The multiplier effect: a classroom exercise.
Mago, Shakun D.
I. Introduction
The word fiscal comes from the root fisc, which refers to the
"treasury" of a government. Accordingly, fiscal policy refers
to the government's spending and taxing behavior. Most students are
aware that in response to the 2008 recession, the American Recovery and
Reinvestment Act was passed in February 2009. However, they are usually
unclear about how precisely the policy initiative was supposed to
stimulate the economy. The $831 billion package comprised both federal
tax incentives, and direct spending on infrastructure, education,
health, and energy. In light of the large and ever-increasing national
debt problem, a crucial part of the current economic discussion is which
fiscal policy mechanism is more effective increased government spending
or lower tax rates. There is a general perception that government
spending and tax cuts are equivalent in their impact and therefore are
interchangeable, i.e. a dollar increase in government expenditure
increases GDP by the same amount as a dollar decrease in taxes. Students
often believe that the appropriate policy prescription for fiscal
stimulus and economic growth depends solely on one's political
ideology, with the liberal activists recommending increased government
spending and the conservatives arguing for higher tax cuts. The media
sources and the political discussions tend to be highly partisan, and
the classroom presentation of formulae does not make the process any
less perplexing. The primary objective of this exercise is to
demonstrate a) how change in the fiscal policy parameters leads to a
change in GDP and b) which fiscal stimulus spending is more effective
(i.e. the difference between the expenditure multiplier and the tax
multiplier).
In this exercise, students alternatively take on the roles of
business owners, owners of capital and labor, and consumers. Through the
"bottoms-up" participatory approach they experience firsthand
the economic incentives and forces governing the multiplier process.
Going through a sequence of financial decisions of how much to save and
spend, students learn how the initial shock sets off a chain reaction,
leading to successive rounds of changes in spending and income. We
believe that this exercise creates a concrete mental image of the
multiplier process such that students are able to easily decipher how
their propensity to save/spend not only affects the income of other
sellers and the overall output production in the economy, but also their
income in the future. This simple framework can then be used to evaluate
the effect of relaxing standard assumptions, and to demonstrate the
impact of automatic stabilizers (which reduce the size of the
multiplier) such as taxes and transfer payments. Finally, this exercise
can be used to initiate a discussion on how the theoretical predictions
differ from the actual real-world results due to credit liquidity
restrictions, unemployment benefits, inflation, and governmental
inefficiency.
Our demonstration is ideal for smaller Principles of Macroeconomics
classes, and the benefits will be diminished in classes larger than 50
students. The initial exercise takes about 1525 minutes of class time,
and depending on the learning objectives, 25-50 minutes can be reserved
for discussion.
II. Step-By-Step Procedure For The Instructor
1. Some preparation needs to done before the start of the class.
Each student should receive a copy of the instructions and the record
sheets provided in the appendix. They must also have a pen or pencil and
a simple calculator. Before class, the instructor will need to prepare
classroom dollars in different denominations. It is easiest to use play
dollar bills, which are very inexpensive and available at most retail
stores. With regard to the breakdown of denominations, we recommend that
the instructor brings to class at least six $20 bills, ten $10 bills,
eighteen $5 bills and thirty five $1 bills. (1) The instructor must also
bring placards identifying various businesses and a financial lender or
a resident bank. The businesses range from large corporations employing
a number of workers such as American Car and American Steel & Ore,
to small self-employed businesses such as Rickety Rentals, Trader's
Food and Shimmery Shirts.
2. Recruit six volunteers: Five to serve as the business owners and
one to serve as the financial lender. (2) Hand all of them their
business placards, and ask them to face the class. The instructor acts
as the government with a fiscal stimulus plan. The remaining students
serve as the pool of potential workers and/or consumers. Not all
students can participate in this exercise, but in my experience, the
prospect of future participation is usually very effective in keeping
the entire class engaged.
3. Read the instructions aloud to the students. Reiterate that GDP
may be calculated using the expenditure approach (measure of all goods
and service produced) or using the factor payments approach (measure of
income earned by all factors of production). (3) Emphasize the following
assumptions:
a. Marginal Propensity of Consumption is 0.8.
b. This is a closed economy.
c. There are no taxes and transfer payments.
d. Firms have no inventories.
None of these assumptions are crucial in terms of the qualitative
aspects of the results. In fact, the later part of the exercise will
focus on the effects of relaxing these simplifying assumptions.
II.1 Expenditure Multiplier
4. We begin with the demonstration of the expenditure multiplier.
Announce that as the federal government, you would like stimulate the
economy by building and improving the national highway system. To
accomplish this you would need to buy road rollers and other
construction equipment (hereafter, simply referred to as
"cars") worth $100 from American Car. (4) Give $100 to
American Car (preferably broken into small denomination bills of two
$20, two $10, five $5 and fifteen $1; I usually ask the banker to assist
me in these transactions). Upon receiving the $100 from the Federal
government, American Car must make the production decision. A couple of
leading questions will guide the class through the production decision:
Does American Car have any inventory in its warehouse? (No, by
assumption.) By what amount should American Car increase its production?
