uphill the whole way, the car's
tires are actually inflated, etc. There appears to be no end to the
number of necessary provisos needed if such obviously inappropriate,
excessive disclosure were required. In this case, Judge Holmes would
likely find that Hyundai only owes $5,000 in damages.
V. Damage Calculation
Although previously it was assumed that the cost of non-performance
to the customer is $5,000, there are a variety of ways to calculate the
amount that will make customers whole. Assume there are 900,000
customers. Suppose there has been a breach, and suspend the assumption
that cost of breach to any customer is $5,000. Hyundai could use actual
numbers or estimated numbers to calculate damages.
Actual Damages
In order to award actual damages, Hyundai would need to monitor how
many miles each customer drives each day and where each customer
purchases gas. Additionally, Hyundai could compensate its customers in a
variety of time intervals, ranging from a daily basis to a lump sum. It
would be costly and therefore inefficient for Hyundai to measure and pay
each of its 900,000 customers for their exact gas use on a daily basis
(this may not be true with only 10 customers). Compensating with a lump
sum based on a certain time frame would also be inefficient because
individuals would drive more during observation period in order to be
awarded more damages. Additionally, Hyundai must consider the lost
resale value because customers cannot claim their Elantras get 40 MPG.
Actual damages have very high transaction costs that are likely to be
prohibitively costly when there are a large number of customers to
compensate.
Estimated Damages
Hyundai could also consider using estimated calculations that will
have lower transaction costs but will undercompensate some customers.
Using this approach, Hyundai would need to determine the average amount
its customers drive as well as the average price of gas. The calculation
could account for region (e.g., state, county, or town). The more
detailed the breakdown, the higher the costs of acquiring information
will be. Additionally, there is an issue with those inframarginal
consumers who will be undercompensated. These are customers who drive
more or use more expensive gas (for convenience) than the calculated
average. Meanwhile, customers in the opposite situation will be
overcompensated. Therefore, using estimated damages will not be
perfectly efficient.
Elantra Damages
Given the above options, Hyundai actually has decided (option [2]
mentioned in the Introduction) to compensate its customers with a debit
card using their actual miles driven, presumably in conjunction with an
average gas price determined by some regional measure. This method of
compensation requires the customers to drive to a dealership to get
their odometers checked, costing them time, so Hyundai adds another 15%
for good measure to compensate customers for the inconvenience involved.
Although still imperfect (since customers vary in opportunity cost of
time), this calculation appears to be better than using average mileage
in reaching approximately appropriate individual compensation levels,
and it is administratively expedient. Moreover, for any consumer that
finds this particular compensation scheme to be objectionable, Hyundai
has provided other compensation options (reviewed in the Introduction).
VI. Brand Name Capital and Performance
Hyundai has voluntarily offered compensation to its customers to
avoid costly litigation and to protect its brand name capital. A
spokesman for Hyundai stated, "Fuel efficiency and trust in our
customers is the most important thing" (Ramstad 2012). A company
invests money in building its brand, so if its product does not perform
as advertised consumers will lose confidence in the brand and will not
pay for it in the future. Hyundai has attempted to protect its brand
name capital through money compensation, but DeAlessi and Staaf (1994)
have advanced a clever argument that even court-ordered money damages
may be an inadequate remedy relative to specific performance when
trademark capital is involved. The argument calls attention to consumers
who, for idiosyncratic reasons, so much prefer specific performance
compared to a remedy of simple money damages that they would insist on a
penalty clause for nonperformance in the contract, except that contract
law does not permit inclusion of a penalty clause (since the presence of
a penalty clause would inhibit efficient breach and since it may cause a
party to attempt to induce an inefficient breach by the other party
[Posner 2011:160]). DeAlessi and Staaf (1994) find a workaround in brand
name capital: if a firm fails to provide specific performance, its
trademark capital suffers a loss, but the loss does not accrue as a gain
to the party suffering the breach. Thus, trademark capital can assure
specific performance, much like a penalty clause might if it were legal,
but without the drawback of creating the potential for opportunistic or
uncooperative behavior!
Despite its substantial investment in brand name capital, Hyundai
has chosen to compensate rather than perform specifically by recalling
its cars and refurbishing them to achieve 40 MPG. Obviously, whatever
the imperfections of the compensation scheme, they pale in comparison to
the costs that would be involved in achieving specific performance.
