首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月01日 星期日
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Arson and the business cycle.
  • 作者:Corrigan, Frank E., III ; Siegfried, John J.
  • 期刊名称:American Economist
  • 印刷版ISSN:0569-4345
  • 出版年度:2011
  • 期号:March
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Omicron Delta Epsilon
  • 摘要:Arson causes over $1 billion in U.S. property damage annually (United States Fire Administration, 2005). Arsonists deliberately burn structures for various reasons, some which may be sensitive to economic circumstances. Because insurance usually covers fire damage, the incentive for owners to set fires deliberately or be neglectful in maintenance varies with conditions that affect market values relative to insured values. If insured value exceeds market value, there is an incentive to commit arson. An owner may deliberately set fire to his business to avoid losses during a recession or to collect fraudulent insurance payments when the expected cost of continuing the business exceeds its expected revenue. A home owner, whose property value has plummeted, for example, due to a severe downturn in the housing market, may find it more attractive to collect insurance than to sell, repair, or continue to live in the structure.
  • 关键词:Arson;Business cycles;Fires;Mortgages;United States economic conditions

Arson and the business cycle.


Corrigan, Frank E., III ; Siegfried, John J.


I. Arson and the Economy

Arson causes over $1 billion in U.S. property damage annually (United States Fire Administration, 2005). Arsonists deliberately burn structures for various reasons, some which may be sensitive to economic circumstances. Because insurance usually covers fire damage, the incentive for owners to set fires deliberately or be neglectful in maintenance varies with conditions that affect market values relative to insured values. If insured value exceeds market value, there is an incentive to commit arson. An owner may deliberately set fire to his business to avoid losses during a recession or to collect fraudulent insurance payments when the expected cost of continuing the business exceeds its expected revenue. A home owner, whose property value has plummeted, for example, due to a severe downturn in the housing market, may find it more attractive to collect insurance than to sell, repair, or continue to live in the structure.

A Fox News Report, broadcast on January 27, 2008, indicated that some American homeowners were deliberately burning residences because the slump in U.S. housing prices had driven market values below insured values. Fire investigators have noted the possibility of financial circumstances motivating arson. Certified Fraud Examiner Douglas Crewse claims business owners in financial distress may deliberately set fire to their business "to avoid insolvency, prevent further losses in the business, ..., dispose of inventory, liquidate a business due to unprofitable contracts, or even relocate and/or renovate the business" (Crewse, 2005). Arson for profit is not limited to commercial buildings. Fortune magazine reported on January 10, 2008 that the insurance-industry-funded Coalition Against Insurance Fraud had warned that "fraud fighters were watching closely for a spike in arsons by desperate homeowners who could no longer afford their home payments;" Dennis Schulkins, a claim consultant in State Farm's Special Investigative Unit asserted that "when the economy is down, we see an increase in fraud." Of course, increased risk of criminal prosecution occurs if an arsonist acts on the potential gain from the insurance contract he or she holds.

In 1979, Thomas Spillman and Thomas Zak investigated the relationship between arson and the business cycle. They regressed arson rates on economic activity over time, using the unemployment rate as a measure of both property values and the opportunity cost of crime. Because they used quarterly observations from 1963 to 1976 from Nashville, Tennessee, binary variables were included to adjust for seasonal variation in arsons. Surprisingly, Spillman and Zak found no relationship between the unemployment rate and arson. However, their specification did not directly incorporate property values, but rather correlated arson with general employment conditions.

Hershbarger and Miller (1978, 275-290) continued this line of research, relating commercial arsons to the number of business bankruptcy cases filed, duration of unemployment, and other indicators of general business vitality. Using annual data for the U.S. from 1964-75, Cloninger (1981, 494-504) found that arson increases as the yield on business assets falls. Brotman and Fox (1988, 751-754) found no correlation between dollar losses due to arson and unemployment, but surprisingly found higher arson losses when the bankruptcy rate is lower and housing prices are higher. They did not consider, however, the possibility that arson losses can rise with housing prices while arson frequency diminishes. In a second empirical study of arson, Cloninger (1990, 540-545) directly tested the hypothesis that arson is an attractive form of asset abandonment when property values fall below replacement values. Using data from 1964 through 1987, he found that arsons vary inversely with "Tobin's q," the ratio of market value to replacement value. Finally, Steven Green and Allen Seward (1998) found cross-section evidence that arsons increase when housing prices fall and when homeowners are in financial distress.