($100.)
5. Next, note that when American Car produces $100 worth of cars it
must also pay its workers wages for their labor services, the lender an
interest on the borrowed loans, and its supplier (American Steel &
Ore) for the raw materials. In turn, American Steel & Ore must also
pay its workers and the financial lender. (5) In my experience, it is
never a problem to find students who are willing to work for American
Car and American Steel & Ore, and you can assign the first 4
students who volunteer as workers--2 for each business. Instruct the
students acting as business owners to make the factor payments. Suppose,
American Car pays its workers $20 each, buys $40 worth of raw material
from American Steel & Ore, and pays an interest of $10 on loans
secured from the lender, leaving it with a profit of $10. Next, American
Steel & Ore pays its workers a total wage of $30 and spends $2 in
interest payments, making a net profit of $8. (6)
6. Instruct all the students to record the appropriate allocations
in the record sheet (Table 1), and then ask what has been the initial
change in income or GDP in the economy. It should be fairly obvious that
the total income has increased by $100 (in our example, $70 as wages,
$18 as profit and $12 as interest). The answer would be the same if,
instead of the factor payments approach, students use the expenditure
approach to calculate the increase in GDP - cars worth $100 were
produced. Reiterate the point that, "each time a dollar in output
is produced, a dollar in income is created."
7. Given the increase in income, student participants will be able
to consume more. Since taxes are assumed to be zero, a $100 increase in
income is also a $100 increase in disposable income. For the sake of
simplicity, we will restrict consumption to basic necessities like food,
clothing and housing. A series of leading questions will guide the class
through the consumption decisions. Do you have to pay any taxes? (No, by
assumption) How much of the additional income is available for
consumption? (All of it) What percentage of your income would you
consume? (MPC = 0.8). What do you do with your savings? (Save/ put it in
the bank). (7) In our example, workers will spend $56 (0.8 of the wages
of $70), American Car and American Steel & Ore will spend $14.4 (0.8
of the profit of $18) and the lender/banker will spend $9.6 (0.8 of the
interest income of $12) on Trader's Food, Shimmery Shirts and
Rickety Rentals.
Thus, the total increase in spending will be $80 (=0.8*$100).
Instruct the business owners, the financial lender and the workers to
make their consumption decisions and ask the students to record the
total change in their record sheets. Suppose, in response to these
consumption decisions, Trader's Food and Shimmery Shirts produce
food and clothing worth $20 each, and Rickety Rentals produces housing
services worth $40. (8)
8. Before proceeding further, ask the class what is the change in
income as a result of this second round increase in consumption spending
on food, clothing and housing ($80). Employing the expenditure approach,
students will note that $100 worth of car and $80 worth of food,
clothing and housing services were produced. Employing the factor
payments approach, it is easy to compute that the wages for workers, the
interest income for the lender, and the profit for all 5 businesses
totals $180. The instructor should record this second round increase in
GDP on the board, and point out that although the government increased
its spending by $100, the total change in GDP is $ 180. Thus, when
consumers spend an additional $80 on consumption, firms that produce
those goods and services will earn an additional $80 in sales revenue,
which in turn, will become income for the households that supply those
resources to these firms.
9. It is not necessary to repeat this procedure for many rounds,
but the instructor may wish to do at least one more round of consumption
spending to demonstrate the change in income. In the interest of time,
this may be done amongst the four business owners (with the exclusion of
American Steel & Ore). For instance, suppose Rickety Rentals, who
earns income of $40 and spends 80 percent of it, has the following
expenditure breakdown $20 on American Car, $6 each on Shimmery Shirts
and Trader's Food. Similar transactions can be made by the other
two businesses, Shimmery Shirts and Trader's Food who earned an
income of $20 each. The instructor should ask the class what is the
change in income as a result of this second round of consumption
spending (0.8*$80 = $64), and should also record this third round
increase in GDP on the board while students make appropriate entries on
their record sheets.
10. By this point in the exercise, it should be obvious to the
students that the initial increase in government spending leads to much
greater increase in GDP. They also grasp that the increase in GDP is
smaller at each stage (each successive round of additional spending is
80 percent of the previous round income), and the process must
eventually end. At this point, the standard discussion of MPC and the
expenditure multiplier can be used to show that the initial spending of
$100, with a MPC of 0.8, will lead to a total increase in GDP by $500.9
Before proceeding further, it would be useful to summarize the
change in GDP for each round, and the aggregate change in GDP in the
summary section of the record sheet. The students can use this to
contrast the expenditure multiplier with the tax multiplier, described
later.
