The Heart of Teaching Economics: Lessons from Leading Minds.
Ramrattan, Lall ; Szenberg, Michael
The Heart of Teaching Economics: Lessons from Leading Minds, by
Simon W. Bowmaker, (Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 2010).
Introduction
The Heart of Teaching Economics: Lessons from Leading Minds by
Simon Bowmaker contains gems that no one concerned with economics can
afford to ignore. These treasures are targeted toward students, teachers
and lovers of economics. The material contained in the volume will
affect the "mind set and attitudes" of teachers according to
Robert Solow (Foreword). The book supports the theme that a love of
economics and good teaching are correlated. Good teaching is not just
textbook teaching, but extends to a coherent view of economic ideas. It
complements research, widens the differential in the achievement level
between the average and the most talented students, nurtures students to
reveal their talents, develops them fully, and, what is most important,
closes the gap between the actual and the potential self.
Bowmaker's volume contains 21 interviews circumscribed by four
themes: talking about teaching, the role of teachers, the fruits of a
teacher's experience, and teaching vs. research. The book addresses
these questions in three parts, namely, "Fundamentals,"
"Tools," and "Applications." Each face-to-face
interview answers seven questions: Background, General Thought on
Teaching, The Learning Process, Teaching Philosophy and Techniques,
Course Content, Design and Textbooks, and finally, Teaching Economics in
the Future. Bowmaker's most serious message is centered on what to
learn and how to learn. In this regard we find core principles in the
various subdisciplines in economics in this book, and a variegated way
to impart and know them.
The book offers recommendations for teaching that is suggested by
the nature of economics itself. Sir John Hicks separated three aspects:
"There is much of economic theory which is pursued for no better
reason than its intellectual attraction ... Secondly, there is a part of
economic theory which is pursued for the sake of ideology; it is
concerned with ideal arrangements, whether of the Left or the Right ...
In the third place, there is optimum theory, allocation theory, given
ends and scarce resources" (Hicks, 1979, viii-ix).
A teacher can take the cue from Adam Smith that economics is based
on moral philosophy as he expounded in his earlier book Theory of Moral
Sentiments. We find there the "doctrine that our judgments
concerning our own conduct have always a reference to the sentiments of
some other being ... that our judgments concerning the conduct of others
are founded in sympathy" (Smith, 197, 49). In modern parlance, we
can read into this spiritual connectivity with passionate delivery,
giving time and energy of ourselves, genuine generosity and kindness,
empathy, spiritual uplift, and finally, the best moral dictum: love your
students as your children. We must be mindful, however, that some of
what Adam Smith expounded comes under the categories of either preaching
or nondescript ideas. But "the preaching ... becomes almost
nonexistent in Ricardo's Principles, quite sparse in Mills's
Principles, and virtually nonexistent in Marshall's
Principles" (Stigler, 1982, 4) [Italics original].
A tremendous amount of material is covered in this book of
interviews. Everyone is expected to find their own gems buried in its
pages, and our approach cannot be exhaustive. We have distilled some of
the best concepts in this book for several topical areas including
formalism, creativity and novelty, learning techniques, old vs. new, and
imitative learning, among others.
Formalism
Subjects such as mathematical economics and econometrics are by
nature formal. Yet we find that the authors do not approach them from a
truly formal point of view. A truly formal point of view of teaching
mathematical economics would be to follow the Moore method for instance.
The method of R. L. Moore requires a syllabus listing definitions,
axioms and theorems. The class is conducted in a manner where students
are called to the board to prove those theorems, without any lecture
from the teacher (Krantz, 1999, 32). Even in mathematics teachers are
skeptical of the method, and it is not unknown to have modified
Moore's method and even to choose no Moore method at all. The
formalists' method in this book falls somewhat in between the Moore
and the modified Moore method.
In the application of math and stats to economics, the Nobel
laureate Ragnar Frisch wrote, "I have started with a detailed
discussion of a few particularly simple special cases. But I have not
applied to these simple cases the elementary and easy method which might
have been sufficient to solve the problem in these particular cases. In
this way, the reader is brought--in a quite intuitive manner, usually
without the aid of any proof--to understand the steps leading to the
generalization. The generalization then becomes almost evident"
[Italics inserted] (Frisch, 1966, v). This might be likened to the idea
of a sketch of the proof usually employed by mathematicians. We find in
Alfred Marshall, however, a tendency to put all mathematical analyses in
the appendices of his Principles of Economics. On the other hand,
Augustin Cournot, Leon Walras, and Paul Samuelson had a permanent home
for mathematics in their writings.