In this note, we replicate and update the Spillman and Zak study (1979, 37-43), and then extend it by adding variables reflecting housing prices to reflect the benefits of arson, leaving the unemployment rate to reflect the opportunity cost of the crime. After explaining why arson rates should be more sensitive to contemporaneous housing prices than to general economic conditions, we test our hypothesis by repeating the Spillman and Zak tests, adding measures of housing prices to unemployment rates to distinguish the specific role of housing prices from general business conditions, which do not always move in the same direction.

II. The Economic Model

Arson is a pre-meditated crime. A rational criminal considers the consequences of his actions before committing a crime. To be profitable, the expected benefits from arson must exceed expected costs. Expected benefit is the financial gain the arsonist receives by destroying property, essentially the difference between its insured and market value. Expected costs are legal penalties imposed on a convicted arsonist, adjusted for the probability of being caught and the probability of being convicted.

Arson is financial abandonment. Linking formal financial abandonment models developed by Robichek and Van Home (1967, 577-89), Dyl and Long (1969, 88-95), and Joy (1976, 1225-28) to criminal behavior models created by Becker (1968, 169-217) and Ehrlich (1973, 521-565), Cloninger (1981, 494-504) shows that abandonment is financially attractive if the abandonment value (insurance) exceeds the net present value of expected cash flows over the remaining expected life of an asset. Arson is the optimal form of abandonment when expected gains from proceeds of an insurance claim arising out of a fire exceed both expected gains from a legal sale and the expected net present value of the flow of utility from continued use of the asset. Normally, insured value is less than market value of an asset, and expected gain is zero. However, rapid depreciation of an asset or plummeting demand can lower market value to such an extent that replacement value exceeds market value. For example, many structures built during 2005 and 2006 could not be reconstructed with their 2010 market value.

The devastation caused by Hurricane Katrina in 2005 was blamed for increased arson in the Gulf Coast area. Arson was suspected as the probable cause of numerous suspicious fires in New Orleans. According to the superintendent of one New Orleans area fire department, "speculation is that some homeowners without flood insurance or those with a low cap on their [flood] policies may be hoping to cover themselves by collecting through their fire coverage" (Hunter, 2005). Some homeowners may have perceived the expected gain in potential property insurance compensation that had not been adjusted for the value lost as a result of Katrina to exceed the expected cost of being arrested for arson. Katrina essentially caused a downturn in the local economy, which lowered a cost (the market value of structures) of committing arson. The lower cost increased the incentive to commit arson, with the expectation of greater financial gain in the form of insurance compensation.

Accordingly, we hypothesize that arson depends on the expected future value of property (benefits), the direct costs of potential legal consequences (costs), and time (because of progress in fire avoidance and suppression technology). Like Spillman and Zak, our empirical model uses the annual number fires in Nashville, Tennessee judged to be arson as the dependent variable. These data were collected personally from the Nashville Fire Marshall's office. We use 31 rather than 14 years of data, thereby including more business cycles. (1) We use annual rather than quarterly data because only annual data were collected by the Nashville Fire Marshall for the entire period we analyze. Annual data also eliminate concerns about seasonal variation in arson.

We consider two measures of arson. "Arsons" are fires determined to have been set deliberately. The number of arsons is a function of the number of structures, which, in turn, depends on population. "Suspicious fires" is the sum of vandalistic, arson, and suspicious fires. It is more inclusive than arsons, adding probable-but-not-surely-determined arsons. "Suspicious fires" is also a function of population.

We include the unemployment rate as a measure of the opportunity cost of being apprehended and convicted of arson. But, we add measures of property values to capture directly and separately from the opportunity cost of being apprehended and convicted of a crime, the potential benefits of committing arson. The unemployment rate measures the percentage of those in the civilian labor force who do not have a job and are seeking work. During periods of high unemployment, potential arsonists have less to lose if apprehended and convicted for arson.

