Does player mobility lead to higher earnings? Evidence from the NHL.
Vincent, Claude ; Eastman, Byron
I. Introduction
The extensive coverage of player movement at trading and free
agency deadlines has generated a perception among fans and journalists
that players on the move are consistently moving to higher salaries. A
corollary of this perception is that players who have been more mobile
during their careers should have higher earnings than their more stable
counterparts, ceteris paribus. No one has looked at the veracity of this
hypothesis in the context of a major professional sport. This paper does
so through an examination of the relationship between mobility and
earnings in the National Hockey League. Specifically, we inquire into
the cumulative impact of changing teams on the earnings of players.
A cursory look at NHL earnings data shows that players who have
changed teams earn 30 percent more, on average, than players who have
not, a stylized fact that supports the aforementioned commonly held
perception. But does moving systematically lead to higher earnings? To
answer this question, we estimate a multivariate earnings function in a
human capital framework to ascertain if a player's current salary
is a reflection of the impact of all past mobility decisions. We also
examine the manner in which free agency shapes the relationship. This is
the first investigation of the effect of career mobility on earnings for
NHL players.
There is a paucity of literature examining the relationship between
free agency and earnings in the NHL with only lip-service being paid to
the effects of mobility, per se. In one of the earliest studies,
McPherson (1976) examines turnover rates in the NHL from the 1950-1951
to the 1965-1966 seasons. The league formed a closed system during this
period and since there was no external competition with respect to
personnel recruitment, turnover of players was involuntary. The author
finds that involuntary turnover rates varied by position. Goaltenders
and defensemen had lower turnover rates than forwards. The study
doesn't examine the relationship between turnover and earnings, per
se, but the author suggests that the positions with the highest turnover
rates are the most highly remunerated. This is the first hint of the
hypothesis that earnings and mobility in the NHL may be directly
related. Jones, Nadeau, and Walsh (1997, 1999), in two separate
investigations, examine NHL earnings for the 1989-1990 season and
include a dichotomous variable to capture the free agent effect. It
takes a value of one if the player has signed a contract as a free agent
(excepting his first contract). Since there was little inter-club
competition for players and only marginal quality players changed teams
as free agents during the study period, the authors expect a negative
relationship between earnings and free agency. Instead, they find no
statistically significant relationship. Idson and Kahane (2000) examine
earnings in the NHL for the 1990-1991 and 1991-1992 seasons. In their
study, they test the premise that a player who will become a free agent
at the end of a season may perform better than he might otherwise in
order to increase his status and hence future earnings with potential
employers. They include in their earnings equation a dichotomous
variable which takes a value of one if the player was a free agent in
the year previous to the one associated with the current salary. They
find a positive relationship between earnings and free agency. In
another study, Curme and Daugherty (2004) use data from the 1998-1999
and 1999-2000 seasons to estimate separate earnings equations for older
and younger players. They argue that older players are likely to have
been eligible for unrestricted free agency sometime in their career
while younger players will have never been eligible. Their empirical
results suggest the existence of a more competitive market wherein free
agency permits greater player mobility, and which has earnings linked
more closely to actual performance as experience increases.
This study takes the literature a step further: it examines the
effect of career mobility on current earnings. Our analysis incorporates
both free agent and non-free agent environments. The rest of the paper
is organized as follows. Section II presents the model followed by a
description of the data. Section III presents the estimation results.
Concluding remarks are presented in the final section.
II. Empirical Specification
In labor markets mobility can be either voluntary or involuntary.
Employees can change jobs for three main reasons: layoffs, discharges
and quits. For an NHL player, however, moves are completely involuntary
until later in his career. Generally, a player's career begins when
he is selected by a team in the annual entry draft. The term of his
first professional contract is fixed on the basis of his age, and
compensation is capped at levels prescribed in the collective bargaining
agreement. When his first contract expires the player becomes a
restricted free agent. This means that he can then sign with another
team but the requirement that compensation be paid to his original team
significantly inhibits his ability to initiate team changes. During this
part of his career any move to another team is a management
decision--from the player's perspective any move is involuntary.
The player can be traded to another team for compensation. The team can
also leave the player unprotected to be claimed in a waiver or expansion
draft. Management's final option is to not offer the player a
contract when his current contract expires, thereby permitting him to
sign with any team. Players released in this way are typically
performing below expectations. Later in his career a player will become
a free agent (1). This is the first time in his career that the player
can negotiate and sign a contract with any team on his own terms--from
the player's perspective the move would be seen as voluntary. His
current team cannot interfere with his decision other than through
offering him another contract. It may, in fact, compete with other teams
to retain his services. We incorporate both pre-free agency and
post-free agency moves into our analysis of the relationship between
mobility and earnings in the final part of the paper.
1. The Model
We specify an empirical log-linear earnings equation that includes
measures of offensive and defensive performance, experience, reputation,
amateur background and mobility as explanatory variables. Letting
[LNSAL.sub.i] denote the natural logarithm of player i's earnings,
[x.sub.i] represent a vector of typical human capital based explanatory
variables, and [M.sub.i] refer to a vector of mobility variables, we
estimate the following linear relationship:
[LNSAL.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][X.sub.i] +
[[gamma].sub.1][M.sub.i] + [u.sub.i] (1)
where [[beta].sub.0] is the constant term, [[beta].sub.1] and
[[gamma].sub.1] are vectors of unknown parameters, and [u.sub.i] is the
disturbance term. Estimates of the parameters are obtained using
ordinary least squares.
Our model includes the following explanatory variables commonly
used in the literature. Experience, which embodies intangible skills, is
expected to yield positive returns and is captured by the number of
games played (GAMES) over a player's career in the NHL. Any
nonlinear effects of experience on earnings are captured by its square
(SQGAMES). We expect a positive relationship between earnings and
offensive performance which is primarily measured by career points per
game (PTSGAME). We also expect a positive relationship between earnings
and a player's aggressiveness and his defensive performance.
