Homer Economicus: The Simpsons and Economics.
Luccasen, R. Andrew, III
Homer Economicus: The Simpsons and Economics, edited by Joshua
Hall, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2014.
Joshua Hall brings together a distinguished group of economists to
explain what one can learn about economics from watching the popular
television show The Simpsons. This book is intended for an audience with
little or no previous exposure to economics, and includes 16 chapters on
introductory topics organized into three sections. Often the book make
use of character studies (imagine Bart does this, or Homes does
that...), but most chapters draw on episodes from the fictional show as
anecdotal but intuitive evidence to illustrate basic economic concepts
presented in the chapter.
Part 1 provides an introduction to the economic way of thinking,
beginning with Anthony M. Carilli's overview emphasizing concepts
such as opportunity costs, scarcity and choice, and specialization. In
chapter 2, Douglas Rogers and Peter J. Boettke explain the role of
comparative advantage, prices, profits, and losses in organizing
economic activity. While chapters 1 and 2 reference many episodes, Art
Carden focuses on one episode in Chapter 3 to illustrate that people
respond to incentives, but often in ways that are not intended by
policymakers.
Part 2 is entitled "Money, Markets, and Government."
Andrew T. Young begins this section by examining episodes of The
Simpsons that illustrate the defining characteristics of money. Chapter
5 by Gregory M. Randolph reiterates the role of profits and losses in
allocating scarce resources, and also discusses how barriers to market
entry lead to abnormally high profits. Per L. Bylund, Christopher M.
Holbrook, and Peter G. Klein draw upon several episodes to discuss
entrepreneurship as a dynamic process. Diana W. Thomas provides examples
of market power and barriers to entry, public goods, and asymmetric
information as examples of market failure. Justin Ross continues the
theme of externalities by discussing the Coase Theorem and raises
questions concerning the ability of government action to improve upon
market externalities. John Considine, in turn, expands on the previous
chapter by citing episodes that illustrate government failure.
The topic of part 3 is "Applied Microeconomics." Focusing
on the case of Kwik-E-Mart manager Apu as well as the episode
"Coming to Homerica," Seth R. Gitter and Robert J. Gitter
begin this section with an economic analysis of immigration. Episodes
illustrating labor markets are discussed by David T. Mitchell, and
topics introduced include compensating differentials, job search, and
signaling. The complex market for healthcare services, including
asymmetric information, third-party payers, and medical licensing is
simplified for the reader by Lauren Heller. Chapter 13 uses one episode,
"Homer vs. The Eighteenth Amendment," as a case study of the
(unintended) effects of alcohol prohibition. Mark Thornton applies these
lessons to the parallel case of drug prohibition, arguing that such
prohibitions raise prices and therefore are associated with greater
crime, create an incentive to produce more potent products, and does not
appear to have any appreciable affect on consumption. Similarly, the
economic costs and benefits of legalized casino gambling, as illustrated
by "Springfield (Or, How I Stopped Worrying and Started to Love
Legalized Gambling)" are explained by Douglas M. Walker and Shannon
M. Kelly. Jodi Beggs tackles the topic of behavioral economics, using
various episodes to demonstrate time inconsistency, narrow bracketing,
reference-dependent utility, and the anchoring effect. Behavioral
economists may take issue with referring to behavioral traits discussed
as "irrational," as well as not delineating between biases and
heuristics. The final chapter by Steven Horwitz and Stewart Dompe does
reference individual episodes, but the authors point out improvements in
product quality evident in the show over the last twenty years (HDTV,
cell phones, and the internet) to discuss economic growth and standards
of living.
The interested instructor may assign Homer Economicus as engaging
supplementary reading or as a source for entertaining examples to use in
class. However, a few caveats are in order. Although several examples in
the book appear in previously published journals, the references to
these articles are missing. Many examples can be found in a 2010 paper I
coauthored with M. Kathleen Thomas entitled "Simpsonomics: Teaching
Economics Using Episodes of The Simpsons" {Journal of Economic
Education, Volume 41, Number 2, pp. 136-149.). If citing the book's
references, one should double check the source. For example, Joshua
Hall's 2010 paper with Mark Gillis entitled, "Using The
Simpsons to Improve Economic Instruction through Policy Analysis"
was published by this journal, The American Economist, but is listed as
being published by the American Economic Review. Finally, there is not a
section on macroeconomic topics. At the risk of sounding self-serving,
the interested teacher can refer to another paper published by this
journal (Andrew Luccasen, Michael Hammock, and M. Kathleen Thomas. 2011.
"Teaching Undergraduate Macroeconomics Using Cartoons." The
American Economist. Volume 56, Number 1, pp. 38-47). for examples from
The Simpsons (among other cartoons) that illustrate macroeconomic
principles.
Instructors who enjoy presenting a variety of perspectives in class
should know that the majority of chapters are from the Austrian
perspective. When market failures are discussed, the conjecture is that
government intervention is likely to worsen market outcomes rather than
improve upon them. Such libertarian exuberance may be off-putting for
some students. For example, one chapter argues that safety regulations
are unnecessary, as any safety differences in products would be
capitalized into prices. Whether or not one agrees with this policy
recommendation, instructors who want to promote critical analysis by
students may wish to counterbalance the book with articles, such as
Michael Sandel's recent article in the Journal of Economic
Perspectives entitled "Market Reasoning as Moral Reasoning: Why
Economists Should Re-engage with Political Philosophy" (2013.
Volume 27, Number 4, pp. 121-140).
With this in mind, the book is a relatable and provocative
introduction to the economic way of thinking. The intuition of economic
analysis is made not only entertaining but also memorable by referring
to scenes from The Simpsons. Instructors can use this book as a source
for entertaining examples to use in class and it would make a nice gift
not only for fans of The Simpsons, but also anyone looking for an
accessible introduction to economic analysis.
R. Andrew Luccasen, III
Economics and Finance
Mississippi University for Women