Housing markets do not always mimic general business conditions, because the expected growth in future housing prices depends on current and recent changes in housing prices (i.e. speculation), as well as on current and expected future mortgage interest rates. We use two property value indexes: 30-year fixed rate mortgage rates and a home price index. When mortgage rates rise, potential homebuyers find it more expensive to borrow and therefore more expensive to purchase property, thus decreasing demand for housing and, consequently, housing prices. Moreover, increases in home mortgage rates reflect increases in other long-term interest rates, including business loans. As costs of doing business rise, financial pressures intensify and business asset values decline.

Average annual interest rates for 30-year fixed-rate mortgages were obtained from the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Association (FHLMA) [18]. (2) The home price index is average home value in Nashville, tabulated by the FHLMA. (3) It was set at 100 on January 1, 1987. Each home price index observation represents year end property values.

While mortgage rates measure property values indirectly, the home price index measures them directly, giving our model two measures of property value variability.

A second set of estimates controls for the effect of city size on the quantity of arsons. The number of structures, potential "victims" of arson, is roughly proportional to population. Nashville annual average unemployment rate and population information were collected from the Tennessee Department of Labor and the U.S. Census [16, 17]. Population in the model is the number of residents (in units of 10,000) in the Nashville metropolitan area.

III. The Empirical Model and Results

The equation is estimated with multivariate ordinary least squares regression. First, the Spillman and Zak study is replicated using suspicious fires as a measure of arsons, as in their study. Spillman and Zak used quarterly observations from 1963-1976 in first-difference equations, regressing suspicious fires on the unemployment rate, including indicators for seasons. They estimated:

[DELTA]Suspicious [Fires.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] * [DELTA]Unemployment [Rate.sub.1] + [[beta].sub.2]*[Q.sub.1] + [[beta].sub.3]*[Q.sub.2] + [[beta].sub.4]*[Q.sub.3]

Because we use annual data, quarterly indictors are not needed. Thus, we "replicate" the Zak and Spillman estimates with first-difference regressions (4) of suspicious fires on the unemployment rate, using annual data from 1971 through 2003. Then, new estimates are made, adding the housing market measures. Each dependent variable, arsons and suspicious fires, is regressed on the unemployment rate, the mortgage rate, and the home price index:

Arson or Suspicious [Fires.sub.1] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] * Unemployment [Rate.sub.1] +[[beta].sub.2]* Mortgage [Rate.sub.1] + [[beta].sub.3]* Home Price [Index.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t]

Population is controlled by dividing arsons or suspicious fires by population.

We replicate Spillman and Zak's 1979 estimates using our more recent annual data in order to insure that any differences we find compared to the Spillman and Zak results are not a consequence of the different data used for estimation. The estimated replication, using first differences, is:

[DELTA]Suspicious Fires = -2.478 - 2.042 [DELTA] Unemployment Rate (-0.33) (-0.240)

with t-statistics in parentheses, an adjusted coefficient of determination of -0.04, and an F-ratio of 0.05. The coefficient on the unemployment rate is not statistically significantly different from zero. The results are similar to Spillman and Zak's, with low explanatory power and no significant coefficients.

The empirical results reported in Table 1, adding direct measures of housing prices, reveal strong correlations between arson and the housing market variables, but continued weak associations of arson with employment conditions. (5) In fact, the estimated coefficient of the unemployment rate implies that arsons decline during periods of higher unemployment. This suggests that changes in possible benefits have a greater effect on decisions to commit arson than changes in potential costs of being apprehended and punished. In Table 1, each measure of arson is estimated using the unemployment rate, the mortgage rate, and the housing price index. Since the unemployment rate, the mortgage rate, and the housing price index have hypothetical unambiguous effects on arson, one-tail t-tests are used to determine statistical significance. The coefficients of both the mortgage interest rate and the housing price index are statistically significant at the one percent level in both regressions. Rising property values are associated with less arson. Importantly, however, the unemployment rate is not significant in either regression (because its sign is contrary to expectations). The mortgage rate is significantly correlated with suspicious fires in all four estimates, and the housing price index is statistically significant in each regression except the one on suspicious fires that does not control for population. The adjusted coefficient of determination for the regression on suspicious fires without controlling for population, the one in Table 1 closest to the Spillman and Zak replication, is 60 percent vis-a-vis virtually zero for the replication.