Aggressiveness is captured by career penalty minutes per game (PIMGAME)
and defensive skills are captured by career plus-minus record per game
(PLUSGAME). We also include the height (HEIGHT) and weight (WEIGHT) of
players in the earnings equations because physically larger players may
be able to use their size to gain an advantage during games by
obstructing the play of opposing players and by creating scoring
opportunities for themselves and teammates. We expect a positive
relationship between earnings and the size of the player. Since fans are
attracted to a player's star power, we include in our model the
dichotomous variable STAR which indicates whether a player has ever been
selected to either a First or Second All-Star team during his career. We
expect a positive relationship between earnings and this measure of
reputation. A dichotomous variable DRAFT indicates whether or not the
player was selected in the first two rounds of the NHL Entry Draft. A
player who is selected in the early rounds of the draft may be able to
negotiate a higher salary in his initial contract, especially if his
initial skills are a good indicator of future performance that may
persist throughout his career.
We also control for a player's amateur background by including
dichotomous variables that indicate if he played most of his junior
hockey in the Ontario Hockey League (OHL), the Quebec Major Hockey
League (QMJHL), the Western Hockey League (WHL), the university or
college system in the United States or Canada (USCOLLEGE), or in Europe
(EUROPE). Jones, Nadeau and Walsh (1999) argue that university or
college trained players and European players may experience higher
opportunity costs and could therefore demand higher initial salaries.
Junior hockey variables can also be used as proxies for a player's
style of play. For example, in models that predict a player's
offensive performance in the NHL, Dawson and Magee (2000) suggest that
European players are more offensive minded than North American players.
Similarly, Voyer and Wright (1998) find that offensive performance in
junior hockey (goals or points per game scored) is a significant
predictor of NHL performance. However, penalty minutes, weight and
reputation are also significant predictors, but with smaller effects,
for Canadian and American born players. In addition to style of play,
amateur background may also represent unmeasurable forces related to
networking possibilities. For example, if Ontario based agents dominate
the NHL, this could provide OHL players with a comparative advantage in
salary negotiations.
The primary mobility variable (MOVER) is a dichotomous variable
that indicates whether a player played for more than one team in his
career. Human capital theory provides the basis for the relationship
between mobility and earnings. NHL players acquire general training with
every game they play. They also acquire specific training unique to each
team. When a player changes teams he brings with him his general
training and leaves behind any specific training he may have acquired.
His current earnings will reflect a combination of his accrued general
and specific training. Because a player who has played for more than one
team may have more nontransferable human capital, he should have lower
productivity and therefore earn less than his counterparts who have
played with just one team, ceteris paribus. However, this loss in human
capital resulting from the nontransferable specific training may be more
than compensated for by a better match and/or teammate effects. Idson
and Kahane (2000) discuss such teammate effects on individual player
productivity and find that players in the NHL can be considered as
complementary inputs and they suggest that this complementarity has
positive effects on player salaries. In addition, a move to a new team
may result in a better match when the player's style of play
corresponds with the coaching philosophy and/or the team's style of
play. Such moves would also include considerations related to team
staffing requirements wherein a player leaves a team overstaffed in his
position for a team that is understaffed in the position.
2. The Data
Our data set contains career information on 625 players: 407
forwards and 218 defensemen. Players are included if they played at
least 10 games in the NHL and salary data for the 2003-2004 season are
available (2). The reported earnings of players were obtained from the
NHLPA website (www. nhlpa.com) and reflect earnings for the 2003-2004
season. Choosing this season avoids the distorting effects of the salary
cap, introduced after the lockout of 2004-2005, on the relationship
between earnings and productivity. Data on the performance of players,
including total points, penalty minutes and plus-minus records refer to
their regular season career statistics prior to the 2003-2004 season.
The players' physical characteristics, performance and mobility
data were obtained from the official guide and record book published by
the National Hockey League. Most players in our sample played their
entire junior (amateur) hockey in only one of the three major junior
hockey leagues in Canada, in Europe, or in the US college system. A
relatively small number of players played their amateur hockey in more
than one system. These players were assigned to the junior system they
last played in before joining the professional ranks.
To incorporate mobility into our analysis, we categorize players as
either movers or stayers. Movers are players who changed teams at least
once in their careers prior to the 2003-2004 season; stayers are players
who played for the same team throughout their careers. The distribution
of players by mobility is shown in Table 1. Approximately two thirds of
the forwards and defensemen in our sample are movers while the remainder
have never changed teams. In terms of the number of moves over a
player's career, about one quarter of the players have changed
teams only once (24% of forwards and 28% of defensemen). At the other
extreme, only 15% of forwards and 12% of defensemen have moved at least
four times during their career.
The group means of earnings and other variables are shown in Table
2. Without controlling for the influence of any productivity measures,
the common perception holds true: movers earn more, on average, than
stayers. For forwards, movers earn approximately $500,000 more than
stayers while the difference is $260,000 for defensemen. This may
suggest that moving, per se, has a positive effect on earnings. But does
the act of changing teams, on its own, increase earnings? The suggestion
is misleading because it doesn't take account of the fact that
movers have higher productivity, are more aggressive and have more
experience. For example, forwards who have moved have scored more points
per game. Forwards and defensemen who moved have incurred more penalty
minutes per game. Additionally, movers have played more games than
stayers. These stylized facts suggest that movers as a group earn more
than stayers not simply because they are more mobile but rather because
they are more productive.
Tables 3 and 4 present some interesting details related to tenure.
The tables show the distribution of the average number of games played
with each team. Row (3) of Table 3 illustrates that, on average, a
forward plays approximately 200 games with his first team no matter how
many times he has moved during his career. (3) Two hundred games
represents a little more than two seasons. Similar data for defensemen
are presented in Table 4 and display more variation in the mean number
of games played with the first team. The descriptive statistics in
Tables 2, 3 and 4 provide a good backdrop for the more revealing
regression analysis, to which we now turn.
III. Estimation Results
The OLS estimates of the earnings functions are shown in Table 5.
Overall, the results related to the variables commonly used in earnings
functions for the NHL are consistent with those found in the literature.
