What really happens in the Solow model: technological progress versus population growth?
Quinn, Kevin ; Hoag, John
This paper has two objectives. First, it presents the Solow model
in a way that is intuitive for students. Second, it applies the
presentation to show that more can be learned by looking at the model
this way.
In the standard model, the basic expository device is the Solow
diagram where the levels of output, saving and break-even investment per
efficiency unit are plotted as function of capital per efficiency unit
(k and y hereafter). This exposition identifies steady state levels of K
and Y per efficiency unit. Comparative static exercises then look at how
the steady state levels change when parameters such as the savings rate,
the rate of population growth (n) or the rate of growth of efficiency
(g) are changed. Often the results are coupled with a picture of the
implied time-path of k or y from the initial to the new steady state.
There are two problems with this approach. First, it is difficult
for the student to make the connection between the diagram involving
levels and the time path of the transition from one steady state to
another. In addition, because the diagram concentrates on capital and
output per efficiency unit, it is difficult to see the implication for
the growth rates and time-paths of capital and output per capita, which
are the variables which matter for welfare.
Second, and more importantly, focus on the per efficiency unit
variables obscures the huge differences for welfare between an increase
in n, the population growth rate, and an increase in g, the growth rate
of efficiency. Both of these changes reduce the steady-state value of
output and capital per efficiency unit, but the one decreases while the
other increases the level of capital and output per capita at every date
in the future compared to what they would have been with no change.
Our solution to both problems is to do the analysis of the steady
state not with the Solow diagram, but with growth rates, not levels, of
K/L or Y/L (not K/LE or Y/LE) expressed as functions of capital per
efficiency unit. It is much easier to see the connection with the
time-path for the levels of each when we look at the model expressed in
terms of growth rates. We work explicitly with growth rates of the per
capita variables, so different implications of changes in the same
direction of n and g are obvious.
I. The growth rate of K/L and why it matters
As a first step, we will find the relationship between the
percentage growth of k and the percentage growth of (K/L), which we
denote as K. By definition, k = (K/L)/E = [kappa]/E. Therefore, two
important relationships hold.
ln k = ln([kappa]) - ln E, so ln [kappa] = ln k + ln E (1)
Before proceeding to the implications of this equation for [kappa],
we relate K to what really matters: per-capita output. In general the
growth in Y/L, per-capita output, is directly related to k and,
therefore to growth in k and E. In the case of Cobb-Douglas production
with constant returns to scale, Y = [K.sup.[alpha]][(LE).sup.1-[alpha]]
so that Y/L = [(K/L).sup.[alpha]][E.sup.1-[alpha]]. It follows that
[DELTA](Y/L)/(Y/L) = [alpha] [DELTA]([kappa])/([kappa]) + (1 - [alpha])
[DELTA]E/E. The growth rate of Y/L is a weighted average of the growth
rates of [kappa] and E. This holds for all constant returns production
functions.
Now we proceed with our treatment of K/L. The derivative of (1),
provides this expression:
[DELTA][kappa]/[kappa] = [DELTA]k/k + g, (2)
where g = [DELTA]E/E. In order to gain further insight, we use the
accumulation equation, as developed by Mankiw (2009: 223). Also, see
Jones (2002: 39-43).
[DELTA]k = sf(k) - ([delta] + n + g)k (3)
Divide both sides by k:
[DELTA]k/k - sf(k)/k - ([delta] + n + g). (4)
Substitute this expression into (2) to obtain the following.
[DELTA][kappa]/[kappa] = sf(k)/k - ([delta] + n), (5)
where s is the saving rate, f(k) is the production function,
[delta] is the depreciation rate, and n is the population growth rate.
Because of diminishing returns sf(k)/k is a decreasing function of
k. That makes [DELTA][kappa]/[kappa] also a decreasing function of k.
Figure 1 shows the components of Equation (2).