In the fundamental section of the book, we meet John Taylor's
teaching principles of economics emphasizing a mixture of the two sided
nature of economics. He is not referring to the demand and supply sides,
but the "fuzzy" and "techie" sides dealing with
history, with philosophy on the fuzzy side, and math on the technical
side. Professor Taylor believes in teaching models, and in using models
to analyze historic periods of the economy. Similarly, he prescribed a
proper mixture of graphs, equations, and stories for effective learning
(28). He extends this mixture concept to an idea one can introduce in
the classroom: "you should give both sides to whatever extent you
can" (33).
Robert Frank's early approach was to "teach people how to
master ideas and apply them" (6). This is best done in the form of
a narrative, that is, a story with an interesting plot and characters
that can easily be transmitted. Caroline Hoxby, who teaches public
economics, also has the same approach: logical organization and stories.
After transmission of ideas, memory comes with application of the idea.
Robert Frank has found that placing students into the real world to pick
up a question and then asking them to write 500 words about it
contributes to retention of learning.
William Green, a bestseller writer, does not recommend the
theorem-proof style in the teaching of econometrics (102). He tells his
students that they are going to do formalism in their own research
(107). He advises students to learn what the software is doing, and not
just push a button for the answer. Rather than proof, he emphasizes
empirical work and explains the direction, drift in the subject such as
toward robust estimates and why autocorrelation is present rather than
how to correct for it (109). His technique of teaching varies between
teaching to teach and teaching to do econometrics.
In the technical field of games theory, Benjamin Polak says that
formalism should be motivated and illustrated (88). The method of
teaching he recommends is to discuss what a model means, write down
crude models and have the student criticize them (92). For instance,
teaching backward induction requires the student to put himself in the
shoes of others (93). Using traditional methods of proof, for instance
by induction, does not go well in the classroom. Instructors need to
teach enough unnecessary steps so that the pattern can be discerned
(85). "Some students' minds freeze on math, and so getting
them over that is quite important," Polak says (89). He thinks it
useful for everyone in the social sciences to learn some game theory,
but would not generalize that all of social science is just a branch of
game theory (90).
Creativity and Novelty
One major aspect of creativity is novelty, which is concerned with
reaching new results or behavior (Chance, 1994, 148). Teaching at the
Intermediate level, David Landsburg brings many creative aspects to his
teaching of microeconomics. He teaches that students should not answer a
question by squeezing it into a mold that they are familiar with (45).
Creativity can mean "How would this answer have been different if
this curve had been shaped a little differently or if this point had
been in a different place?" (46).
David Lansburg uses dialogue in the classroom as a way to
understand the students learning process (47). He stresses
"intellectual rigor," "formal apparatus,"
assumptions, logical steps, conclusions about modes, and a certain
playfulness in learning. Students get only 50 percent credit on exams
for regurgitating materials they have learned from the instructor (46).
Ideas in the history of economics make sense when situated in
context, says Steven Medema. Ideas evolve, are "historically
contingent," and should be presented as such (146). Many theories
were developed "in light of a particular social or economic
problem" (155). Reading primary sources are important to bring out
how ideas are articulated, compared, and reasoned in different epochs
(147). One's understanding deepens when he investigates how a
theory developed (153). Controversial ideas such as Marxism may be
handled with a pros and cons approach (157).
Old vs. New Theories
New theories and research are brought in to liven up a class.
Professor Gordon, who gave us a bestseller in intermediate
macroeconomics, supplements the dated editions of the books he teaches
with PowerPoint presentations on research materials (61). He uses models
such as the IS-LM, AD-AS, and the Phillips curve for numerical and
historical analysis. He believes that "there are models that really
do provide answers" (72) and begins his course with wonderful
examples, emphasizing the business cycle upfront to gradually increase
the level of the student knowledge and then brings in the importance of
incentives in economics (62). Professor Gordon is emphatic on what he
leaves out in a course that is on a quarter basis--new classical, new
Keynesian, and real business cycle theory (66). He is wedded to the
paradigm that potential output and the natural rate of unemployment are
the same, and their fluctuations are mirror images of one another (67).