Experience (GAMES, SQGAMES), points per game (PTSGAME) and reputation
(STAR, DRAFT) have the expected sign and are statistically significant
for both forwards and defensemen. Aggressiveness and size (PIMGAME,
WEIGHT) are significant for forwards only. Further, defensemen from the
Quebec Major Junior Hockey League (QMJHL) earn substantially less than
defensemen from the Ontario Hockey League (OHL) who represent the
omitted group in the analysis. This earnings differential is most likely
related to the network effects mentioned earlier. (4)
1. Initial Results
Because our primary purpose is to examine the cumulative effects of
player mobility on current earnings, the remainder of this paper focuses
on the mobility variables. The first measure of mobility is a
dichotomous variable (MOVER) which takes a value of one if the player
changed teams at least once in his career and zero otherwise. Contrary
to the previous comparison of the mean earnings of movers and stayers,
the regression analysis shows that movers earn Jess, not more, than
stayers after controlling for productivity and other determinants of
earnings. Columns (2) and (5) in Table 5 show that forwards who moved
earn 8% less than those who did not; defensemen who moved earn 20% less
in the same context. (5)
As interesting as these results are, we glean more information from
an analysis of the number of times a player has changed teams instead of
examining simply whether or not a player has moved during his career.
Columns (3) and (6) in Table 5 present regression results incorporating
the number of moves. The omitted group in the regressions is STAYER,
players who never changed teams during their careers. The mobility
variables therein are then defined as follows: NMOB1 = 1 if a player has
changed teams only one time; NMOB2 = 1 if a player has changed teams
twice; NMOB3 = 1 if a player has changed teams three times; and NMOB4 =
1 if a player has changed teams four or more times. The results for
forwards show that changing teams once or twice has no significant
impact on earnings when compared to those who have not moved during
their career. However, when a player moves a third time (NMOB3) his
earnings are approximately 19% lower than stayers. Forwards who have
moved four or more times (NMOB4) can expect to earn 48% less than
forwards who have remained with the same team throughout their careers.
For defensemen, changing teams only once has no effect on earnings
but moving more than once does. Defensemen who have moved twice (NMOB2)
earn approximately 20% less than stayers; defensemen who have moved
three times (NMOB3) earn 31% less while four or more moves (NMOB4
results in 59% lower earnings.
2. Player Quality Effects
The estimations related to the mobility variables above may be
biased because they do not take account of the possibility that mobility
may be related to unmeasurable player talent. (6) Highly talented
players may stay with the same team or not move often because such
unmeasurable talent is highly valued by their team.
In order to capture player quality effects we selected the top and
bottom quartiles of forwards and defensemen by points per game, assuming
that points per game and latent talent are related, and reestimated the
earnings equations for each quartile by position. The results are
presented in Table 6 for forwards and Table 7 for defensemen.
For the top quartile of forwards, the effect of mobility on
earnings is complex. The coefficient for MOVER in column (1) of Table 6
is not significant for these highly talented players. However, if
mobility is broken down into the number of moves rather than simply
whether the player moved or not, moving may have positive or negative
effects on the earnings of movers when compared to non-movers depending
on the number of moves. Column (2) of Table 6 shows that forwards who
move twice (NMOB2) earn 26% more than non-movers, whereas, moving four
times (NMOB4) results in 41% lower earnings. For the bottom quartile of
players, moving has a negative effect on earnings. The results in column
(3) show that players in this quartile who move (MOVER) earn 18% less
than non-movers. The results in column (4) show that the impact of
mobility on earnings occurs only after two moves. The earnings of
forwards who move a third time (NMOB3) are approximately 33% lower than
nonmovers. Forwards who have moved four or more times (NMOB4) can expect
to earn 52% less than non-movers.
These results suggest that mobility may be linked to latent talent
in the case of forwards. When player quality is ignored in Table 5,
moving has a negative effect on earnings with a significant impact only
after two moves. The results in Table 6 suggest that in the case of less
talented forwards, the effect of moving on earnings is qualitatively
similar but the magnitude of the effects is larger. When looking at
highly talented forwards, moving per se has no effect on earnings while
moving has a positive effect after two moves and a negative effect only
after four moves.
As for the defensemen, there is also evidence that there is a link
between mobility and latent talent. For the top quartile of defensemen,
the effect of mobility on earnings is smaller when compared to all
defensemen. At the same time, the effect of mobility on earnings is
larger for defensemen in the bottom quartile. The MOVER variable for the
highly talented defensemen changes from having a negative effect of 22%
on earnings to having no significant effect as shown in column (1) of
Table 7. The qualitative effect of the number of moves is the same
except that it increases in magnitude. Column (2) of Table 7 shows that
movers in the top quartile earn 54% less than non-movers after three
moves and 55% less after four moves. In the bottom quartile, column (3)
of Table 7 shows that the MOVER coefficient morn than doubles to 41%.
The estimates in column (4) of Table 7 show that the number of moves for
these defensemen is larger and significant for all moves.
3. Free Agency Effects
The analysis so far has ignored the effect of free agency. Free
agency as a concept was adopted by the NHL in 1975 with age as the most
important determinant of eligibility. Prior to free agency, all moves,
from the player's perspective, are involuntary; after it, they
become voluntary. We investigate the potential effect of free agency on
the relationship between moving and earnings by estimating separate
regressions based on player eligibility for free agency. The age
requirement under which players become free agents has been modified
over the years and we have taken these modifications into account. The
results are presented in Table 8 for forwards and Table 9 for
defensemen.
The first three columns of Table 8 report the regression results
for the subset of forwards who are not eligible for free agency. Column
(2) shows, that looked at dichotomously, movers earn approximately 12%
less than stayers. When the number of moves is considered, in column
(3), moving only once (NMOB1) has no effect on the earnings of movers
compared to stayers, but moving more than one time results in lower
relative earnings: two moves (NMOB2) results in earnings that are 15%
lower. The difference in earnings increases to 27% when there are three
moves (NMOB3) mid to 39% when there are four or more moves (NMOB4). The
last three columns relate to the subset of forwards who are eligible for
free agency. Ignoring the number of moves and considering only whether
they moved or not, column (5) shows that there is no difference in the
earnings of movers and stayers. When the impact of the number of moves
on relative earnings is considered, only forwards who have moved four or
more times (NMOB4) earn less than stayers. For forwards, free agent
status seems to equalize the movers and stayers as long as they move
less than four times in their careers.