11.2 Relaxing the Standard Assumptions
1. MPC: Ask the students what will be the increase in GDP if MPC
was 0.6, instead of 0.8. (or the instructor could use whatever MPC
amount is used in the assigned text). It is not necessary to go through
the entire calculation in class, and we recommend that the instructor
use the summary sheet instead. It is instructive to show that although
the first round increase in GDP remains at $100, in the second round GDP
increases by $60 and in the third round by $36. Ask the class to
calculate the total change in GDP ($250 = 1/1-0.6 * 100). Next, ask them
to re-do the calculations of each of the three rounds and for the total
change in GDP when MPC is 0.9 ($1000). These numerical examples should
amply display that the value of expenditure multiplier (and therefore,
the impact of spending on GDP) is positively related to the MPC.
Detailed calculations with varying MPC levels (Table 2) can be assigned
as a homework problem. Emerson (2011) is a nice supplementary reading on
the history of MPC in the U.S., and can also be assigned as an optional
homework assignment after the in-class exercise.
2. Imports: In the U.S. for every additional dollar of spending, 15
cents goes to imports. Even goods made domestically have many imported
components. If the additional spending is on goods and services imported
from abroad, then these spending changes do not stimulate additional
domestic production that can power the next round of the multiplier,
causing a much smaller change in GDP in subsequent rounds. To
demonstrate this, assume that Shimmery Shirts is not based in the U.S.
but in Mexico. Redo the calculations. The first round increase in income
and spending remains at $100 but in the second round, goods and services
produced in U.S. amount to $60 (instead of $80). This in turn, affects
the consumption spending in the third round and so on. Table 3 contains
the corresponding record sheet. After a brief in-class discussion this
can be assigned as a homework problem.
3. Taxes and Transfer Payments: So far, we have assumed that there
are no taxes and transfer payments. Thus, when government spending
increased by $100, both income and disposable income rose by $100 and in
the next round of multiplier process both households and businesses
spend 80 percent of their disposable income, or $80. But in the real
world, as income rises some taxes such as payroll and income taxes
automatically rise and some transfer payments such as unemployment
benefits automatically fall. As a result, the increase in (disposable)
income is smaller in each round, resulting in an even smaller rise in
consumption in the subsequent rounds. To demonstrate this, relate the
following scenario: Suppose American Car, which has 2 workers, hired one
of its workers only when it received the government stimulus of $100.
Suppose this worker who receives a wage of $20 had previously received
an unemployment benefit of $10. Thus, the increase in his disposable
income is not by $20 but only by $10. Further suppose that as income
rises by $100, the government collects a total of $15 in taxes from all
entities. Combining the two, net taxes (= taxes - transfer payments)
increase by $25. As a result, when the income increases by $100 in round
1, the disposable income increases only by $75. In the next round of the
multiplier process, consumption spending (and income) increase only
0.8*75 = $60. We believe that by this point in the demonstration it is
not necessary to redo the entire calculations, but asking students a
series of leading questions would yield a fruitful discussion on how
taxes and transfer payments reduce the impact of fiscal spending. Be
certain to point out that such factors that reduce the size of the
multiplier are called automatic stabilizers.
4. Inventories: This assumption can be relaxed by discussing the
simplest case - one where American Car has $100 worth of inventory in
its warehouse. This means that an increase in the purchases by the U.S.
government does not automatically lead to any increase in the production
by American Car, and the multiplier process fails to commence. This is
usually suffice to drive home the argument that spending changes that
fail to stimulate additional domestic production have no lasting impact
on the GDP.
In our experience, it is important to spend sufficient time
explaining each step of the initial simulation. Recruiting volunteers,
reading instructions (staged at the beginning of each individual round),
answering queries and then the exercise itself usually takes about 15-25
minutes. We recommend that any questions that do not directly pertain to
the initial exercise be postponed for the expost discussion. (10) The
second part of the exercise comprising the relaxing of standard
assumptions is more amendable to the time constraint. For instance, as
mentioned earlier, varying levels of MPC (Table 2) and imports (Table 3)
serve as useful homework problems after only a brief discussion.
However, we recommend that the instructor spends some time discussing
the net taxes. The latter is a good segue to the tax multiplier,
described below.