Steady state occurs where the two lines cross, at k*. We can easily
see that the equilibrium is stable. Suppose that k > k*. In that
case, g > [DELTA][kappa]/[kappa] so by (2), [DELTA]k/k < 0, and k
falls. The same type argument holds for k < k*.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
From a welfare perspective, important issue is how [kappa] and k
grow. In steady state, [kappa] and E must grow at the same rate for k to
be constant at k*. Also, E grows at the rate g, so K must grow at the
rate g as well. Because [DELTA][kappa]/[kappa] is the slope of In K, In
[kappa] (and In E) are linear functions with slope g as shown in Figure
2.
Figure 2 presents the Solow model in terms of growth rates and time
paths so that the student can more easily see what is going on in the
model. It also facilitates seeing how changes in the parameters of the
model differ, a difference that is not easy to see in the standard
analysis.
II. The impact of a change in the population growth rate on
[kappa].
An increase in n reduces [DELTA][kappa]/[kappa]; as (5) shows. Thus
the graph would look as shown in Figure 3. The immediate impact at k* is
that now [DELTA][kappa]/[kappa] < g, so k* falls to k** as described
above.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Figure 4 shows what happens to the growth path of [kappa]. Suppose
that at [t.sub.o], n increases. The dashed line shows what the time path
would have been if n had not increased. The solid line shows what
actually happens to the path of ln([kappa]). The new steady state is
reached at time [t.sub.l]. The smaller gap between ln([kappa]) and In E
means that Ink has fallen. This clearly agrees with Figure 3.
III. The impact of a change in the growth of efficiency on [kappa].
Consider next an increase in the rate of growth of efficiency.
Figure 5 shows that the g line shifts up to g'. The
[DELTA][kappa]/[kappa] function is not affected. Clearly the equilibrium
value of k* falls to k**. This is exactly the same impact on k as the
increase in n. In this case, however, the growth rate of [kappa] never
falls; rather, it rises steadily toward g' from g. By contrast, in
the earlier scenario, the growth rate of K drops abruptly at the time of
the change before steadily recovering to an unchanged g.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The upper dashed line in Figure 6 shows the time path of
ln([kappa]) if there had been no change. At [t.sub.o], g changes to
g', and the ln E line changes slope abruptly. The path of
ln([kappa]) now swings up and regains steady state at [t.sub.l]. Now
ln([kappa]) grows at rate g' rather than g, but [k.sup.*] has
fallen. After [t.sub.o] the path of ln([kappa]) is always above what it
would have been if g had not changed.
IV. The impact of a change in n and a change in g on Y/L.
The growth rate of Y/L is a weighted average of the growth rates of
E and [kappa]. Therefore, when [kappa] is growing faster than E, so is
Y/L; when [kappa] is growing more slowly than E, so is Y/L; and when
[kappa] grows at rate g, so does Y/L. Now we can put ln(Y/L) on the same
graph with ln E and ln([kappa]), and ln(Y/L) will look qualitatively the
same as ln([kappa]). We leave it to the reader to construct this graph.
Here is the important outcome of the exercise. When n increases,
the growth rates of both Y/L and K/L immediately fall, the former by
less than the latter. The faster growth of Y/L then raises Y/K, pushing
both growth rates back toward g in the new steady state.
When g increases, the impact effect on the growth rate of K/L is
zero, while the growth rate of Y/L will increase--but not to g'.
Again, Y/L is growing faster than K/L raising Y/K and thus increasing
both growth rates toward their new common steady state value, g'.
V. Summary
This paper develops a method to see more clearly the differing
impacts of a change in population growth rate and a change in the rate
of growth of labor efficiency in the Solow model. Both have the same
impact on the efficiency-adjusted capital labor ratio, but they have
very different impacts on capital and output per person. This difference
is not so easy to see in the standard presentation. The approach
provided here makes the difference apparent.
References
Jones, Charles. 2002. Introduction to Economic Growth. 2nd edition.
London: Norton.
Mankiw, Gregory. 2009. Macroeconomics. 8th edition. Worth, New
York: Worth.
Kevin Quinn, Associate Professor of Economics, Bowling Green State
University, Bowling Green, Ohio 43043 Email: kquinn@bgsu.edu
John Hoag, Professor of Economics, Bowling Green State University,
Bowling Green, Ohio 43403 Email: jhoag@bgsu.edu
The authors deeply thank two anonymous referees for who made
substantial improvements.