The regression on arsons per 10,000 people predicts one additional arson per 10,000 people annually is associated with a six percentage point rise in the mortgage interest rate (which would cause a decline in housing prices). Using Nashville's average annual population of 510,243 over the period of analysis, this means a one percentage point rise in mortgage rates is associated with 8.6 more arsons per year. A one percentage point decline in the Housing Price Index is predicted to be associated with 0.015 more annual arsons per 10,000 people or 0.8 more arsons per year.

Our results concerning the association between arson and general business conditions are similar to those of Spillman and Zak, namely fluctuations in unemployment are not correlated with arson. Combined with the strong direct correlations between arson and property values, the results indicate that labor market conditions more likely reflect opportunity costs of committing arson than represent the expected benefits of arson. Unemployment apparently does not change opportunity costs enough to alter decisions to deliberately burn structures. As expected by arson investigators (Crewse, 2005; Hunter, 2005; Scott, 2005), higher property values and lower mortgage interest rates are associated with fewer arsons.

IV. Conclusion

Estimates using data from Nashville, Tennessee show that unemployment is not related to the incidence of arson, but that property values are highly correlated with arson. Although Spillman and Zak did not detect significant relationships between arson and general business cycle conditions, arson does appear to be related directly to property values. In light of the volatile housing market conditions from 2007 to 2011, continued analysis of the relation of arson with the business cycle during a rapidly changing housing market could further clarify the connection between arson and housing prices. Similar studies for other metropolitan areas would help improve our understanding of moral hazard and indicate whether our conclusions about the causes of arson can be generalized.

References

Becker, Gary S., "Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach." Journal of Political Economy 76(2) (March/April 1968): 169-217.

Brotman, Billie Ann, and Pauline Fox. "The Impact of Economic Conditions on the Incidence of Arson: Comment." Journal of Risk and Insurance. 55(4) (December 1988): 751-754.

"Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions." National Bureau of Economic Research. 17 Dec. 2005 <http://www.nber.org/cycles.html>.

Cloninger, Dale O. "Risk, Arson and Abandonment." Journal of Risk and Insurance. 48(3) (September 1981): 494-504.

Cloninger, Dale O. "Arson and Abandonment: A Restatement." Journal of Risk and Insurance. 57(3) (September 1990): 540-545.

Crewse, Douglas O. "Financial Statement Analysis Methods in Arson for Profit Investigations." InterFIRE.org (2005). 16 Dec. 2005 <http://www.interfire.org/res_file/fuab_fs.asp>.

Dyl, Edward A., and Hugh W. Long. "Abandonment Value and Capital Budgeting: Comment." Journal of Finance. 24(1) (March 1969): 88-95.

Ehrlich, Isaac. "Participation in Illegitimate Activities: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation." Journal of Political Economy 81(3) (May/June 1973): 521-565.

Green, Steven L., and J Allen Seward. The Economics of Residential Arson: Theory and Evidence from a Panel of Cities. American Risk and Insurance Association, Oct. 1998. 28 Jan. 2006 <http://finance.baylor.edu/seminars/papers/Arson.pdf>.

Hershbarger, Robert A., and Ronald K. Miller. "The Impact of Economic Conditions on the Incidence of Arson." Journal of Risk and Insurance 45 (1978): 275-290.

Hunter, Michelle. "Arson suspected in rash of fires." The New Orleans Times-Picayune 10 Nov. 2005. 16 Dec. 2005 <http://www.nola.com/news/t-p/metro/index.ssf?/base/news- 11/1131605687166260.xm1>.

Joy, Maurice O. "Abandonment Values and Abandonment Decisions: A Clarification." Journal of Finance. 30(3) (September 1976): 1225-28.

Robichek, A. and James C. Van Home. "Abandonment Value and Capital Budgeting." Journal of Finance. 22(4) (December 1967): 577-89.

Scott, Charles. Deputy Fire Marshal, Nashville-Davidson County. Personal interview. 5 Dec. 2005.

Spillman, Thomas C., and Thomas A. Zak. "Arson: An Economic Phenomenon?" The American Economist 23 (1979): 37-43.

The State of Tennessee. Department of Labor and Workforce Development. Labor Force, Employment & Unemployment. 2005. 17 Dec. 2005 <http://source.virtuallmi.com/>.

United States. U.S. Census Bureau. About Population Projections. 2 Aug. 2002. 17 Dec. 2005 <http://www.census.gov/population/www/projections/aboutproj.html>.