11.3 Tax Multiplier
To demonstrate the tax multiplier, we recreate the scenario of the
2008 Bush tax cuts where tax cuts were given to all households below a
certain income limit. (11) Reiterate that all students in the class are
households. Some may be employed, some may be unemployed, and yet others
may be Social Security recipients. Suppose government passes a stimulus
bill of $100, but instead of increased spending, a $100 tax cut is
proposed. Distribute $100 among some students and ask them what they
will do with their additional income. The answers may range from buying
new clothes, books, televisions etc., to going on an exotic vacation, to
paying off credit card debt, to putting all the money in the bank. A
series of leading questions will guide the class through the consumption
decisions - (a) As an economy, how much of the additional income is
available for consumption, i.e. what is the increase in disposable
income? ($ 100) (b) As an economy, what percentage of your income would
you consume? (MPC =
0.8, by assumption), (c) As a result of economywide increased
consumption spending, what is the first round increase in GDP ($80 =
$100*0.8) (d) How does this initial increase in the GDP compare when the
stimulus spending is in the form of governmental purchase from American
Car vs. tax cuts for all households? Students should readily see that
government spending leads to a dollar-for-dollar increase in aggregate
spending; but in case of tax cuts, the impact on spending comes
indirectly through an effect on household's disposable income. This
means that if households' after tax income (disposable income)
rises by $ 100, they will increase their consumption not by full $100,
but only by a fraction of it.
What happens after the initial rise in GDP by $80? When households
spend an additional $80, firms that produce consumption goods and
services will earn an additional $80 in sales revenue, which in turn,
will become income for the households that supply resources to these
firms, and the cycle of multiplier process proceeds as before. Thus, the
series of the subsequent increase are the same, except that for tax cut,
the first $100 is missing. This difference between the expenditure and
the tax multiplier becomes very evident in the summary section of the
record sheet. Since $100 increase in government spending increases GDP
by $500, a $100 cut in taxes must raise GDP by $400 (= $500 - $100). At
this point, the standard discussion of the MPC and the tax multiplier
can be used to show that tax cuts of $100, with a MPC of 0.8, will lead
to a total increase in GDP by $400 (= -0.8/1 -0.8 x -100).
III. Discussion
After the initial simulation, students should be encouraged to ask
questions, although some answers may be postponed until after the entire
demonstration is over. Below we list some common concerns and suggest
plausible responses. (12)
1. Real world evidence on the multipliers: There is a vast
empirical literature studying the fiscal multiplier, and the summary of
this literature is that the multiplier is somewhere in the range of 0.7
to 1.0 (see Hall, 2009 for a discussion of the empirical findings). All
economists acknowledge that the size of the multiplier varies according
to the economic conditions and various other factors (discussed below).
But since there is no general consensus on the precise impact, the
debate of spending vs. tax multiplier rages on (Auerbach and Gale,
2009). For instance, economists in the Obama administration, who assumed
that the federal interest rate will stay constant for a four-year
period, estimated a multiplier of 1.6 for government spending and 1.0
for tax cuts. (13) Other economists, such as Barro (2010) estimate the
spending multiplier to be between 0.4-0.6 and the tax multiplier to be
equal to 1.1.
2. MPC: Students frequently find it suspicious that the MPC for all
entities--individual workers, small or large businesses--is assumed to
be homogenous. Since both the expenditure and the tax multiplier rely on
the value of MPC, it casts a shadow on the credibility of the
demonstration. However, by the end of the exercise when students have a
vivid picture of the multiplier process, they will be able to decipher
fairly easily that this is only a simplifying assumption. Indeed, all
consumption is not homogeneous, and some consumption may be seen as more
beneficial to the economy than others. The ex-post discussion can focus
on situations with varying MPC. Some examples are:
-- Government spending on 'shovel ready' infrastructural
projects has a bigger multiplier effect than a tax cut especially if
consumers save a portion of their tax windfall. Historic examples
include the New Deal and the Hoover Dam project.
-- An individual with above average income and/or wealth will have
a lower marginal propensity to consume compared to a worker with minimum
wage income. Thus, a tax cut targeted at poorer sections of the society
may have a bigger impact on spending than one meant for the more
affluent members. Other individuals with a higher MPC include the
unemployed, students, families with young children, social security
recipients, consumers close to their borrowing limit etc. (14)
-- Consumers may be forward looking and therefore, the overall size
of the fiscal multiplier depends on how people react to the higher cash
inflow. In case of tax rebates and payroll tax cuts, if consumers
realize that the extra cash flow is temporary then their consumption
spending is less sensitive to the changes in current income, producing a
smaller multiplier effect. For instance, only about one-fifth of
respondents in the Reuters/University of Michigan survey report that the
2008 tax rebates led them to mostly increase spending, while over half
said it would lead them to mostly pay off their existing debt (Sahm,
Shapiro and Slemrod, 2009). Additionally, it is important to recognize
the importance of the time horizon--while the decision to pay off the
personal debt may reduce the multiplier effect in the short run, in the
long run the potential for increased leverage can stimulate both
consumption and investment. The precise impact of such intertemporal
substitution mechanism on the expansionary effects of fiscal stimuli is
not clear and has aroused considerable interest in the political and
academic arena, especially in the last two years. (15)
Fiscal multipliers can also to be used to demonstrate the
"Paradox of Thrift." When households and firms cut their
spending in anticipation of tough economic times, the slump in spending
causes a fall in equilibrium GDP that is several times larger than the
original decrease in spending. Thus seemingly virtuous
behavior--cautious saving for hard times--ends up harming everyone while
seemingly reckless behavior makes everyone better off.