The qualitative results for defensemen not eligible for free agency
are similar to the results for the same subset of forwards. However, the
negative impact of the number of moves on earnings is larger for
defensemen. The larger impact of moving on earnings may be greater for
defensemen than forwards because of the specialized nature of this
position that embodies relatively more nontransferable human capital.
The estimates are shown in Table 9. (7) Column (2) shows that movers
earn approximately 22% less than stayers. Column (3) shows that
defensemen who moved more than once have lower earnings than those who
have never moved: defensemen who moved two or three times (NMOB2, NMOB3)
earn approximately 22% less than stayers. The disparity increases to 66%
when there are four or more moves (NMOB4).
Simply looking at free agency status and player team changes begs
the question of movement timing: do moves made before free agency have a
different effect on earnings from those made after? To answer this
question we group the forwards who are free agents according to their
mobility status prior to, and after, becoming unrestricted free agents.
Moreover, since it was shown in column (3) of Table 8 that the negative
effect of the number of moves on the relative earnings of players not
eligible for free agency occurs only after two or more moves, we
redefine a stayer before free agency (STAYER1) as a player with less
than two moves and a mover before free agency (MOVER1) as a player with
two or more moves. This allows us to classify the players into four
types and identify them by the following dichotomous variables:
1. STAYER1_STAYER = 1 if the player moved less than twice before
and never moved after becoming eligible for free agency.
2. STAYER1_MOVER = 1 if the player moved less than twice before and
moved at least once after become eligible for free agency.
3. MOVER1_STAYER = 1 if the player moved more than once before and
never moved after becoming eligible for free agency.
4. MOVER1_MOVER = 1 if the player moved more than once before and
moved at least once after becoming eligible for free agency.
The regression results are presented in column (1) of Table 10 in
which the omitted group is composed of forwards who never moved: the
STAYER1_STAYER category.
Generally, players who were mobile before and after free agency
(MOVER1_MOVER) earn less than other players. They earn approximately 34%
less than players who never moved. Further, the earnings of players who
moved either before or after free agency, but not both, are not
significantly different from the earnings of players who never moved.
Moving after free agency has a significant impact on current
earnings only if the player moved before free agency. We gain further
insight by examining the effect of the number of post free agency moves
vis-a-vis simply whether or not the player moved. For the pre-free
agency moves, we keep the definitions of mobility status used in column
(1): STAYER1 is a player with less than two moves and MOVER1 is a player
with two or more moves. For the post-free agency moves, we define the
dichotomous variables MOB0 = 1 if the player never moved after free
agency, MOB1 = 1 if the player moved once, and MOB2 = 1 if he moved two
or more times. Column (2) of Table 8 presents the regression results.
The omitted group is composed of players with less than two moves before
free agency and who never moved after (STAYER1_MOB0). Moving only once
after free agency has no significant effect on earnings regardless of
whether or not the player moved before free agency. It is only when the
player moved two or more times after free agency that there is a
negative effect on earnings. The magnitude of this effect on earnings
depends on whether or not these players moved before free agency. If
they did not move before free agency (STAYER1_MOB2), players earn 36%
less than the omitted group whereas if they moved before (MOVER1_MOB2),
they earn 64% less.
To summarize, the timing of moves is important. The results in
column (1) of Table I0 show that if a player moved both before and after
free agency there was a negative effect on earnings. However, the
results shown in column (2) reveal a more complicated relationship.
Whether or not the player is a stayer before free agency, there are
negative repercussions on earnings only when a player has moved more
than once after free agency.
IV. Conclusion
The literature has shown mobility to be a very important
determinant of salaries in the labor market outside of professional
sports. The professional sports labor market is different in one major
respect: movement is involuntary for the majority of a career. The basic
human capital model argues that a pecuniary gain is the driving force
for job change. It is primarily employee initiated. This is not so in
the world of sports until complete free agent status is achieved.
This paper has presented a model outlining the effect of labor
movement on earnings in a professional sport. Using career data for
players in the National Hockey League prior to the 2004-2005 lockout to
estimate an earnings function we find that, after controlling for human
capital variables, the cumulative effect of moving on earnings is
negative. Players who have changed teams during their careers earn less
than those who remained with the same team throughout their career. The
difference in earnings is larger for defensemen than for forwards.
We gain further insight into the negative impact that changing
teams has on earnings when the number of moves is considered. For
forwards, changing teams has a negative effect on earnings only if the
number of moves is greater than two, while for defensemen, moving more
than once has a negative effect on earnings.
Separating our players according to free agency eligibility
modifies the results somewhat. For forwards who are not eligible for
free agency, the negative effect of the number of moves on earnings is
felt after one move instead of two. For defensemen who are not eligible
for free agency, the effect of the number of moves does not change when
compared with the full sample--the negative effect still occurs after
the player moves twice.
As for the forwards who are eligible for free agency, players who
change teams more frequently earn less than their more stable
counterparts. The timing of the moves is also important. Although movers
still earn less than stayers, players who have moved only before or only
after free agency, earn more than players who moved both before and
after.
The effect of mobility, per se, on earnings may be overestimated in
our model because we are not able to incorporate unmeasurable variables.
Firstly, mobility may be related to latent talent. Our results show that
the negative impact of moving on earnings is particularly strong for
less talented players. For highly talented players, however, movers earn
less than non-movers only when they change teams often. Otherwise, there
is no difference in the earnings of movers and non movers, except for
highly talented forwards who earn more when they move twice. Secondly,
there is something about players that move often. They do not seem to
find a "fit" with a team as quickly as their more stable
teammates. Perhaps they have a disruptive influence on a team, or
perhaps they are difficult to coach. Mobility may be partially capturing
the effect of these difficult to measure and hence omitted variables. To
the extent that it does, it may be a proxy for "problem"
players that have the skills to keep them in the league but may lack
characteristics that endear them to their teammates and coaches.