VII. Conclusion
Hyundai invested in trademark capital through its "Save the
Asterisk" campaign but did not deliver specific performance
(Ramstad 2012). Upon discovering the "procedural errors" in
its MPG calculations, Hyundai opted for a breach-with-damages approach
to remedy its mistake. This leads to the question; Under what
circumstances do we want specific performance? The company will not
pursue the specific performance option when specific performance is
overwhelmed by other considerations. Often, these considerations are the
associated transaction costs and administration costs (Kronman 1979b).
In the particular hypothetical case involving a superior platinum
component part, the transaction costs involved in collecting all of the
Elantras and installing the proper part ($10,000) outweigh the benefit
of specific performance ($8,000). In the factual case, the costs of
achieving specific performance apparently are similarly prohibitive.
Therefore, although the company has invested in trademark capital, there
was not specific performance. Rather, Hyundai has offered voluntary
compensation for breach of contract in order to minimize the cost of
maintaining its reputation while delivering to its customers the
approximate expected value from owning a Hyundai Elantra that gets 40
MPG. Although there is in fact only one actual case involving the
Hyundai Elantra, customized hypothetical versions of the case drove the
excursion through the economics of contract law.
References
American Bar Association Model Jury Instruction. 1996. [section]
_6.02[2]. Found in David R. Dow and Craig Smyser, Contract Law. Texas
Practice Series, Volume 49: 75-76. Thomson-West.
DeAlessi, Louis, and Staaf, Robert J. 1994. "What Does
Reputation Assure? The Relationship of Trademarks to Expectations and
Legal Remedies." Economic Inquiry 32 (3): 477-85.
Dnes, Antony W. 2005. The Economics of Law: Property, Contracts,
and Obligations. Canada: Thomson South-Western.
"EPA Investigation Prompts Carmaker to Correct Inflated
Mileage Claims," no date. Retrieved July 11, 2014
(http://epa.gov/fueleconomy/label change.htm).
Gobel v. Linn. 47 Mich. 489; 11 N.W. 284; 1882 Mich. LEXIS 673.
LexisNexis Academic. Web. 20 Dec. 2012.
Hadley v. Baxendale. 9 Ex. 341, 156 ng. Rep. 145 (Ct. of Exchequer
1854). http://mtweb.mtsu.edu/cewillis/Hadley%20v%20Baxendale.pdf. Web.
20 Dec. 2012.
Hardy, Charles O. 1979. "Risk and Risk Bearing." Pp
26-28. The Economics of Contract Law. Ed. Kronman, Anthony T. and
Posner, Richard A. New York: Basic Books Inc.
Hirsh, Jerry. "Attorneys object to proposed settlement in
Hyundai, Kia MPG claims." Los Angeles Times, June 2, 2014.
Retrieved July 11, 2014 (http://www.latimes.com/business/autos/la-fi
hy-hyundai-kia-inflated-fuel-economy-claims20140602-story.html)
Holmes Jr., O. Wendell. 1979. "The Common Law." Pp
298-305. The Economics of Contract Law. Ed. Kronman, Anthony T. and
Posner, Richard A. New York: Basic Books Inc.
Jacob & Youngs, Inc. vs. Kent. 230 N.Y. 239; 129 N.E. 889; 1921
N.Y. LEXIS 828; 23 A.L.R. 1429. LexisNexis Academic. Web. 20 Dec. 2012.
Kronman, Anthony T. 1979. "Mistake Disclosure Information and
the Law of Contracts." Pp 114-181. The Economics of Contract Law.
Ed. Kronman, Anthony T. and Posner, Richard A. New York: Basic Books
Inc.
Kronman, Anthony T. 1979. "Specific Performance." Pp
181-194. The Economics of Contract Law. Ed. Kronman, Anthony T. and
Posner, Richard A. New York: Basic Books Inc.
Konic International Corp. v. Spokane Computer Services, Inc. 109
Idaho 527; 708 P.2d 932; 1985 Ida. App. LEXIS 758. LexisNexis Academic.
Web. 20 Dec. 2012.
Posner, Richard A. 2011. Economic Analysis of Law, 8th ed. New
York, NY: Aspen Law & Business.