He uses quizzes to gauge the student learning process, and grades tend
to be high: "A's, A minuses, and B pluses, so it doesn't
matter how hard the exams are, they're all being graded relative to
each other" (62).
Perhaps no subject has suffered a more paradigmatic shift than
Industrial Organization. Luis Cabral, who teaches the subject, propounds
that "learning is a process that bounces back and forth between the
concrete and the abstract and uses analogy a lot" (238). Industrial
Organization has moved toward a new base defined by game theory, which
in pure form can be as abstract as mathematics. But when ordinary games
are used for business problems some will side with Ken Binmore, a modern
game theorist, that "all of social science is just a branch of game
theory" (90).
Imitation
Many scholars teach the way they were taught. As a master of
economic history, Barry Eichengreen learned to teach by observing his
colleagues engaging the audience (163). "One way humans learn is by
observing others--how other humans identify, conceptualize and solve
problems" (165). Shoshana Grossbard, who teaches family economics,
feels that "to some degree we are role models to students"
(257). That is, to some extent, what teachers do and teach is for the
students to imitate and follow, a leader-follower strategy in some
regards. But problem-solving skills are important as well. Studying
topical events in history gives students "a metric by which to
gauge the policy response" (Eichengreen, 169). He recommends we use
models to organize and structure facts (169). For instance, Eichengreen
uses models of growth, distribution and cycles to structure the stages
of globalization in modern times. (170).
Learning Theory
Almost all of the respondents disclaim any theoretical knowledge of
learning theory. Yet we find them giving their opinion on the matter.
Those opinions are so natural that they do have a home in learning
theory, and are not inconsistent with the general ideas we noted in the
introduction from the masters of economics for imparting economic
knowledge.
Attentional and retentional processes are conducive to learning
(Chance, 1994, 173). Respondents in this book try to make their subject
lively to hold attention. In his teaching of money and banking, Frederic
Mishkin thinks that being enthusiastic and passionate makes teaching a
lively activity (384). He and others believe that by explaining the real
world with models attracts attention and retention.
Students tend to retain what they use. Dan Hamermesh asserts that
"the professor has to stimulate you and get you turned on to
something. If you see the value in learning, you will learn better"
(199). Edward Glaeser thinks that in urban economics, students should be
given a core set of tools (217). Nancy Folbre, who teaches race and
gender, also feels that motivation is important for learning (291).
David Cutler, who teaches health economics, would say that incentives,
different views, and graphical representations are important for
learning too (271). Hamermesh promises the students, "I will not
give you any tool that I would not use to analyze any real-world problem
in this class" (201). He thinks that a good way to gain retention
is through rap, for example: "With positive externalities,
it's always wise/To encourage more production--subsidize"
(203). He contributes to the Freakonomics blog, and culls stories from
it to tell his students (202).
In teaching developmental economics, William Easterly appeals to
metaphors and intuition to gain attention. For instance, he probes the
students to discover that their labor would fetch a higher price if they
sell it to the world market where demand is larger than if they sell in
their state alone (360). Similarly, in the area of international trade,
Gene Grossman appeals to experiences that students can relate to in
order to teach a complex subject such as Rybinski Theorem (344). He asks
them to be a bartender making weak and strong screwdrivers that require
two factors, namely orange juice and vodka. If suddenly you come by more
vodka, then you naturally will want to make stronger screwdrivers. But
you will also make less weak screwdrivers in the process because you
would have to take away some orange juice from the production of weak
screwdrivers. In the end you get a more proportional increase in the
goods that use the more intensive factor, vodka, and less of the other
goods.
In his teaching of environmental economics, John List tries to
involve the student in the learning process through such means as
questions and answers or experiments (305). Hamermesh does an experiment
to teach the long-run average cost curve. He brings a colander and some
balls to class to illustrate that "if you slide the colander and
the balls are lined up, the ball at the bottom will be tangent to the
bottom of the colander" (231). For David Laibson, teaching
behavioral economics allows for weekly experiments in class (125). He
follows instruction with a lesson in method, encouraging students to
start writing papers (127). The tools he recommends are a combination of
mathematical modeling and empiricism, judgment, and intuition (131). Big
ideas such as bounded rationality, temporal conflicts, and themes about
distribution define the course.