The finding that changing teams has a negative effect on earnings
only after two or more moves may be explained by the institutional
environment--players sign multiyear contracts. Earnings are
predetermined during a multiyear contract. Therefore, the earnings of a
player changing teams will not be responsive to moves until a new
contract is negotiated. A player that signs a new contract with his
current team is more likely to have negotiated higher earnings than a
player who is signing with a new team. An extension of this research
incorporating contract length would provide insight into the true
relationship between player mobility and earnings. (8)
Acknowledgements
We thank Ashley Ringuette and Tim Eastman for the collection of
data. We acknowledge the financial support from the Laurentian
University Research Fund.
References
Curme, Michael A. and Greg M. Daugherty. 2004. "Competition
and Pay for National Hockey League Players Born in Quebec." Journal
of Sports Economics 5(2): 186-205.
Dawson, Don and Lonnie Magee. 2000. The National Hockey League
Entry Draft, 1969-1995: An Application of a Weighted
Pool-adjacent-violators Algorithm. McMaster University, Department of
Economics Working Papers.
Idson, Todd L. and Leo H. Kahane. 2000. "Team Effects on
Compensation: An Application to Salary Determination in the National
Hockey League." Economic Inquiry 38(2): 345-57.
Jones, J. Colin H., Serge Nadeau and William Walsh. 1997. "The
Wages of Sin: Employment and Salary Effects of Violence in the National
Hockey League." Atlantic Economic Journal 25(2): 191-206.
Jones, J. Colin H., Serge Nadeau and William D. Walsh. 1999.
"Ethnicity, Productivity and Salary: Player Compensation and
Discrimination in the National Hockey League." Applied Economics
31(5): 593-608.
Lavoie, Marc. 2000. "The Location of Pay Discrimination in the
National Hockey League." Journal of Sports Economics 1(1): 401-411.
Lavoie, Marc. 2003. "The Entry Draft in the National Hockey
League: Discrimination, Style of Play, and Team Location." American
Journal of Economics and Sociology 62: 383-405.
Lavoie, Marc and Gilles Grenier. 1992. "Discrimination and
Salary Discrimination in the National Hockey League: 1977 and 1989
compared." In Advances in the Economics of Sports, vol. 1, edited
by Gerald Scully, 151-75. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
McPherson, Barry D. 1976. "Involuntary Turnover: A
Characteristic Process of Sport Organizations." International
Review for the Sociology of Sport 11(4): 5-16.
National Hockey League Official Guide and Record Book 2003. 2004.
Toronto, Canada: Dan Diamond and Associates.
Vincent, Claude and Byron Eastman. 2009. "Determinants of Pay
in the NHL: A Quantile Regression Approach." Journal of Sports
Economics 10(3): 256-277.
Voyer, Daniel and Edward F. Wright. 1998. "Predictors of
Performance in the National Hockey League." Journal of Sport
Behavior 21(4): 456-473.
Notes
(1.) In this paper free agents refer to those players whose
longevity in their career has enabled them to earn unrestricted free
agency status. This occurs at the age of 30 to 32 depending on the
collective agreement in effect. It does not refer to marginal players
who have played only a few games before having reached a minimum age.
The former are referred to as Group III free agents and the latter as
Group VI free agents in the 1995 collective agreement between the NHL
and the NHLPA.
(2.) We excluded two players from our sample. The first player was
deleted because he is part of the ownership group. His team and his
reported salary may not be entirely related to his performance. The
second player was deleted because he signed a contract with a new team
for the 2003-2004 season as a free agent for a salary substantially less
than the one that he could have obtained from his previous team or from
the market.
(3.) The differences across the columns are statistically
insignificant.
(4.) Research by Lavoie and Grenier (1992), Lavoie (2000), and
Lavoie (2003) found evidence of draft discrimination in the NHL. To test
for potential draft discrimination we reestimated the models with the
draft variable removed; there was no change in the sign, magnitude, nor
significance of the QMJHL coefficients. Further, in a previous
investigation Vincent and Eastman (2009) find that the earnings
differential between defensemen in the OHL and QMJHL was significant at
the upper quantiles of the conditional earnings distribution only and
was also unrelated to the draft variable.
(5.) The regression coefficients on the dichotomous variables do
not represent actual percentage changes when the dependent variable is
expressed in natural logs. All references to percentage changes related
to dichotomous variables in this paper are calculated according to the
transformation formula 100[exp([??])- 1].
(6.) We thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion.
(7.) Regression results for defensemen who are eligible for free
agency are not presented because there are insufficient degrees of
freedom.
(8.) Contract information reflecting player history was not
publicly available for the period of study.
by Claude Vincent, Assistant Professor, School of Sports
Administration, Laurentian University, Sudbury, Ontario. P3E2C6. tel:
705-675-1151, x1043, fax: 705-675-4836. cvincent@laurentian.ca.
and
Byron Eastman, Professor, Department of Economics, Laurentian
University, Sudbury, Ontario. P3E2C6. tel: 705-675-1151, x4267, fax:
705-675-4886. bdeastman@laurentian.ca.
TABLE 1.
Mobility Status of Players
All Players Forwards Defensemen
N % N % N %
Total 625 100.0 407 100.0 218 100.0
Movers 407 65.1 264 64.9 143 65.6
Stayers 218 34.9 143 35.1 75 34.4
Number of moves
0 218 34.9 143 35.1 75 34.4
1 157 25.1 96 23.6 61 28.0
2 99 15.8 66 16.2 33 15.1
3 65 10.4 42 10.3 23 10.6
[greater than or 86 13.8 60 14.7 26 11.9
equal to] 4
TABLE 2.