3. Other economic variables that affect the fiscal multiplier:
--Current state of the economy: Consistent with the classical view,
in the long run as the economy approaches the full employment level of
output the fiscal multiplier should be close to zero. "Since there
are no spare resources, any increase in government demand would just
replace spending elsewhere. But in a recession, (in accordance to the
Keynesian view) when workers and factories lie idle, a fiscal boost can
increase overall demand. And if the initial stimulus triggers a cascade
of expenditure among consumers and businesses, the multiplier can be
well above one." (Economist 2009).
--War versus Peace: Some economists argue that fiscal multiplier
differs in war and peace times fiscal stimulus is welfare improving for
a wartime event when most of the spending is defense related but is
likely to be welfare reducing for a recessionary event (Andolfatto
2010).
--Forward looking behavior: If government's actions bolster
confidence in the markets and revive the animal spirits, then
consumption and private investment gets "crowded in" and the
multiplier effect increases. But if households anticipate higher taxes
in the future to finance increased governmental spending, or if interest
rates climb in response to government borrowing then consumption and
private investment could get "crowded out" reducing the impact
of the fiscal multiplier. This may be a good starting point to introduce
a debate on the impact of austerity measures followed by Europe versus
the discretionary spending done by the U.S. in response to the 2008
global recession.
4. Impact of Fiscal Policy versus Monetary Policy: Even those who
do not ascribe to the policy of laissez-faire when it comes to
government intervention, acknowledge that fiscal policy can be too
ham-fisted in practice. One practical problem that limits the
effectiveness of discretionary fiscal policy is timing. Given the
visceral disagreements within the political establishment on how the
benefits of increased spending or tax cuts should be distributed among
the general populace, it can take too long to design and pass the
necessary fiscal legislation. Second, problems persist both with
increased spending and tax cuts. As noted above, most of the money
generated by tax cuts is saved, not spent. The task of finding
appropriate 'shovel ready' spending projects is also clumsy at
best, and only 3 percent of the last stimulus was spent on
infrastructure. Furthermore, spending increased only at the federal
level, and money given to the state governments was spent on reducing
the states' reliance on borrowing and on other
"non-purchase" items, such as subsidies, and interest
payments. Finally, to be effective, discretionary fiscal policy must be
reversible, but reversing changes in government spending or tax cuts
have become increasingly difficult. This is evident in the recent debate
over extending the tax cuts implemented by the Bush administration in
2001 and 2003. Similarly, spending programs that create new departments,
or expand existing departments become difficult to eliminate. As a
consequence of these fiscal policy pitfalls, the Federal Reserve has
taken over the main role in reacting to and smoothing out economic
fluctuations over the past five decades. In most cases, it can act more
rapidly and with greater flexibility. One exception is the recent 2008
recession. With unemployment hovering around 10 percent and with
interest rates close to zero, a large fiscal stimulus package was needed
to supplement both the conventional and non-conventional monetary policy
tools employed by the Fed.
Appendix
Instructions
This exercise demonstrates how federal government can stimulate the
economy through increased spending and tax cuts. There will be an
opportunity for many of you to play a role in this exercise. There will
be 2 large businesses: American Car and American Steel & Ore. There
will be 3 small businesses: Rickety Rentals, Trader's Food and
Shimmery Shirts. In addition, there will be a financial lender. Others
in the class will have the opportunity to play the role of workers and/
consumers. I will act as the government with a fiscal stimulus plan.
In the beginning of the exercise, we will make some simplifying
assumptions. These are not restrictive and we shall relax them later in
the exercise. These assumptions are:
a. Marginal Propensity of Consumption is 0.8. For example, if you
receive an additional income of $10, you will consume $8 (=0.8*10) and
save the remaining $2.
b. This is a closed economy, so there are no exports or imports.
c. There are no taxes and transfer payments.
d. Firms have no inventory.
Instructions for Round 1: As the federal government, I will
introduce a fiscal stimulus bill aimed at improving the National Highway
System. To accomplish this, I need to buy road rollers and other
construction equipment (hereafter, simply referred to as
"cars") worth $100 from American Car. Since the firm has no
inventory (by assumption), an increase in purchases automatically leads
to the same amount of increase in production for American Car. American
Car will have to pay its factors of production--(a) American Steel &
Ore for raw materials, (b) wages to its 2 workers, and (c) interest
payment to the financial lender. It can keep the remaining amount as its
profit. Next, American Steel & Ore has to pay wages to its 2 workers
and interest payments to the financial lender. It can keep the remaining
amount as its profit. After the two businesses decide on their
allocation decisions:
-- Please make the necessary entries in your record sheet.
