The long-run impact of age demographics on the U.S. divorce rate.
Nunley, John M. ; Zietz, Joachim
I. Introduction
The steady rise in the United States (U.S.) divorce rate from the
mid-1960s to the mid-1970s has been a topic of much debate among
demographers and economists (Friedberg 1998; Goldstein 1999; Michael
1978, 1988; Oppenheimer 1997; Preston 1997; Ruggles 1997; Wolfers 2006).
Researchers have focused much of their attention on explaining the rise
in the divorce rate by examining changes in divorce laws during the
early-1970s (Friedberg 1998; Wolfers 2006) and the economic empowerment
of women (Bremmer and Kesselring 2004; Nunley 2010; Ruggles 1997). The
consensus from the literature on divorce laws suggests that the reforms
led to a small, transitory rise in the divorce rate. (1) The literature
on the impact of the economic empowerment of women on the divorce rate
has produced mixed results, which is likely due to the fact that women
began participating in the labor market and in higher education at
increasing rates long before the sharp rise in the divorce rate in the
mid-1960s.
As research has recently shifted to panel data studies, earlier
time-series evidence on the role played by age-specific divorce rates,
such as Michael (1978, 1988) and South (1985), appears to have been
largely bypassed, although it clearly suggests that growth in the
fraction of young adults in the population, a group with a
disproportionately high divorce risk, contributed very significantly to
the sharp rise in the divorce rate during the 1960s and early 1970s. For
example, Michael (1978) finds that women in their 20s contributed to
approximately 60 percent of the rise in the divorce rate observed
between 1960 and 1974. Carlson (1979) also provides evidence that a
higher rate of divorce is present for individuals in their 20s over the
same period.
The purpose of this study is to use more recent time-series
techniques and a longer time horizon than previous studies to reexamine
the extent to which the large variation in the divorce rate can be
attributed to a simple demographic change, the rise and decline in the
share of young adults in the population. As the divorce probability is
higher among young adults and also during the first years of marriage,
the divorce rate should change ceteris paribus with the fraction of the
population in their twenties. Figure 1 suggests that the rise in the
fraction of young adults is indeed closely tied to the divorce rate per
marriage in the U.S., in particular over the period from the mid-1960s
to the mid-1970s, which has been the focus of numerous divorce studies
in recent years. This study can be considered a reminder that simple
explanations of long-run changes in the divorce rate should not be
dismissed simply because they do not show up during the relatively short
time horizons typically covered by panel data sets.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Previous time-series studies of the divorce rate, such as South
(1985), Michael (1988), Bremmer and Kesselring (2004) or Nunley (2010),
not only consider shorter time horizons than this study (2) but also use
rather different methodologies and variables from study to study, which
makes it difficult at times to compare results. (3) Therefore, a
secondary objective of this study is to help in making previous studies
and their results easier to understand and compare.
Our primary finding is that the results of South (1985) and Michael
(1988) that show the importance of the percentage of young adults in the
population as a key driver of long-run changes in the divorce rate can
be replicated in our analysis, with estimated elasticities ranging from
1.0 to 1.3. The age-composition variable is by far the most robust of
all variables that we include to explain the divorce rate. The
participation rate of females in higher education is used as a proxy for
female economic independence and tends to be positive, which is in line
with the previous literature. We identify a rise in the underlying trend
of the divorce rate from 1969 to 1972 that is not explained by our
included variables. Based on previous research, we attribute this
increase to the "pill effect," as discussed for example in
Michael (1988), and the temporary impact of divorce law changes (Wolfers
2006). The underlying trend in the divorce rate moves up again between
1988 and 1998 because the observed divorce rate does not decline as fast
as predicted by its fundamental driving forces. However, as of now,
there appears to be no obvious reason for this sluggish decline in the
divorce rate.
II. Data
We use time-series data from 1932 to 2006, which goes significantly
beyond the years covered by panel-data studies (Charles and Stephens
2004; Nunley and Seals 2010; Weiss and Willis 1997) and other studies
that make use of aggregate time-series data (South 1985, Michael 1988,
Bremmer and Kesselring 2004, Nunley 2010).
Our outcome variable is divorces per 1,000 married persons, (4) and
our key explanatory variable is the percentage of the population in the
20-29 year-old age group. We motivate this age-composition variable
along the lines of Michael (1988). Marriages are less stable when
individuals marry at younger ages (Becker et al. 1977; Castro-Martin and
Bumpass 1989), and they are less stable during the early years of
marriage (Sweet and Bumpass 1987). Because the median age at first
marriage ranges from the low-20s to the mid-20s, (5) the 20-29 year age
group has a disproportionate number of short-duration marriages. As a
consequence, a rise or fall in the fraction of 20-29 year-olds in the
total population should increase or decrease the aggregate divorce rate
irrespective of other causes of the divorce rate. Figure 1 illustrates
this point. The sharp rise in the divorce rate from the mid1960s to the
mid-1970s happens to coincide with a perceptible increase in the 20-29
age group as a fraction of the total population. Likewise, the steady
decline in the divorce rate from 1980 onwards coincides with a reduction
in the fraction of 20-29 year-olds in the population. (6) Figure 1 also
suggests that the age composition variable alone cannot explain the
long-run swings in the divorce rate over the last 70 years. There are
also other forces at work.