Finally, there is the concept of discovery. According to David
Friedman, "You never know anything unless you have invented it for
yourself" (325). Instructors' models and words convey ideas to
the students. "The purpose of words is to catch ideas; once you
have the ideas, you don't need the words" (325). One way to
teach according to this principle is to introduce puzzles. Students will
think of the puzzles, and perhaps come up with their own answers before
it is given to them. On the model side, Friedman believes that it is
difficult to make standard model useful only because the teacher thinks
it is (326). To some extent, this is the opinion of the bestselling game
theorist author Ariel Rubinstein: "In my 30 years in the
profession, I have not encountered a single case in which game theory
has provided a real solution to a problem and have not found any
evidence that it has the ability to improve strategic thinking"
(94).
Pitching the level of the course
Pitching the level of teaching to a heterogeneous group of students
is a difficult matter for all teachers. A frequent technique used is
teaching to the median level of the students. Some respondents, however,
gave other views. Robert Frank aims "at the people who are never
going to take another course because the're the ones who are far
more numerous than the others" (14). John Taylor qualifies his
sentences so that he does not teach above the best or below the worst
students in the class (32). Steven Landsburg, Steven Madema, Barry
Eichengreen, and John List aim at the high end of the class only (48,
149, 168, 310). Caroline Hoxby thinks that students who want to become
professional theorists or econometricians should have a deep dose of
math or econometrics (187). Edward Glaeser and David Friedman target the
top half of the students (221, 330). David Cutler uses many applications
and tries not to be complicated (275). Nancy Folbre finds that asking
students to work together in groups helps to overcome heterogeneity
(293). Both David Laibson and Benjamin Polak reduce mathematics to
accommodate the less analytically inclined students (89, 126). William
Easterly addresses all levels by presenting the materials intuitively,
with words, with graphs, and math equations (364).
Conclusions
We owe the author and the participants much gratitude for this
book. The knowledge they share can come only with extensive experience
over the course of a lifetime spent in the classrooms of the top
educational institutions in the United States.
We find ample exemplars to approach the difficult task of teaching
in this book. Teachers learn that there is not one way to teach a group
of heterogeneous students and that student attention and retention can
be grabbed in different ways. More importantly for teachers, this book
is evidence that no single strategy is the "best" method of
teaching. There are many ways to engage students, and one may teach with
or without models, math, and rigor.
Bowmaker's interviews incorporate the latest discoveries in
teaching. For instance, William Greene's way of introducing
asymptotic distribution theory to econometric estimates brings out the
cognitive aspect of teaching difficult concepts such as infinity (110).
The same may be said for Hamermesh's colander and ball experiment
to cognize tangency condition with the long-run average cost curve, and
David Landsburg's method of changing points and curvature in
microeconomics. We learn from modern neuroscience research through NOVA
that the brain follows the curve as teachers used them, say, on the
chalkboard. The time honored method of presenting supply and demand
diagrams still stands well, therefore, with modern neuroscience
research. We see also how teaching Freakonomics, rap, and metaphor
enables retention. Many respondents use PowerPoint presentations as a
way to integrate research into teaching.
The book represents a balanced presentation of the subdisciplines
of economics. More or less representation of one area over another will
be a natural concern for the readers. The teachers show us how to do
ordinary things extraordinarily. Some will say that their task is
impossible to accomplish without the acquisition of enemies. We think
their tasks represent teaching and learning in a scientific way, and
therefore, we highly recommend this book to readers.
References
Chance, Paul, Learning and Behavior, Third Edition, (Pacific Grove,
CA: Brooks/Cole Publishing Company, 1994).
Frisch, Ragnar, Maxima and Minima: Theory and Economic
Applications, (Chicago, IL: Rand McNally & Company, 1966).
Hicks, John R., Causality in Economics, (New York: Basic Books,
1979).
Krantx, Steven G., How to Teach Mathematics, Second Edition,
(Providence, RI: American Mathematical Society, 1999).
Smith, Adam, The Correspondence of Adam Smith, edited by Ernest
Campbell Mossner and Ian simpson Ross, (Oxford, U. K.: The Clarendon
Press, 1977).
Stigler, George J., The Economist as Preacher and Other Essays,
(The University of Chicago Press, 1982).
LALL RAMRATTAN
University of California, Berkeley Extension
and
MICHAEL SZENBERG
Lubin School of Business, Pace University