United States. Primary Mortgage Market Survey. Federal Home Loan Mortgage Association. 30-Year Fixed-Rate Mortgages Since 1971. Mar. 2006. 21 Mar. 2006 <http://www.freddiemac.com/pmms/pmms30.htm>.

United States. Economic and Housing Research. Federal Home Loan Mortgage Association. Conventional Mortgage Home Price Index Q3 2005 Release. 5 Feb. 2006. 28 Feb. 2006 <http://www.freddiemac.com/finance/cmhpi/>.

United States. U.S. Fire Administration. Department of Homeland Security. Fire in the United States 1992-2001 13th Edition. Oct. 2004. 19 Sept. 2005 <http://www.usfa.fema.gov/statistics/reports/pubs/flus13th.shtm>.

Notes

(1.) Arson data are unavailable for 1990 and 1998, leaving 31 annual observations from 1971 through 2003, a period covering five recessions in the United States. Recessions identified by the National Bureau of Economic Research (2005) are: November 1973-March 1975, January 1980-July 1980, July 1981-November 1982, July 1990-March 1991, and March 2001-November 2001.

(2.) Since 1971, the FHLMA has surveyed lenders to determine the weekly average 30-year fixed-rate mortgage rate. The weekly averages are compiled into an annual average.

(3.) FHLMA (February 2006) constructs a home price index using repeat sales of same homes.

(4.) Spillman and Zak (1979, 3743) used a first-difference model because the original unit regressions "revealed serious first-order autocorrelation." Our replication similarly exhibits severe serial correlation, and so we have replicated likewise using first differences.

(5.) The numbers of fires and arsons has decreased over time. A trend variable could capture changes in fire/smoke alarms, building codes, etc. that have improved fire safety over time. A time-trend variable was used in regressions not reported; it did not explain enough of the variation in arson to warrant the sacrifice of a degree of freedom. Durbin-Watson statistics in Table 1 show no positive serial correlation, suggesting that the underlying relationships between the economic variables and arsons or suspicious fires do not suffer from serial correlation, and, first differences are not necessary. To confirm that these correlations are not simply spurious because these variables have similar underlying trends, a Dickey-Fuller cointegration test is used to test stationarity of the residuals. Because each regression exhibits a significant cointegration relationship at the one percent level, and the original regressions are not spurious, first-difference regressions are not necessary.

Frank E. Corrigan III, Vanderbilt University

John J. Siegfried, American Economic Association and University of Adelaide, South Australia
TABLE 1.
Estimates of Arson for Nashville, Tennessee

                                                Suspicious
Independent Variables              Arsons          Fires

Constant                           185.273      156.611
                                    (4.329)      (2.783)

Unemployment Rate                  -10.277      -25.567
                                   (-1.540)     (-2.914)

Mortgage Rate                        8.565 **    19.375 **
                                    (2.858)      (4.918)

Housing Price Index                 -0.523 **    -0.247
                                   (-3.144)     (-1.131)

Adjusted [R.sup.2]                   0.601        0.598

Durbin-Watson Stat                   2.281 *      1.780 *

F-statistic                         14.036 *     13.894 *

[[beta].sub.1] from Dickey-         -1.076 **    -0.835 **
Fuller

[DELTA][e.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.]   (-4.922)     (-4.226)
[e.sub.t-1] + [[eta].sub.t]

                                     Arsons/     Suspicious Fires
Independent Variables              Population      /Population

Constant                             3.977         3.255
                                    (4.576)       (2.962)

Unemployment Rate                   -0.169        -0.448
                                   (-1.244)      (-2.613)

Mortgage Rate                        0.168 **      0.388 **
                                    (2.759)       (5.037)

Housing Price Index                 -0.0146 **    -0.00938 *
                                   (-4.327)      (-2.196)

Adjusted [R.sup.2]                   0.710         0.688

Durbin-Watson Stat                   2.144 *       1.843 *

F-statistic                         21.367 *      20.072 *

[[beta].sub.1] from Dickey-         -1.052 **     -0.863 **
Fuller

[DELTA][e.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.]   (-4.806)      (-4.000)
[e.sub.t-1] + [[eta].sub.t]

Number of observations = 31 years

t-scores in parentheses: one-tail tests

* significant at the 5% level.

** significant at the 1 % level.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有