We try to capture these other forces by including the appropriate
control variables. Female economic empowerment is considered an
important driver of the divorce rate in the long run (Ruggles 1997). The
majority of the empirical literature reports that the increasing
economic independence of women led to a rise in divorces. Economic
empowerment is typically associated with increases in the female labor
force participation rate (FLFPR) or in the participation of females in
higher education. (7) For example, Bremmer and Kesselring (2004) find a
positive, long-run relationship between the FLFPR and the divorce rate.
Nunley (2010) identifies a positive relationship between the divorce
rate and changes in female participation in higher education, which is
taken as a proxy for female economic empowerment.
As in Nunley (2010), we also employ the percentage of females
enrolled in higher education as a proxy for female economic
independence. (8) However, we note that, similar to female labor force
participation, the female participation in higher education is not
directly measuring economic empowerment since enrolling in higher
education does not necessarily translate into actual earnings. (9) As
our data cover the years of World War II, we follow Michael (1988) in
employing a variable (GI) that identifies the percentage of the
population older than 18 years of age that is in the military.
In order to understand the results of the previous time-series
literature on the aggregate divorce rate, we also try two macroeconomic
variables, the inflation rate and the unemployment rate. Nunley (2010)
finds a positive and significant impact of inflation on the divorce
rate, but only weak evidence for an impact of unemployment. The weak
significance also emerges from Michael's (1988) models if one
corrects his results for autocorrelation and from South's (1985).
More recently, researchers have examined the divorce rates of
marriages that formed at different times. For example, Stevenson and
Wolfers (2007a, 2007b) find higher levels of marital instability for
marriages that formed prior to the 1970s and more marital stability for
those that formed after the 1970s. Because much of the literature on the
age-divorce relationship focuses on the divorce rates of different
marriage cohorts, we check the robustness of our results to the
inclusion of a proxy for cohort effects. Our proxy for the cohort effect
comes from Stevenson and Wolfers (2007b). The authors construct it by
calculating the probability of a couple divorcing by the 5th wedding
anniversary for each marriage cohort.
Using a long sample requires some solutions to apparent data
problems. For example, the Center for Disease Control (CDC) stopped
collecting data on divorces per 1,000 married persons in 1997. However,
we are able to calculate the number of divorces per 1,000 married
couples from 1998 to 2006 from generally available data sources. (10) In
addition, there are missing years of data for the variable measuring the
participation of females in higher education. Only odd years are
reported before 1945. We replace the missing years of data with the
average of the odd years. For example, female participation in higher
education in 1934 is taken to equal the average of the 1933 and 1935
values. Some averaging is also done for the variable capturing the
divorce risk facing different marriage cohorts. In addition, missing
values for the marriage-cohort variable are replaced with the known
values of the cohort subsample at either end. For the other variables
used in the analysis, data are available for the entire sample period.
Table 1 provides variable names, definitions, and summary
statistics for the variables used in the analysis. For the cointegration
part of the empirical analysis, we test each of the variables used in
our analysis for the presence of a unit root using Augmented
Dickey-Fuller tests (ADF) with the null hypothesis of a unit root. The
ADF tests cannot reject a unit root for any of the variables at the five
percent level except for the unemployment rate. We conclude that the
unemployment rate should only be added into the cointegrating equation
together with at least two other variables to avoid spurious results.
III. Econometric Methodology
Our focus is to identify the long-run relationship between the
divorce rate and the size of the age group most likely to divorce. We
consider two newer time-series techniques that have been used before to
study the time-series behavior of the aggregate divorce rate,
cointegration and unobserved component modeling. (11)
Given that our explanatory variable of primary interest and most
control variables are plausibly exogenous, we employ the single-equation
cointegration approach introduced by Engle and Granger (1987) rather
than the multivariate one of the Johansen (1988) type. (12) Using the
residuals from the Engle-Granger cointegrating regression, we employ an
ADF test with a testing-down procedure for the optimal number of lags of
the dependent variable; p-values for the cointegration test statistic
come from MacKinnon (1996).