-- Calculate the total increase in income or GDP using both
expenditure and factor payments method (Column 2).
-- Calculate the increase in consumption spending as a result of
increased income (Column 3).
Instructions for Round 2: Because of increased income, workers and
businesses will be able to consume more. For the sake of simplicity we
restrict consumption to basic necessities like food, clothing and
housing. At this point, all participants with increased income should
decide on their consumption allocation for Rickety Rentals,
Trader's Food and Shimmery Shirts. After the two businesses and the
4 workers decide on their allocation decisions:
-- Please make the necessary entries in your record sheet.
-- Calculate the total increase in income or GDP using both
expenditure and factor payments method (Column 2).
-- Calculate the increase in consumption spending as a result of
the increased income (Column 3).
Instructions for Round 3: Suppose consumption decisions are
restricted to the 3 small businesses. That is, Rickety Rentals can spend
its increased income on Shimmery Shirts, Trader's Food and/or
American Car. Similarly, for the other 2 small businesses. After the
three small businesses decide on their allocation decisions:
-- Please make the necessary entries in your record sheet.
-- Calculate the total increase in income or GDP using both the
expenditure and factor payments method (Column 2).
-- Calculate the increase in consumption spending as a result of
the increased income (Column 3).
Record Sheets (Accompanying the Instructions)
TABLE 1.
Increase in Government Spending by $100 when MPC = 0.8
Round # Expenditure Approach Factor Payments Approach
Round 1 Income
American Car Car = Wages =
Profit =
Interest =
Cost of Raw Material =
American Steel & Ore Wages =
Interest =
Profit =
Change in GDP =
Round 2 Income
Trader's Food Food = Wages & Profit =
Shimmery Shirts Shirts = Wages & Profit =
Rickety Rentals Housing = Wages & Profit =
Change in GDP =
Round 3 Income
Trader's Food Food = Wages & Profit =
Shimmery Shirts Shirts = Wages & Profit =
Rickety Rentals Housing = Wages & Profit =
American Car Car = Wages & Profit =
Change in GDP =
Round # MPC = 0.8
Round 1 Spending
American Car Consumption/ Business Spending
= MPC* Change in Income
=
American Steel & Ore
Change in Spending =
Round 2 Spending
Trader's Food Consumption/ Business Spending
Shimmery Shirts = MPC* Change in Income
Rickety Rentals =
Change in Spending =
Round 3 Spending
Trader's Food Consumption/ Business Spending
Shimmery Shirts = MPC* Change in Income
Rickety Rentals =
American Car
Change in Spending =
Change in GDP = First Round + Second Round + Third Round
Total Change in GDP == 1 / 1 - MPC * [DELTA] Spending
Summary Result: Change in GDP is higher/ lower/ the same
as the initial change in spending, (i.e. value of the
Expenditure Multiplier is greater than one)
TABLE 2.
Relaxing Standard Assumptions #1: MPC Suppose MPC - 0.6 instead of 0.8
Round # Expenditure Approach Factor Payments Approach
Round 1 Income
American Car Car = Wages =
Profit =
Interest =
Cost of Raw Material =
American Steel & Ore Wages =
Interest =
Profit =
Change in GDP =
Round 2 Income
Trader's Food Food = Wages & Profit =
Shimmery Shirts Shirts = Wages & Profit =
Rickety Rentals Housing = Wages & Profit =
Change in GDP =
Round 3 Income
Trader's Food Food = Wages & Profit =
Shimmery Shirts Shirts = Wages & Profit =
Rickety Rentals Housing = Wages & Profit =
American Car Car = Wages & Profit =
Change in GDP =
Round # MPC = 0.6
Round 1 Spending
American Car Consumption/ Business Spending
= MPC* Change in Income
=
American Steel & Ore
Change in Spending =
Round 2 Spending
Trader's Food Consumption/ Business Spending
Shimmery Shirts = MPC* Change in Income
Rickety Rentals =
Change in Spending =
Round 3 Spending
Trader's Food Consumption/ Business Spending
Shimmery Shirts = MPC* Change in Income
Rickety Rentals =
American Car
Change in Spending =
Change in GDP = First Round + Second Round + Third Round
Total Change in GDP == 1 / 1 - MPC * [DELTA]Spending
Summary Result: Change in GDP (i.e. value of the
Expenditure Multiplier) is higher/ lower/ the same
when the MPC is lower.
TABLE 3.
Relaxing Standard Assumptions #2: Imports (i.e. Open Economy)
Suppose Shimmery Shirts is not a U.S.firm, hut instead it is
based in Mexico. Consumers and businesses spend some of their
income on Shimmery Shirts in Round 2, but this Round 2 spending
is transferred out of U.S. and no longer affects future income or
spending.