Posner, Richard. 1979. "Gratuitous Promises in Economics and
Law." Pp 46-58. The Economics of Contract Law. Ed. Kronman, Anthony
T. and Posner, Richard A. New York: Basic Books Inc.
Raffles v. Wichelhaus. 2 H. & C. 906, 159 Eng. Rep. 375 (Ct. of
Exchequer 1864). Holmes College. Retrieved December 20, 2012
(http://www.holmescollege.org/Students/2011_Contracts/Raffles%20v%20Wichelhaus%20Full%20 Text.pdf).
Ramstad, Evan and Ramsey, Mike. "Hyundai Surrenders 40 MPG
Claims." Wall Street Journal Retrieved November 2, 2012
(http://online.wsj .com/article/SB 10001424052970204712904578
094412515725112.html).
Sherwood v. Walker. 66 Mich. 568; 33 N.W. 919; 1887 Mich. LEXIS
525. LexisNexis Academic. Web. 20 Dec. 2012.
Tullock, Gordon. 1979. "The Logic of the Law." Pp 35-47.
The Economics of Contract Law. Ed. Kronman, Anthony T. and Posner,
Richard A. New York, NY: Basic Books Inc.
White, Joseph B. "Hitching the New Small Wagon to Better Fuel
Efficiency." Wall Street Journal 24 Dec. 2012. New York Ed.: Dl.
Retrieved December 24, 2012 (http://online.wsj.com/article/ SB
1000142412788732490720457818756038305 9762.html).
Corey Beck, College of the Holy Cross, Class of 2013. E-Mail:
cebeckl3@g.holycross.edu
David Schap, Professor, Department of Economics, College of the
Holy Cross, Worcester, MA 01610. E-Mail: dschap@holycross.edu Phone:
(508) 793-2688
The authors express thanks to the anonymous referee for helpful
comments.
Notes
(1.) Extortion can occur when damages exceed the amount that would
make the customer whole. The problem with extortion is twofold. The
first problem arises if a payment is made because of a threat of
contract completion. The customer might bribe the other party to breach
the contract and not complete it. Such a payment would occur if contract
completion would make the purchaser worse off relative to breach and
money damages. The threat always exists that the company might complete
the contract and the consumer will be relatively undercompensated. The
second problem is that transaction costs will inevitably increase as a
result of the opportunity for extortion and related strategic bargaining
(Posner 2011:143).
(2.) The more general principle is that if consumers will not be
compensated adequately for the failure of a contract, they will either
not enter into contracts at all or will increase the time spent and
detail in negotiating contracts (Posner 2011:150). In the instant case,
the lack of trust in advertising would manifest itself as a decline in
future demand for cars in the Hyundai product line, which implies a
lower future equilibrium price and lower equilibrium quantity transacted
in the future. Viewed from this perspective, Hyundai's payment of
$5,000 in damages mitigates its reputational loss and associated
profitability decline.
(3.) Posner (2011:149-158) explains how setting damages
appropriately in cases of intentional breach establishes precedent that
guides parties in the future to choose to breach a contract only in
circumstances in which breach frees resources to flow to a higher valued
use.
(4.) In Jacob & Youngs Inc. v. Kent, Jacob & Young's
Inc. did not install the correct brand of pipes into the
defendant's walls when building his home. The contract called for
Reading pipe to be installed. As a result of oversight by a
subcontractor, Jacob & Young's Inc. used Cohoes pipe. According
to the opinion of the court, the pipe used was of very similar quality.
However, Kent refused to pay the remainder of the fees for the
construction and Jacobs & Young's Inc. filed suit. The court
found that the action of taking out the pipe and replacing it with
Reading pipe would be inefficient. The court ruled that the brand of
pipes installed within walls did not need to be changed after the
installation was complete.
(5.) The Foreseeability Doctrine in part requires any extraordinary
knowledge to be disclosed for losses associated with that information to
be recoverable. The full implications of the Foreseeability Doctrine are
considered a bit later in this essay.
(6.) For example, suppose that two parties bet on the outcome of a
coin flip. The winning party gains the entire bet while the losing party
gets zero. Party A is involved in only one coin flip and consequently
will get the entire bet or nothing; the two extremes. Meanwhile, party B
is involved in this bet and 99 other similar bets. Consequently, party B
will get something closer to a 50/50 payout across all bets. Therefore,
party B should be assigned the risk because the standard deviation,
which is the standard measure of risk, is lower.