Following the approach taken by Nunley (2010), we also employ an
unobserved component model to identify the impact of the age-composition
variable on the divorce rate. Intuitively, this approach can be thought
of as a modified regression, where the constant term is replaced by
stochastic components that capture any underlying trend or seasonal or
cyclical variation. The variation of the dependent variable is
decomposed into an observable part, the contribution of the regression
variables, and an unobservable part, which is captured by the stochastic
components. This decomposition approach has a number of advantages. The
most relevant from an economic perspective is that it delivers reliable
estimates of the impact of the observed variables, such as the
age-composition variable in our case, even if important driving forces
of the dependent variable are not explicitly entering the equation,
either because theory is silent about them or because they are difficult
to measure in practice. Leaving out important variables of this type or
not capturing their impact fully with the included variables has the
potential to cause a well-known omitted variables problem in least
squares regression. The UCM modeling approach delivers useful
coefficient estimates even under these circumstances because the impact
of the missing variables is picked up by the unobserved components. (13)
Which unobserved components need to be added to the model depends on the
nature of the dependent variable and the observed explanatory variables.
In our application, the model structure is given as
[[gamma].sub.t] = [[mu].sub.t] + [summation.sub.i] [[beta].sub.i]
[x.sub.i,t] + [[epsilon].sub.t],
where [[gamma].sub.t] is the dependent variable and [[mu].sub.t] a
stochastic trend component, which absorbs variation in the dependent
variable that is not captured by the observed explanatory variables
[x.sub.i,t] and their associated coefficients [[beta].sub.i;]
[[epsilon].sub.t] is a random error with zero mean and constant
variance. The stochastic trend [[mu].sub.t] is modeled itself as a
random walk,
[[mu].sub.t] = [[mu].sub.t-1] + [[eta].sub.t],
where [eta] is an random error term with zero mean and constant
variance. (14)
IV. Estimation Results
Cointegration Method
Table 2 presents the results from the cointegration analysis. For
each model, we conduct a test for cointegration. In cointegration space,
we include a constant and a time trend, along with the explanatory
variables of interest in logarithmic form. (15) The cointegration tests
reveal at the five-percent level the presence of a common trend among
the divorce rate and the explanatory variables tested in Models 1
through 3 and in Model 5. The evidence for cointegration is less strong
for Models 4 and 5 and not present at common levels of statistical
significance for Model 7.
The impact of the age-composition variable is positive and larger
in size in each model specification than the other explanatory
variables. However, the magnitude of the effect varies somewhat
depending on the additional explanatory variables included in
cointegration space. For example, in Models 1 and 3, a one-percent
increase in the percentage of the population in the 20-29 age group
results in a 1.38 percent rise in the divorce rate. For all models, for
which cointegration can be assumed, the elasticity value lies
approximately between 1.2 and 1.5, which suggests a fair amount of
robustness to alternative model specifications.
As in Michael (1988), a rise in the percentage of the population in
the military is associated with a rise in the divorce rate. The
elasticity is relatively low, however, with a value around 0.10. The
economic empowerment of women, which is proxied in this study by their
participation in higher education (fem_educ), is positively related to
the divorce rate in the long run, but with a relatively low elasticity
between 0.10 and 0.20. These results are consistent with earlier work by
Nunley (2010), Bremmer and Kesselring (2004), and South (1985), who also
find a positive impact of their proxies for female economic
independence. If either the inflation rate or the unemployment rate is
included as an additional variable, as in Models 5 or 7, the models lose
their cointegration property. Model 6, however, demonstrates that a
model with only the age-composition variable and the unemployment and
inflation rates passes the contegration test. The inflation rate has a
positive effect on the divorce rate, while the unemployment rate turns
out to have a negative influence on the divorce rate. Our finding for a
positive relationship between the inflation rate and the divorce rate is
consistent with previous work (Nunley 2010). The negative relationship
found for the unemployment rate and the divorce rates is at odds with
some studies (e.g., South 1985) but is consistent with others (e.g.,
Nunley 2010). (16)
The relative sensitivity of the cointegration property to the
inclusion of the macroeconomic variables is partly explained by the
correlation coefficients of the explanatory variables presented in Table
3: the coefficients of the macroeconomic variables tend to be larger
than those of the demographic variables. Table 3 also reveals that the
GI variable is negatively correlated with the unemployment rate, which
is largely driven by the period around WWII.
An important result of the cointegration analysis for our study,
which is at least implicit in Table 2, is that there exists no
combination of variables that can reject the null hypothesis of
no-cointegration unless the age-composition variable is included among
the variables under investigation. That means, the age-composition
variable is of crucial importance; no other variable is. The
age-composition variable continues to be a decisive variable for
cointegration if the sample is restricted to the years after WWII
(1948-2006). In that case, cointegration can be established, at the 10
percent level, only if both the age-composition variable and female
participation in higher education are included in the cointegration
equation. Inclusion of any macroeconomic variable eliminates any
cointegration property.