Round # Expenditure Approach Factor Payments Approach
Round 1 Income
American Car Car = Wages =
Profit =
Interest =
Cost of Raw Material =
American Steel Wages =
& Ore Interest =
Profit =
Change in GDP =
Round 2 Income
Trader's Food Food = Wages & Profit =
Shimmery Shirts Shirts = Wages & Profit =
Rickety Rentals Housing = Change in GDP = Wages & Profit =
Round 3 Income
Trader's Food Food = Wages & Profit =
Shimmery Shirts Shirts = Wages & Profit =
Rickety Rentals Housing = Wages & Profit =
American Car Car = Wages & Profit =
Change in GDP =
Round # MPC = 0.8
Round 1 Spending
American Car Consumption/Business Spending
= MPC* Change in Income =
American Steel
& Ore
Change in Spending =
Round 2 Spending
Trader's Food Consumption/Business Spending
Shimmery Shirts = MPC* Change in Income =
Rickety Rentals Change in Spending =
Round 3 Spending
Trader's Food Consumption/Business Spending
Shimmery Shirts = MPC* Change in Income =
Rickety Rentals
American Car
Change in Spending =
Change in GDP = First Round + Second Round + Third Roilnd
Total Change in GDP = 1 / 1 - MPC * [DELTA]Spending
Summary Result: Change in GDP (i.e. value of the Expenditure
Multiplier) is higher/ lower/ the same when additional spending is on
goods and services imported from abroad.
Summary Sheet
A.1 Increase in Government Spending by $100 when MPC = 0.8 (Table
1)
Change in GDP __/First Round + __/Second Round + __/Third Round
Total Change in GDP = 1/1-MPC
* [DELTA] Government Spending
A. 2 Increase in Government Spending by $100 when MPC = 0.6 (Table
2)
Change in GDP __/First Round + __/Second Round + __/Third Round
Total Change in GDP = 1/1- MPC * [DELTA] Government Spending
Summary Result: Change in GDP (i.e. value of the Expenditure
Multiplier) is higher/ lower/ the same when the MPC is lower.
B. Tax Cuts of $100 when MPC = 0.8
Change in GDP __/First Round + __/Second Round + __/Third Round
Total Change in GDP = - MPC/1 - MPC * [DELTA] Tax
=
Summary Result: Change in GDP is higher/ lower/ the same when the
fiscal stimulus is in the form of increased government spending rather
than lower taxes.
References
Andolfatto, D. 2010. "Fiscal Multipliers in War and in
Peace." Federal Reserx'e Bank of St. Louis Review 92(2):
121-27.
Auerbach, A. J. and Gale, W. G. 2009. "Activist Fiscal Policy
to Stabilize Economic Activity." NBER Working Paper 15407, National
Bureau of Economic Research (October 2009).
Barro, R. J. 2010. "The Stimulus Evidence One Year On."
The Wall Street Journal (February 23, 2010).
Cogan, J. F., Cwik, T., Taylor, J. B. and Wieland, V. 2010.
"New Keynesian versus Old Keynesian Government Spending
Multipliers." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34(3):
281-295.
Emerson, J. 2011. "Consumption-Saving Investigation: United
States." Journal of Economic Educators 11(1): 39-46.
Hall, R. E. 2009. "By How Much Does GDP Rise if the Government
Buys More Output?" NBER Working Paper 15496, National Bureau of
Economic Research (November 2009).
Laury, S. and Holt, C. 2000. "Classroom Games: Making
Money." Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(2): 205-213.
"Much ado about Multipliers." The Economist (September
24, 2009).
Krugman, P. 2012. "The Conscience of a Liberal." The New
York Times (October 9, 2012).
Sahm, C. R., Shapiro, M. D. and Slemrod, J. B. 2009.
"Household Response to the 2008 Tax Rebates: Survey Evidence and
Aggregate Implications." NBER Working Paper 15421, National Bureau
of Economic Research (October 2009).
Zandi, M. 2008. "A Second Quick Boost From Government Could
Spark Recovery." Edited excerpts from Congressional Testimony (July
24, 2008).
Uhlig, H. 2010. "Some Fiscal Calculus." American Economic
Review, P&P 100(2): 30-34.
Notes
(1.) This amounts to $340 which is greater than the total spending
in the demonstration ($244). The extra reserve of different
denominations allows the instructor and/or the banker to provide smaller
denomination bills as needed for the later rounds of the simulation.
(2.) The bank does not play a pivotal role in this fiscal policy
demonstration, and the instructor can choose not to employ the
"financial lender" without comprising student learning.