Discriptive Statistics by Position and Mobility Status
All players Forwards
Stayers Movers Stayers Movers
Total 218 407 143 264
Earnings ('000) 1,538 2,013 1,519 2,105
GAMES 236.62 494.61 225.25 509.39
PTSGAME 0.37 0.40 0.43 0.48
PIMGAME 0.78 0.96 0.70 0.91
PLUSGAME 0.00 -0.02 0.00 -0.02
HEIGHT 73.18 73.24 72.82 72.76
WEIGHT 203.06 205.81 199.18 202.51
DRAFT 0.51 0.46 0.50 0.46
STAR 0.05 0.07 0.06 0.07
AMATEUR LEAGUE
EUROPE 83 99 54 62
OHL 34 95 23 67
QMJHL 18 40 14 27
US COLLEGE 36 100 27 66
WHL 47 73 25 42
Defensemen
Stayers Movers
Total 75 143
Earnings ('000) 1,575 1,841
GAMES 258.29 467.32
PTSGAME 0.25 0.26
PIMGAME 0.94 1.06
PLUSGAME 0.01 -0.02
HEIGHT 73.88 74.13
WEIGHT 210.44 211.88
DRAFT 0.52 0.45
STAR 0.04 0.05
AMATEUR LEAGUE
EUROPE 29 37
OHL 11 28
QMJHL 4 13
US COLLEGE 9 34
WHL 22 31
TABLE 3.
Tenure Average Number of Games by Number of
Moves Forwards
Moves
0 1 2 3 4+
Number of players 143 96 66 42 60
Total Games 225 335 493 673 692
Games per team
First 225 200 190 205 197
Second -- 135 198 195 129
Third -- -- 105 156 120
Fourth -- -- -- 117 113
Fifth -- -- -- -- 89
Sixth and higher -- -- -- -- 44
TABLE 4.
Tenure Average Number of Games by Number of
Moves Defensemen
Moves
0 1 2 3 4+
Number of players 75 61 33 23 26
Total Games 258 361 421 613 648
Games per team
First 258 222 154 194 163
Second -- 139 130 203 108
Third -- -- 137 134 120
Fourth -- -- -- 81 120
Fifth -- -- -- -- 77
Sixth and higher -- -- -- -- 60
TABLE 5.
Earnings Equations by Position by Mobility Status
Forwards
(1) (2) (3)
GAMES 0.00209 *** 0.00223 *** 0.00274 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
SQGAMES -1.43E-06 *** -1.49 E-06 -1.55 E-06
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
PTSGAME 2.015 *** 1.982 *** 1.795 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
PIMGAME 0.0963 *** 0.0957 *** 0.0767 **
(0.007) (0.007) (0.013)
PLUSGAME 0.282 0.247 0.0308
(0.125) (0.182) (0.845)
HEIGHT 0.0241 0.0215 0.0224
(0.151) (0.201) (0.144)
WEIGHT -0.00396 * -0.00366 -0.00414 **
(0.080) (0.106) (0.048)
DRAFT 0.256 *** 0.247 *** 0.238 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
STAR 0.331 *** 0.329 *** 0.203 *
(0.005) (0.006) (0.055)
QMJHL -0.0661 -0.0748 -0.0251
(0.489) (0.432) (0.759)
WHL -0.0318 -0.0481 0.00512
(0.625) (0.465) (0.931)
USCOLLEGE 0.00198 -0.00238 0.0445
(0.978) (0.974) (0.504)
EUROPE 0.0437 0.0311 0.0852
(0.490) (0.627) (0.145)
MOVER -0.0816 *
(0.065)
NMOB1 0.0125
(0.797)
NMOB2 -0.0534
(0.369)
NMOB3 -0.213 ***
(0.003)
NMOB4 -0.658 ***
(0.000)
_cons 11.46 *** 11.62 *** 11.62 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
N 407 407 407
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.750 0.751 0.798
AIC 487.9 487.6 406.6
BIC 544.0 547.8 478.8
Defensemen
(4) (5) (6)
GAMES 0.00284 *** 0.00311 *** 0.00375 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
SQGAMES -1.74 E-06 -1.83 E-06 -2.08 E-06
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
PTSGAME 1.732 *** 1.672 *** 1.554 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
PIMGAME -0.0508 -0.0418 -0.00506
(0.355) (0.441) (0.921)
PLUSGAME 0.533 * 0.374 0.115
(0.067) (0.184) (0.634)
HEIGHT 0.0350 0.0399 0.00487
(0.204) (0.152) (0.843)
WEIGHT 0.00410 0.00391 0.00514
(0.298) (0.323) (0.139)
DRAFT 0.185 *** 0.155 ** 0.160 ***
(0.009) (0.030) (0.008)
STAR 0.568 *** 0.549 ** 0.380 *
(0.007) (0.010) (0.067)
QMJHL -0.312 ** -0.300 ** -0.400 ***
(0.032) (0.030) (0.001)
WHL -0.0648 -0.0859 -0.181
(0.545) (0.405) (0.053)
USCOLLEGE -0.00519 0.0115 -0.135
(0.965) (0.921) (0.221)
EUROPE -0.0199 -0.0435 -0.157
(0.862) (0.698) (0.102)
MOVER -0.222 ***
(0.000)
NMOB1 -0.0746
(0.232)
NMOB2 -0.227 ***
(0.006)
NMOB3 -0.378 ***
(0.003)
NMOB4 -0.903 ***
(0.000)
_cons 9.444 *** 9.217 *** 11.51 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
N 218 218 218
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.654 0.667 0.737
AIC 302.1 294.8 246.1
BIC 349.5 345.6 307.1
p-values in parentheses based on White heteroskedastic standard
errors.
* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01.
TABLE 6.