Adding the cohort-effect variable to any of the cointegration
regressions reported in Table 2 results in a loss of the cointegration
property. The correlation coefficients of Table 3 reveal a potential
reason: the cohort variable is highly correlated with a number of other
variables, in particular the participation of females in higher
education. This suggests that the cohort variable is not identifying an
independent causal explanation of movements in the divorce rate over
time. In fact, one may speculate that the increase in the cohort
variable in the 1960s and 1970s is causally related to the changes in
society happening at that time, of which the increase in the proportion
of the population in the 20-29 year-old age group is likely to be key.
The sheer size of the Baby Boom generation that triggered the divorce
rate changes of the 1960s and 1970s may be thought of as also being the
key factor to bringing about the societal changes that characterized the
1960s and 1970s as "radically different" from the past. Hence,
we can think of the demographic change as the most likely cause also of
the observed cohort changes of the 1960s and 1970s. This is borne out if
we try to predict the cohort variable for the period 1958 to 1995 with
the age-composition variable. It turns out that the proportion of the
population in the 20-29 year-old age group can explain 78 percent of all
the variation in the cohort variable over that time period. (17)
Unobserved Component Model
An important difference between the cointegration analysis of the
last section and the unobserved component modeling lies in the fact that
the latter depends much less on asymptotic estimator properties and the
assumption of a stable environment. In practice, we replace an
underlying deterministic trend term (time trend in Table 2) with a more
flexible stochastic trend. In return, we need to pay attention now to
the statistical properties of the estimator, as reflected by statistical
tests on the model residuals. The issues of outliers and time lags also
arise.
Table 4 summarizes the estimation results. (18) The most important
aspect is evident from the first row of estimates. The estimated
elasticity of the age-composition variable has about the same range (1
to 1.3) as in Table 2, and it remains highly statistically significant
regardless of the model specification. This suggests our conclusion that
the age-composition variable is a key driver of the divorce rate is very
robust.
We note that the GI variable now enters with a lag of one year. The
estimated elasticities are rather similar to those of the cointegrating
equations of Table 2. The elasticity of the participation rate of
females in higher education tends to be slightly larger on average in
Table 4 compared to Table 2. However, by far the largest differences
compared to the cointegration results arise in the elasticities of the
two macroeconomic variables. The inflation elasticity is significantly
smaller than the ones reported in Table 2 and the elasticity for the
unemployment rate changes sign. This supports our earlier conclusion
that the impact of the macroeconomic variables is much less certain than
that of our age-composition variable or our proxy for female economic
independence.
Some of the models reported in Table 4 suffer from autocorrelation
and non-normality in the residuals. Autocorrelation is an issue in
Models 1 to 3, and non-normality in Models 1, 2, and 5. Model 3 shows
that the inclusion of observation specific dummy variables either among
the regressors or in the stochastic trend can remove the non-normality
problem. That means non-normality is caused by outliers. As a direct
comparison of Models 2 and 3 reveals, removing the non-normality with
dummy variables has no material impact on our focus variable, the
age-composition variable. By far the best fit is achieved with Model 6,
especially considering that no observation specific dummy variables are
used. Again, both our age-composition variable and our proxy for female
economic independence are in line with the results of Table 2.
Figure 2 gives a graphical representation of the estimates implied
by Model 6. The top panel shows the logarithm of the divorce rate, which
is the dependent variable in all our models. The panel in the middle
presents the predictions of the explanatory variables, the so-called
regression component. The third panel shows the evolution over time of
the underlying trend, which is the unobserved model component. Except
for the residual, which is not shown, the regression component and the
unobserved component add up to the dependent variable.
We see that the regression component closely tracks the dependent
variable. However, a few deviations are notable. These are evident in
the behavior of the unobserved component in the bottom panel. The
unobserved component stays around 5.0 for much of the time to around
1968, except for some ups and downs during the war years, which are not
fully captured by the GI variable. We note a distinct upward drift from
1968 to about 1972, which is presumably a result of the "pill
effect" and the changes in divorce laws at this time. The
unobserved component stays flat for numerous years until the late 1980s,
when it rises again for about 10 years in the decade of the 1990s. This
last rise, however, appears to be temporary, unlike the increase around
1970. Another difference compared to 1970 is that the rise in the
unobserved component is not reflected by an increase in the divorce rate
but comes about because the divorce rate falls more slowly than
predicted by the included regression variables. What may be the cause of
this temporary rise in the unobserved component of the divorce rate is
not clear.