However, inclusion of the lender reinforces the way in which interest
payments factor into the GDP calculations. It also allows for greater
student participation, and the instructor can ask the banker to assist
in the moneyed transactions e.g. counting the bills, making change for
smaller denomination bills etc. Finally, and perhaps most importantly,
the banker provides a point of continuity if the instructor wishes to
follow-up this fiscal multiplier exercise with the money multiplier
exercise. We recommend the "Making Money" classroom game
(Laury and Holt, 2000) that focuses on the process of money multiplier
through multiple creation of deposits. In fact, this exercise is
inspired by the latter demonstration.
(3.) The instructor can chose only one approach without adversely
affecting student learning. Record sheets can be easily modified by
eliminating the corresponding column.
(4.) For ease of calculation, we keep the stimulus amount small at
$100, but during the ex-post discussion, the instructor can reiterate
that the fiscal stimulus bill of 2008 was worth $831 billion.
(5.) Since ore is mined from the ground, the cost of raw materials
is assumed to be zero.
(6.) These numbers are purely for illustrative purposes. It is
imperative to allow firms (students) to make their own allocation
decisions. Since the remaining students in the class serve as a pool of
potential workers, it is usually very straightforward for the firms to
hire workers. However, to avoid several rounds of wage negotiations,
which would likely slow down the experiment and detract attention from
its main point, instructor can also choose to assign a wage rate per
worker. The latter may or may not differ by industry/firm.
(7.) Our focus is solely on the fiscal policy decisions, and we
want to abstract from any interaction with the monetary policy. However,
some students might question why banks cannot loan out the consumer
saving deposits this not only puts more money in the hands of the
consumers but the lender also makes additional profit. A succinct
response would be that the multiplier effect is further amplified in the
presence of banks. However, this query is best answered at a later date.
(8.) We have already demonstrated the relation between a business
and its raw material supplier (American Car and American Steel &
Ore). Therefore, for the sake of simplicity, we will assume that cost of
raw materials for these small, self-employed business owners is zero and
they retain their entire income as profit. This assumption can be easily
modified to reflect a more plausible scenario (for e.g. Trader's
Food may buy its raw materials from Forest Farms etc.) but it makes the
demonstration needlessly complicated.
(9.) To derive the multiplier formula, we start with the numerical
values in our example.
The change in GDP: AGDP = 100 + 80 + 64 + 51.2 +......
Factoring out $100, we get: [DELTA] GDP = 100* (1 + 0.8 +
[0.8.sup.2] + [0.8.sup.3] +.....)
In our example, $100 was the initial increase in government
spending and 0.8 was assumed to be the value of MPC. Generalizing for
any change in spending or any value of MPC, we get [DELTA[GDP =
[DELTA]Spending *(1 + (MPC) + [(MPC).sup.2] + [(MPC).sup.3] +....).
Applying the formula for sum of infinite geometric series, we get
[DELTA] GDP - [DELTA] Spending * {1/(1 - MPC)}.
(10.) The instructor can make a note of the queries on the board.
In our experience, students are able to answer most of the queries
themselves by the end of the exercise.
(11.) Most taxpayers below the threshold income limit received a
rebate of at least $300 per person ($600 for married couples filing
jointly). For people with an income tax greater than $300 (or $600 in
case of married couples), the tax rebate was equal to the payer's
net income tax liability, but could not exceed $600 (for a single
person) or $1200 (for married couple filing jointly). Those with
dependent children received an additional $300 per child.
(12.) An easy to read article from the Economist (2009) can also be
assigned as a homework reading after the in-class exercise.
(13.) In the congressional testimony given in July 2008, Mark
Zandi, the chief economist for Moody's Economy.com, provided
estimates of the one-year multiplier effect for several fiscal policy
options. He testified that any form of increased government spending
would have more of a multiplier effect than a tax cut of an equivalent
amount. For instance, the lowest multiplier for a spending increase
(general aid to state governments, 1.36) had a higher multiplier effect
than the highest tax multiplier. Among tax cuts, multipliers ranged from
1.29 for a payroll tax holiday down to 0.27 for accelerated
depreciation. It bears pointing out that refundable lump-sum tax
rebates, the policy used in the Economic Stimulus Act of 2008, had the
second-largest multiplier for a tax cut, 1.26.
(14.) This explains why Zandi (2008) estimated that the most
effective policy is a temporary increase in food stamps, with an
estimated multiplier of 1.73.
(15.) For instance, Krugman's (2012) short run analysis can be
contrasted with the long run prognosis discussed by Cogan, et al. (2010)
and Uhlig (2010).
Shakun D. Mago
Department of Economics, Robins School of Business, University of
Richmond, 1 Gateway Road, Richmond, VA 23173. E-mail:
sdatta@richmond.edu; Phone: 804-287-6631, Fax: 804-289-8878
I would like to thank the participants of the National Conference
on Teaching Economics 2012 for helpful comments and suggestions.