Earnings Equations for Forwards by Quality by Mobility Status
Top Quartile
(1) (2)
GAMES 0.00312 *** 0.00354 ***
(0.000) (0.000)
SQGAMES -1.88 E-06 -1.90 E-06
(0.000) (0.000)
PTSGAME 1.587 *** 0.937 *
(0.007) (0.072)
PIMGAME 0.102 -0.0710
(0.398) (0.556)
PLUSGAME -0.0567 -0.124
(0.905) (0.754)
HEIGHT 0.111 ** 0.105 **
(0.037) (0.028)
WEIGHT -0.0121 ** -0.0113 **
(0.026) (0.017)
DRAFT 0.181 * 0.197 *
(0.094) (0.079)
STAR 0.309 * 0.366 **
(0.055) (0.028)
QMJHL -0.166 -0.00387
(0.512) (0.985)
WHL -0.0745 0.0139
(0.675) (0.925)
USCOLLEGE 0.137 0.241
(0.440) (0.118)
EUROPE 0.210 0.338 **
(0.157) (0.015)
MOVER -0.00224
(0.986)
NMOB1 0.0621
(0.604)
NMOB2 0.299 **
(0.045)
NMOB3 -0.119
(0.464)
NMOB4 -0.533 **
(0.013)
_cons 6.749 ** 7.348 ***
(0.035) (0.009)
N 102 102
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.512 0.621
AIC 156.3 133.1
BIC 195.7 180.4
Bottom Quartile
(3) (4)
GAMES 0.000750 0.00109 **
(0.182) (0.031)
SQGAMES 2.920E-07 6.020E-07
(0.688) (0.290)
PTSGAME 1.601 ** 1.571 **
(0.029) (0.018)
PIMGAME 0.0363 0.0522
(0.392) (0.180)
PLUSGAME 0.419 ** 0.250
(0.033) (0.129)
HEIGHT 0.00773 0.0209
(0.711) (0.219)
WEIGHT -0.000976 -0.00105
(0.747) (0.700)
DRAFT 0.259 *** 0.258 ***
(0.001) (0.000)
STAR
QMJHL 0.0258 -0.0106
(0.833) (0.915)
WHL -0.00677 -0.00422
(0.939) (0.960)
USCOLLEGE -0.156 -0.0329
(0.102) (0.684)
EUROPE -0.0201 0.0869
(0.848) (0.347)
MOVER -0.200 ***
(0.002)
NMOB1 -0.106
(0.136)
NMOB2 -0.131
(0.160)
NMOB3 -0.408 ***
(0.000)
NMOB4 -0.730 ***
(0.000)
_cons 12.55 *** 11.48 ***
(0.000) (0.000)
N 102 102
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.418 0.530
AIC 54.88 35.63
BIC 91.63 80.25
p-values in parentheses based on White heteroskedastic standard
errors.
* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01.
TABLE 7.
Earnings Equations for Defensemen by Quality by Mobility Status
Top Quartile
(1) (2)
GAMES 0.00322 *** 0.00433 ***
(0.000) (0.000)
SQGAMES -1.76 E-06 -2.25 E-06
(0.003) (0.000)
PTSGAME 1.622 ** 1.639 **
(0.040) (0.047)
PIMGAME 0.216 0.124
(0.336) (0.494')
PLUSGAME 0.382 0.391
(0.552) (0.500)
HEIGHT 0.0499 0.00480
(0.418) (0.916)
WEIGHT 0.00473 0.0113
(0.548) (0.139)
DRAFT -0.135 -0.116
(0.450) (0.472)
STAR 0.353 0.137
(0.182) (0.606)
QMJHL -0.0801 -0.358
(0.763) (0.263)
WHL -0.0821 -0.191
(0.715) (0.445)
USCOLLEGE -0.239 -0.217
(0.314) (0.319)
EUROPE -0.236 -0.318
(0.193) (0.107)
MOVER -0.194
(0.178)
NMOB1 -0.0630
(0.645)
NMOB2 -0.163
(0.319)
NMOB3 -0.780 **
(0.026)
NMOB4 -0.809 ***
(0.006)
-cons 8.339 ** 10.08 ***
(0.027) (0.001)
N 55 55
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.537 0.650
AIC 92.03 78.36
BIC 122.1 114.5
Bottom Quartile
(3) (4)
GAMES 0.00239 *** 0.00249 ***
(0.002) (0.001)
SQGAMES -8.900E-07 -0.615
(0.358) (0.609)
PTSGAME -1.168 -1.301
(0.357) (0.303)
PIMGAME -0.110 * -0.106 *
(0.096) (0.097)
PLUSGAME 0.191 0.110
(0.656) (0.785)
HEIGHT 0.0411 0.0324
(0.445) (0.448)
WEIGHT 0.0000318 0.000193
(0.995) (0.965)
DRAFT 0.344 *** 0.366 ***
(0.003) (0.001)
STAR
QMJHL -0.0704 -0.161
(0.716) (0.292)
WHL -0.0367 -0.0803
(0.760) (0.471)
USCOLLEGE 0.0902 -0.0468
(0.567) (0.761)
EUROPE -0.0238 -0.182
(0.866) (0.153)
MOVER -0.530 ***
(0.000)
NMOB1 -0.362 ***
(0.001)
NMOB2 -0.564 ***
(0.000)
NMOB3 -0.864 ***
(0.000)
NMOB4 -0.747 *
(0.060)
-cons 10.41 *** 11.05 ***
(0.004) (0.000)
N 55 55
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.547 0.577
AIC 45.08 43.11
BIC 73.19 77.24
p-values in parentheses based on White heteroskedastic standard
errors.
* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01.
TABLE 8.