As a robustness check, we also estimate unobserved component models
for the period 19482006. The results can be summarized as follows. The
age-composition variable remains stable, with an estimated elasticity at
around unity. The elasticity of the female participation rate in higher
education stays at around 0.30. The estimation results for the
unemployment rate and the inflation rate again tend to be variable and
not uniformly significant. (19)
V. Summary and Conclusions
The sharp increase in the aggregate divorce rate from the mid-1960s
to the mid-1970s and its decline beginning around 1980 has been a topic
of much debate. The sharp rise and steady decline in the divorce rate
happens to coincide with a perceptible increase and decrease in the
20-29 age group as a fraction of the total population, which is largely
the result of the Baby Boom generation passing through this age group at
that time. This has been noted before in the literature but seems to
have been pushed into the background as research into the causes of
changes in the divorce rate has shifted almost exclusively toward
questions that are amenable to panel data studies.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The purpose of this study has been to bring back to the forefront
the centrality of the age composition of the population for questions
surrounding the aggregate divorce rate. We confirm earlier results by
South (1985) and Michael (1988) that the percentage of the 20-29
year-olds in the population is a very robust predictor of the divorce
rate in the long run, with estimated elasticities ranging from 1.0 to
1.3. These elasticities are consistently larger than for any other
determinant of the divorce rate and are not sensitive to the inclusion
of other explanatory variables that have been used in the literature.
This applies not only to the estimates on the complete sample period
from 1932 to 2006, but is true also for estimates limited to the time
period after WWII.
We find that our proxy for the economic independence of women, the
female participation rate in higher education, is positive and has an
elasticity between 0.2 to 0.3, depending on the model specification. We
show that the macroeconomic variables we use, the unemployment rate and
the inflation rate, are far more fragile in their impact on the
aggregate divorce rate than our age composition variable or the variable
capturing female participation in higher education.
We find some evidence of a positive "pill effect" and/or
a temporary impact of the divorce law changes from the late 1960s to the
early 1970s. We also identify another unpredicted hump in the divorce
rate during the 1990s, which arises because the divorce rate falls far
more slowly over that time period than predicted. According to our
estimates, there is little evidence to support the notion that there is
a cohort effect present around the 1970s. What has been identified as a
cohort effect by Stevenson and Wolfers (2007b) is largely predictable by
our age-composition variable in conjunction with the female
participation rate in higher education.
Acknowledgements
The authors thank Charles Baum, Gregory Givens, Mark Owens, and
Alan Seals for helpful comments and suggestions.
References
Becker, Gary S., Elisabeth Landes, and Robert Michael. 1977.
"An Economic Analysis of Marital Instability." Journal of
Political Economy, 85(6): 1141-1188.
Bremmer, Dale and Randy Kesselring. 2004. "Divorce and Female
Labor-Force Participation: Evidence from Time-Series Data and
Cointegration." Atlantic Economic Journal, 32(3): 175-190.
Carlson, Elwood. 1979. "Divorce Rate Fluctuation as a Cohort
Phenomenon." Population Studies, 33(3): 523-536.
Carter, Susan B. et al. 2006. Historical Statistics of the United
States, Earliest Times to the Present, Millennium Edition. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Castro-Martin, Theresa and Larry L. Bumpass. 1989. "Recent
Trends and Differentials in Marital Disruption." Demography, 26(1):
37-51.
Charles, Kerwin and Melvin Stephens. 2004. "Job Displacement,
Disability, and Divorce." Journal of Labor Economics, 22(2):
489-522.
Commandeur, Jacques J.F., and Koopman, Siem J. 2007. An
Introduction to State Space Time Series Analysis, Oxford University
Press, Oxford and New York.
Costa, Dora. 2000. "From Mill Town to Board Room: The Rise of
Women's Paid Labor." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4):
101-122.
Engle, Robert F. and Clive W. J. Granger. 1987.
"Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation,
and Testing." Econometrica, 55(2): 251-276.
Friedberg, Leora. 1998. "Did Unilateral Raise Divorce Rates?
Evidence from Panel Data." American Economic Review, 88(3):
608-627.
Goldin, Claudia. 2006. "The Quiet Revolution That Transformed
Women's Employment, Education, and Family." American Economic
Review, 96(2): 1-21.
Goldin, Claudia, Lawrence F. Katz, and Ilyana Kuziemko. 2006.
"The Homecoming of American College Women: The Reversal of the
College Gender Gap." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(4):
133-156.
Goldstein, Joshua. 1999. "The Leveling of Divorce Rates in the
United States." Demography, 36(3): 409-414.
Harvey, Andrew. 1989. Forecasting, Structural Time Series Models
and the Kalman Filter, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Johansen, Soren. 1988. "Statistical Analysis of Cointegrating
Vectors." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12(2-3):
231-54.
MacKinnon, James G. 1996. "Numerical Distribution Functions
for Unit Root and Cointegration Tests." Journal of Applied
Econometrics, 11 (6): 601-618.
Michael, Robert. 1978. "The Rise in Divorce Rates, 1960-1974:
Age-Specific Components." Demography, 15(2): 177-182.
Michael, Robert. 1988. "Why Did the U.S. Divorce Rate Double
within a Decade?" In Research in Population Economics, Volume 6,
ed. T. Paul Schultz, 367-399, Conneticut: JAI Press.
Nunley, John M. 2010. "Inflation and Other Aggregate
Determinants of the Trend in U.S. Divorce Rates since the 1960s."