(7.) This is a fanciful version of what is currently happening
regarding EPA gas mileage calculations. The EPA is not without its own
errors (White 2012). The EPA allows car companies to do their own MPG
calculations and submit them for approval. Then, the EPA certifies these
calculations. Occasionally, the EPA will audit the calculations,
especially when there are consumer complaints as in the case of Hyundai
(Ramstad 2012).
(8.) In Sherwood vs. Walker, Sherwood agreed to buy a cow named
Rose the Second of Aberlone from Walker. At the time of the contract,
both parties assumed that the cow was not pregnant and was therefore
valued less than a pregnant cow. However, it was later discovered that
Rose was actually pregnant so Walker refused to sell the cow as per the
original contract. The court found that because there was a mutual
mistake, the contract did not need to be fulfilled.
(9.) Posner uses the example that if a contract for the sale of
wheat for $3 a bushel is agreed upon for a delivery date in the future,
a market price of $6 on the contract's delivery date does not make
the contract invalid (Posner 2011:129).
(10.) In Gobel v. Linn, the defendant argued that the beer company
he represented agreed to an increased price of ice under duress. In the
original contract, the plaintiff agreed to sell Gobel ice at a price of
$1.75 per ton. However, due to a failure of the ice crop, Linn notified
Gobel that the price had to be increased. Gobel agreed to the higher
price because ice is a necessary input to maintain beer and consequently
the company. After the ice was delivered, Gobel refused to pay and Linn
brought suit. The court found that extraordinary circumstances rendered
the first contract void. The ice company could not deliver on the
original contract. It had not chosen to increase the price with the
ability to fulfill the contract at the original price level (ice at
$1.75 per ton). Therefore, the case was over the new contract that Gobel
and Linn had both agreed to. The principle that emerged from this case
is that, if events out of a party's control arise that render a
contract void, new contracts that are negotiated are enforceable.
(11.) In Raffles v. Wichelhaus, the defendant agreed to buy cotton
from the plaintiff that would be shipped on the boat Peerless. However,
there were two ships names Peerless. The defendant expected the cotton
to arrive on the Peerless in October, but the plaintiff shipped the
cotton on the Peerless that arrived in December. The defendant refused
to accept the cotton from the December Peerless and the plaintiff sued.
The court held that the contract was for cotton delivered on a boat
named Peerless so the contract was valid. However, the dissenting
opinion points out that the ship Peerless was an ambiguous term.
Therefore, there was no meeting of the minds and no consideration
present because both parties were referencing different ships.
(12.) In Konic International Corp. v. Spokane Computer Services,
Inc., Konic contracted to sell a surge protector for "fifty-six
twenty" to Spokane. The employee of Spokane believed that this
price meant $56.20, but the price was actually $5,620. As a result,
Spokane refused delivery. When Spokane refused delivery, Konic sued for
breach of contract. The court found that there was no meeting of the
minds and therefore no consideration present. Spokane was not forced to
take the surge protector.
(13.) In Hadley v. Baxendale, the plaintiff lost profit when his
mill's crankshaft broke and was not replaced in the expected time
frame. The defendant who repaired the crankshaft stated if the
crankshaft was dropped off prior to noon it would be ready the next day.
The plaintiff did not express the urgency (potential lost profits), but
dropped off the crankshaft prior to noon expecting it to be repaired the
next day. However, due to the defendant's neglect the crankshaft
was not ready the next day. The court found that the defendant had no
way of knowing the extent of the damages from a delay in fixing the
crankshaft. Because the plaintiff did not disclose the urgency of fixing
the crankshaft (which was not ordinary knowledge), the defendant was not
found liable for damages related to lost profits.
(14.) Hardy (1979) points out that when a party accepts knowledge,
that party accepts risk.
(15.) Resolution by analogy is one way that a judge can determine
if a contract is enforceable. With this method, the judge can try to
determine what the parties would have done based on what they agreed to
do in a similar situation. The example that Tullock (1979:24) gives is
that if a flood destroys a house, the clause addressing an unintentional
fire could be applied.
(16.) Construction is the concept that Judge Holmes developed
whereby a case is ruled based on what the parties likely would have
built into the contract if they had foreseen the unforeseen circumstance
(Holmes 1979:30).