Earnings Equation of Forwards by Free Agency Eligibility
Not Eligible
(1) (2) (3)
GAMES 0.00244 *** 0.00265 *** 0.00285 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
SQGAMES -1.20E-06 *** -1.27 E-06 -1.25 E-06
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
PTSGAME 1.591 *** 1.526 *** 1.471 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
PIMGAME 0.0688 ** 0.0681 ** 0.0709 **
(0.027) (0.024) (0.012)
PLUSGAME 0.219 0.165 0.0663
(0.217) (0.346) (0.668)
HEIGHT 0.00716 0.00244 0.00873
(0.643) (0.875) (0.555)
WEIGHT -0.00563 *** -0.00514 ** -0.00537 ***
(0.008) (0.015) (0.009)
DRAFT 0.207 *** 0.192 *** 0.202 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
STAR 0.347 ** 0.334 ** 0.249
(0.035) (0.040) (0.109)
QMJHL -0.0394 -0.0578 -0.0585
(0.658) (0.502) (0.452)
WHL 0.00346 -0.0278 -0.0330
(0.955) (0.647) (0.567)
USCOLLEGE 0.00896 -0.00506 0.0153
(0.901) (0.944) (0.825)
EUROPE 0.0409 0.0135 0.0347
(0.504) (0.828) (0.546)
MOVER -0.125 ***
(0.007)
NMOB1 -0.0326
(0.527)
NMOB2 -0.165 ***
(0.008)
NMOB3 -0.311 ***
(0.000)
NMOB4 -0.501 ***
(0.000)
-cons 13.14 *** 13.45 *** 13.01 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
N 312 312 312
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.762 0.767 0.787
AIC 271.9 267.1 241.2
BIC 324.3 323.2 308.6
Eligible
(4) (5) (6)
GAMES 0.00256 ** 0.00260 ** 0.00290 ***
(0.023) (0.024) (0.001)
SQGAMES -1.93 E-06 -1.95E-06 *** -1.91 E-06
(0.003) (0.004) (0.000)
PTSGAME 2.986 *** 2.972 *** 2.601 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
PIMGAME 0.164 0.165 0.0435
(0.177) (0.178) (0.683)
PLUSGAME 0.253 0.228 -0.379
(0.712) (0.744) (0.524)
HEIGHT 0.104 ** 0.104 ** 0.0705 *
(0.036) (0.037) (0.100)
WEIGHT -0.00436 -0.00433 -0.000708
(0.525) (0.529) (0.902)
DRAFT 0.302 ** 0.298 ** 0.273 **
(0.018) (0.020) (0.024)
STAR 0.0411 0.0344 -0.0581
(0.832) (0.861) (0.790)
QMJHL 0.0567 0.0663 0.122
(0.813) (0.785) (0.546)
WHL -0.0554 -0.0551 0.153
(0.759) (0.763) (0.376)
USCOLLEGE 0.0524 0.0652 0.0931
(0.766) (0.722) (0.559)
EUROPE 0.0106 0.0248 0.0696
(0.955) (0.900) (0.659)
MOVER -0.0858
(0.427)
NMOB1 0.0897
(0.541)
NMOB2 0.191
(0.258)
NMOB3 -0.0237
(0.871)
NMOB4 -0.589 ***
(0.000)
-cons 4.953 * 5.019 * 6.885 ***
(0.070) (0.067) (0.004)
N 95 95 95
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.712 0.708 0.783
AIC 165.2 167.1 141.4
BIC 201.0 205.4 187.4
p-values in parentheses based on White heteroskedastic standard
errors.
* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01.
TABLE 9.
Earnings Equation of Defensemen Not Eligible For Free Agency
(1) (2) (3)
GAMES 0.00286 *** 0.00322 *** 0.00348 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
SQGAMES -1.51 E-06 -1.66 E-06 -1.79E-06 ***
(0.002) (0.000) (0.000)
PTSGAME 1.790 *** 1.712 *** 1.760 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
PIMGAME -0.0156 -0.00444 -0.0140
(0.785) (0.938) (0.786)
PLUSGAME 0.298 0.115 -0.126
(0.319) (0.684) (0.576)
HEIGHT 0.0170 0.0268 0.00144
(0.452) (0.250) (0.943)
WEIGHT 0.00590 0.00517 0.00596 *
(0.122) (0.178) (0.062)
DRAFT 0.175 ** 0.141 ** 0.160 *
(0.017) (0.048) (0.005)
STAR 0.357 0.327 0.438 *
(0.227) (0.270) (0.090)
QMJHL -0.233 -0.191 -0.314 **
(0.136) (0.196) (0.018)
WHL 0.00941 -0.0145 -0.110
(0.936) (0.898) (0.259)
USCOLLEGE 0.119 0.166 -0.0371
(0.349) (0.186) (0.751)
EUROPE 0.0689 0.0380 -0.0841
(0.543) (0.730) (0.406)
MOVER -0.243 ***
(0.000)
NMOB1 -0.0874
(0.147)
NM0B2 -0.253 ***
(0.003)
NM0B3 -0.250 *
(0.079)
NM0B4 -1.091 ***
(0.000)
-cons 10.26 *** 9.767 *** 11.52 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
N 170 170 170
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.690 0.711 0.791
AIC 194.2 183.5 131.1
BIC 238.1 230.5 187.5
p-values in parentheses based on White heteroskedastic standard
errors.
* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01.
TABLE 10.
Earnings Equations of Forwards Eligible for
Free Agency
(1) (2)
GAMES 0.00353 *** 0.00327 ***
(0.001) (0.001)
SQGAMES -2.31E-06 *** -1.93E-06 ***
(0.000) (0.000)
PTSGAME 2.695 *** 2.543 ***
(0.000) (0.000)
PIMGAME 0.0598 0.129
(0.610) (0.142)
PLUSGAME -0.291 0.298
(0.669) (0.641)
HEIGHT 0.0914 * 0.0491
(0.054) (0.165)
WEIGHT -0.00144 -0.000254
(0.844) (0.967)
DRAFT 0.242 * 0.0869
(0.080) (0.487)
STAR 0.0464 -0.0488
(0.830) (0.777)
QMJHL 0.0576 -0.0260
(0.790) (0.868)
WHL -0.0734 -0.0575
(0.660) (0.653)
USCOLLEGE 0.00285 0.121
(0.987) (0.348)
EUROPE -0.0281 -0.0152
(0.866) (0.911)
MOVER1_STAYER 0.0480
(0.703)
STAYER1_MOVER -0.0208
(0.920)
MOVER1_MOVER -0.421 **
(0.013)
STAYER1_MOB1 0.0319
(0.908)
STAYER1_MOB2 -0.445 **
(0.041)
MOVER1_MOB0 -0.0152
(0.881)
MOVER1_MOB1 -0.171
(0.257)
MOVER1_MOB2 -1.018 ***
(0.000)
_cons 5.278 ** 8.221 ***
(0.038) (0.000)
N 95 95
adj. [R.sup.2] 0.743 0.814
AIC 156.7 127.3
BIC 200.2 175.8
p-values in parentheses based on White heteroskedastic standard
errors.
* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01.