Applied Economics, 42(26): 3367-3381.
Nunley, John M. and Alan Seals. 2010. "The Effects of
Household Income Volatility on Divorce." American Journal of
Economics and Sociology, 69(3): 983-1010.
Oppenheimer, Valerie K. 1997. "Comment on "The Rise in
Divorce and Separation in the United States, 1890-1990.""
Demography, 34(4): 467-472.
Preston, Samuel H. 1997. "Comment on Steven Ruggles's
"The Rise in Divorce and Separation in the United States,
1890-1990."" Demography, 34(4): 473-474.
Ruggles, Steven. 1997. "The Rise of Divorce and Separation in
the United States, 1880-1990." Demography, 34(4): 455-466.
South, Scott. 1985. "Economic Conditions and the Divorce Rate:
A Time-Series Analysis of Postwar United States." Journal of
Marriage and the Family, 47(1): 31-41.
Stevenson, Betsey and Justin Wolfers. 2007a. "Marriage and
Divorce: Changes and their Driving Forces." Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 21(2): 27-52.
Stevenson, Betsey and Justin Wolfers. 2007b. "Trends in
Marital Stability." Unpublished Manuscript.
Sweet, James A. and Larry L. Bumpass. 1987. American Families and
Households. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Weiss, Yoram and Robert Willis. 1997. "Match Quality, New
Information, and Marital Dissolution." Journal of Labor Economics,
15(1): $293-$329.
Wolfers, Justin. 2006. "Did Unilateral Divorce Laws Raise
Divorce Rates? A Reconciliation and New Results." American Economic
Review, 96(5): 1802-1820.
Notes
(1.) The divorce rate began trending upward in the mid-1960s, which
predates the widespread adoption of unilateral divorce across states in
the 1970s. Wolfers (2006) concludes that the adoption of unilateral
divorce laws led to a slight rise in the divorce rate due to pent-up
demand; that is, a lot of bad marriages could not end under mutual
consent but did so under unilateral divorce. Nevertheless, the effects
on the divorce rate of divorce-law reform are small, short-lived, and
incapable of explaining its doubling from the mid-1960s to the
mid-1970s. Also, as noted for example by Michael (1988), many European
countries experienced a similar development of the divorce rate over
time as the U.S., yet did not have concurrent divorce law changes. As a
consequence, we do not consider divorce law changes in this study.
(2.) All four studies except Michael (1988) focus on post-WWII
data; Michael's (1988) estimation sample ends in 1974.
(3.) South (1985) uses an autoregressive distributed lag model that
eliminates autocorrelation, but provides only short run effects; Michael
(1988) uses least squares without correction for autocorrelation, with
potentially biased long-run coefficient estimates; Bremmer and
Kesselring (2004) use cointegration methods to identify long-run
influences on the divorce rate; and Nunley (2010) uses unobserved
component modeling.
(4.) Divorces per 1,000 married couples and divorces per 1,000
persons display similar behavior over the sample period used in this
study. In fact, a scatterplot of divorces per 1,000 persons and divorces
per 1,000 married couples reveals a clean, linear relationship between
the two variables. This suggests that the estimated effects of our
explanatory variables would be similar regardless of which divorce
measure is used. In fact, we find similar results, regardless of which
measure of the divorce rate is used.
(5.) See Carter et al. (2006) for U.S. data from 1850-1999 median
ages at first marriage. Note there are differences between males and
females. However, the difference between men's and women's
median age at first marriage is approximately two to three years, with
women typically marrying at younger ages than men. Nevertheless, the
median ages at first marriage for both men and women fall into the 20-29
age grouping.
(6.) We also check the robustness of our results to alternative
ways of measuring the young population. In particular, we use the
fraction of 20-24 year-olds in the population as a robustness check. The
results are not materially affected by this substitution. As a result,
we present the results using the 20-29 year-old age group measure, as
they are most comparable to the measures used by Michael (1988).
(7.) We do not consider the FLFRP in our analysis, as data on this
variable are only available back to 1948. Likewise, using the FLFPR as a
proxy for women's rising economic empowerment may not be ideal
because many women remained secondary earners within households until
the late-1960s and 1970s, continued to take their husband's
labor-market choices as given, and worked part time with little
opportunity for on-the-job advancement (Goldin 2006).
(8.) Similar to the FLFPR, female participation in higher education
has grown steadily since the late-1940s. Over this period, Goldin et al.
(2006) document how the rate of females taking math and science courses
in high school converged to that of men. This better prepared them for
college and supplied the necessary skills to sort into professionalized
fields of study, such as medical, law, business, and dental schools. As
women increased their economic independence through participation in
professional jobs, household laborarket decisions became interdependent,
perhaps indicating a shift in bargaining power toward women within
households (Costa 2000). The gain in bargaining power from increased
participation in professionalized fields suggests that female
participation in higher education proxies well for the economic
empowerment of women.
(9.) Actual earnings of females, as used in a robustness check by
Michael (1988), would clearly be a better measure, but that information
is not available at the aggregate level and over the long time period we
study.
(10.) Multiplying the number of divorces per 1,000 persons by the
U.S. population per 1,000 persons gives the total number of divorces in
a given year. Dividing this number by the stock of married couples
creates the variable of interest: divorces per 1,000 married couples.
This measure draws on various U.S. Statistical Abstracts. Data on
divorces per 1,000 married couples are available until 1997. Therefore,
to check our estimates for the years 1997-2006 use the same calculation
method described above for the available years of the divorce rate per
1,000 married couples, and we find that any difference in the estimates
are in the decimal places.
(11.) Cointegration methods are applied in Bremmer and Kesselring
(2004) and unobserved component modeling in Nunley (2010).
(12.) We note that Johansen type tests for multivariate
cointegration are sensible only for models with more than two variables
and then only if the variables are jointly determined. In our case, it
is unlikely that the divorce rate and the variables used to explain its
trend are jointly determined. In particular, Granger causality tests
strongly confirm that none of the variables used to explain the divorce
rate are themselves Granger-caused by the divorce rate at any reasonable
level of statistical significance. That includes but is not limited to
our focus variable, the fraction of 20-29 year olds in the population.
(13.) It is important for the outcome that the unobserved
components are part of the model specification, rather than part of the
residual term.
(14.) We note that the variances of [[eta].sub.t] is the only
estimable parameter of the stochastic trend [[mu].sub.t]. This variance
is estimated jointly with the regression parameters [[beta].sub.i] and
the variance of the error term [[epsilon].sub.t], using maximum
likelihood in combination with the Kalman Filter. Details are discussed
at a nontechnical level in Commandeur and Koopman (2007) and at a more
advanced level in Harvey (1989).
(15.) The log form allows us to interpret the coefficients as
elasticities.
(16.) From a theoretical perspective, divorce and inflation should
be unambiguously positively related as inflation acts as a tax on the
household. By contrast, the relationship between divorce and
unemployment is ambiguous. Unemployment should raise the divorce rate
because it reduces the returns from marriage. But unemployment can also
reduce the divorce rate by forcing spouses to rely each other's
income as a source of consumption insurance.
(17.) The age composition variable in combination with the variable
capturing the rate of female participation in higher education explains
even more, 87 percent of the variation in the cohort variable.
(18.) As in the cointegration analysis, we leave out the cohort
effects because they are strongly correlated with our age variable and
the participation rate of females in higher education.
(19.) We generated a figure analogous to Figure 2 for the 1948-2006
time period. The figure is based on a model that contains only two
explanatory variables, the age-composition variable and the female
participation rate in higher education. The model explains 51 percent of
the variation around the stochastic trend, has normally distributed
residuals, no autocorrelation, and no observation specific dummy
variables to absorb the effect of outliers. The unobserved component is
rather similar to that for the complete sample model depicted in Figure
2. It is relatively stable to the late 1960s, then increases to the
early 1970s, and then changes little until a second increase in 1990.
Again, this last increase in the unobserved component is temporary, as
the unobserved component falls back to its mid 1980s level by the end of
the sample. We note that adding the variable for the "pill
effect" from Michael (1988) or our cohort effect variable does not
change the unobserved component perceptively. In the interest of
brevity, we have omitted this figure from the paper. However, it is
available upon request.
John M. Nunley, Assistant Professor, Department of Economics,
College of Business Administration, University of Wisconsin--La Crosse,
La Crosse, WI 54601, phone: 608-785-5145, email: jnunley@uwlax.edu,
website: www.uwlax.edu/faculty/nunley.
Joachim Zietz, Professor of Economics, Department of Economics and
Finance, Jennings A. Jones College of Business, Middle Tennessee State
University, Murfreesboro, TN 37132; and EBS Business School, EBS
Universitat fur Wirtschaft und Recht, Wiesbaden, Germany; phone:
615-898- 5619, email: joachim.zietz@mtsu.edu, website:
www.mtsu.edu/~jzietz.
TABLE 1.
Variable Names, Definitions, and Basic Statistics
Name Definition
Divorce Number of divorces per 1,000 marriages
per2029 Percentage of the U.S. population in the 20-29 age
group
fem_educ Women enrolled in higher education as a percentage of
the population
Inflation Inflation rate; the logarithm is constructed as
ln(1+inflation/100)
unemployment Unemployment rate
GI Percentage of the population older than 18 years in
the military
cohort effect 100 minus the average rate for men and women of
surviving in the marriage (in percent) until the 5th
wedding anniversary; taken from Table 3 of Stevenson
and Wolfers (2007b); averages formed from adjoining
years for missing values; 4 used for missing values
at beginning of sample, 10 used for missing values at
end of sample.
Name Mean Std.Dev. Min. Max.
Divorce 14.89 5.34 6.10 22.80
per2029 0.16 0.02 0.12 0.18
fem_educ 0.017 0.011 0.004 0.034
Inflation 3.58 3.79 -10.30 14.65
unemployment 7.05 4.90 1.20 24.75
GI 1.86 2.11 0.29 12.32
cohort effect 7.67 3.17 4.00 11.65
TABLE 2.
Engle-Granger Cointegration Estimates, with the Log of the
Divorce Rate per 1,000 Married Couples as Dependent Variable
(1932-2006)
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Explanatory Variables:
ln_percent_2029 1.384 1.518 1.381 1.180
ln_GI 0.111 0.107
ln_fem_educ 0.119 0.176
ln_inflation
ln_unemployment
time trend 0.016 0.018 0.013 0.010
Constant 4.609 4.773 5.208 5.231
Diagnostic Statistics:
R-squared 0.896 0.938 0.941 0.896
P-value for test of HO 0.030 0.004 0.011 0.058
of No-Cointegration
Model 5 Model 6 Model 7
Explanatory Variables:
ln_percent_2029 1.208 1.337 1.171
ln_GI 0.080
ln_fem_educ 0.097 0.202
ln_inflation 1.477 1.641 1.349
ln_unemployment -0.103 -0.124
time trend 0.013 0.015 0.008
Constant 4.753 4.675 5.585
Diagnostic Statistics:
R-squared 0.954 0.946 0.954
P-value for test of HO 0.082 0.025 0.185
of No-Cointegration
Notes: In indicates the natural logarithm. Each model is tested
for cointegration over the sample spanning from 1932-2006. The
cointegration test results at the bottom of the table use the
Engle-Granger cointegration tests, with p-values derived from
MacKinnon (1996). In all cases we use a test-down procedure with
four lags for the augmented Dickey-Fuller test of the residuals.
A p-value below 0.05 indicates rejection of the null hypothesis
of no cointegration in favor of a long-run relationship among the
variables. No t-values or p-values are reported for the
individual coefficients because they are not reliable given the
autocorrelation present in the residuals.
TABLE 3.
Correlation Coefficients of Explanatory Variables (1932-2006)
ln_percent2029 In_GI ln_fem_educ
1.000 -0.150 -0.052 ln_percent2029
1.000 -0.185 ln-GI
1.000 ln_fem_educ
ln_inflation
ln_unemployment
cohort effect
ln_inflation ln_unemployment cohort effect
0.312 0.343 0.132 ln_percent2029
0.279 -0.790 -0.186 ln-GI
0.284 -0.127 0.958 ln_fem_educ
1.000 -0.317 0.353 ln_inflation
1.000 -0.050 ln_unemployment
1.000 cohort effect
Notes: In indicates the natural logarithm.
TABLE 4.
Unobserved Component Model Estimates, with the Log of the Divorce Rate
per 1,000 Married Couples as Dependent Variable (1932-2006)
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Explanatory Variables:
ln_percent2029 1.322 1.220 1.266 1.094
(0.002) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000)
In_GI(-1) 0.124 0.106 0.115
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
ln_fem_educ 0.355
(0.000)
ln_inflation
ln_unemployment
Level break 1934 0.204 0.184
Level break 1946 0.390 0.285
Level break 1948 -0.107 -0.105
Outlier 1945 0.168
Outlier 1944 -0.088
Diagnostic Statistics:
R-squared 0.972 0.980 0.992 0.993
R-squared around trend 0.113 0.393 0.766 0.794
DW test statistic 1.187 1.333 1.343 1.616
P-values for test of
no autocorrelation--Q(3) 0.027 0.006 0.006 0.170
Normality 0.000 0.000 0.113 0.349
Model 5 Model 6
Explanatory Variables:
ln_percent2029 1.068 1.011
(0.001) (0.001)
In_GI(-1) 0.128 0.150
(0.000) (0.000)
ln_fem_educ 0.196 0.205
(0.080) (0.054)
ln_inflation 0.757 0.889
(0.001) (0.000)
ln_unemployment 0.070
(0.005)
Level break 1934
Level break 1946
Level break 1948
Outlier 1945
Outlier 1944
Diagnostic Statistics:
R-squared 0.984 0.986
R-squared around trend 0.513 0.574
DW test statistic 1.790 1.940
P-values for test of
no autocorrelation--Q(3) 0.459 0.763
Normality 0.000 0.039
Notes: In indicates the natural logarithm. P-values are reported in
parenthesis. R-squared around trend identifies the explanatory power
of the regression component, which includes observation specific dummy
variables as for Models 3 and 4. DW stands for the Durbin-Watson
statistic. Autocorrelation is tested by the Box-Ljung Q statistic at
three lags, Q(3). Normality is tested by the Bowman-Shenton test.