Finding a niche.
Eichengreen, Barry
Becoming a professor was easier than becoming an economist. Growing
up in Berkeley I was surrounded by professors; they dominated my
parents' dinner parties, though my mother and father themselves
were not academics. The conversation touched on book projects,
sabbatical plans, and foreign travel. There was the security of a
regular paycheck but, so it seemed, no one resembling a boss.
Growing up in Berkeley had its distinctive aspects. An outing for
the socially conscious was going down to the university and getting tear
gassed. At about this time the high-school curriculum compelled one to
choose between natural science, social science and humanities tracks.
Social sciences were irresistible for someone growing up in this
political petri dish. The natural sciences track, in contrast, would
have meant more math. Early decisions have long-term consequences.
UC Santa Cruz, where I was an undergraduate, was another child of
the 1960s. Intended as an alternative to factory schools like Berkeley
it had no grades, few major and breadth requirements, and little
intellectual structure. (1) Students were encouraged to design their own
majors. This encouraged healthy disrespect for conventional academic
boundaries, something that comes in handy for an economic historian.
Santa Cruz also sent me for my junior year to the University of St.
Andrews. St. Andrews students met periodically with a tutor to discuss
assignments and read papers. My tutor was the Spanish economic historian
Geoffrey Parker. In my senior year back at Santa Cruz, the department
then hired as a visitor a brilliant graduate student from Stanford,
Flora Gill, to teach a course in economic history.
Put an undergraduate in an unstructured environment, and he or she
will go in one of two directions. One is off the deep end, which for my
classmates meant making candles in Ben Lomand. The other is in search of
more structure. This is my best explanation for how I ended up in
economics. Economics seemed to have more intellectual structure than the
other social sciences, all of which, as a good Santa Cruz undergraduate,
I sampled. Not that I actually learned much about what economists do,
Santa Cruz not being organized to convey such knowledge.
Sometime around the middle of my senior year there was a sparsely
attended meeting of students and faculty to discuss life after college.
Various possibilities were described. One was to enroll in more school.
A more novel alternative was to look for work. One professor who had
spent time in Washington, D.C. suggested that it might be possible to
apply what one had learned by working as a research assistant in a
government agency. When I asked him how to go about this, he seemed
genuinely shocked at having a student follow up on his suggestion.
"Write my former boss at the U.S. Department of Labor," he
suggested. After some weeks, there was no response. Fortunately this
member of the faculty had also been a dissertation fellow at the
Brookings Institution. There the director of Economic Studies, the
prominent tax-policy expert Joe Pechman, was losing his research
assistant before the end of the academic year and was desperate to find
someone who could begin in early April. I was graduating a quarter early
and therefore available off cycle. I like to think that it was on the
intellectual merits that I beat out other candidates for this job, but
there is another interpretation.
Joe Pechman was a famously successful example of how to do
high-quality policy analysis with limited background in mathematics. Joe
substituted intuition, detailed knowledge of the U.S. tax code, and an
ability to write clearly and quickly for technical skills. He also
moderated a Friday lunch at which a galaxy of Brookings fellows
commented on the events of the day. (2) In 1974-5 the conversation
ranged over the first OPEC oil shock, inflation, and Watergate. If
events like those couldn't awaken an interest in policy, it was
hard to imagine what could. Brookings also offered its research
assistants free time and a library that just happened to include a
complete run of the Journal of Economic History. And it provided a Good
Housekeeping Seal of Approval. Many of Joe's previous research
assistants, mostly Swarthmore undergraduates (my position was known
colloquially as "the Swarthmore chair"), had gone on to
graduate school. Thus it was possible for an applicant with no grades
and limited coursework in economics to be admitted to a Ph.D. program.
I arrived at Yale already knowing that I wanted to concentrate on
economic history and international macroeconomics. This is the hardest
part of my intellectual journey to explain. Economic history was not
done seriously at Santa Cruz. It was not done at all at Brookings.
Macroeconomics in the 1970s was still almost entirely a closed-economy
affair. And the combination of economic history and international
macroeconomics was virtually unknown. (3) To be sure, I had already had
chance encounters with Geoff Parker and Flora Gill. Economic history
appealed to someone with a healthy disregard for disciplinary
boundaries. Much of what I knew about economics at this point was
self-taught, having been gained by checking out journals from the
Brookings library, and economic history journals were more accessible
than most. For its part, international economics appealed to someone
whose parents were first-generation Americans and who had been made
aware from a relatively early age that the United States was part of a
larger world. There was also the example of my closest childhood friend,
Jeff Frankel, who had already discovered international economics as a
student of Rudi Dornbusch at MIT.
James Tobin and William Parker dominated my Yale experience. Tobin
of course dominated everyone's Yale experience. His belief that
economics could be used to make the world more just and equitable
affected everyone around him including the graduate students. My own
vaguely Keynesian inclinations and belief that economics and economic
history can serve the public interest are inherited to a considerable
extent from Jim.
Although Tobin was not a member of my dissertation committee, he
encouraged me to apply modern macroeconomic methods to historical
problems. Much of Tobin's course in monetary economics was
organized as Yale-style portfolio theory versus Chicago-style monetarism
with Milton Friedman as doppelganger. (4) But we also read one
uncharacteristically sympathetic assessment of Friedman, Tobin's
review of Friedman and Schwartz's Monetary History of the United
States, in which he hailed the book as path-breaking for its systematic
application of macroeconomic theory to historical problems
The Yale department's economic historian, Bill Parker, was
could lay claim to being the first "new" economic historian,
having drawn the Parker-Klein sample of grain-growing farms from the
1840 census and editing, together with Douglass North, the Journal of
History when the first articles making explicit use of economic theory
were accepted for publication in the 1950s. But Bill was known best for
his students, Jan deVries, Joel Mokyr and Gavin Wright prominent among
them. (5) Parker at Yale played much the same role as Alexander
Gerschenkron at Harvard. (6) He humanized an increasingly technical
economics curriculum. He served as a bridge to the historical literature
on economic growth and development.
In the wake of Time on the Cross, scholarship in economic history
was driven by debates over methodology. Quantification good or bad?
Should counterfactuals be explicit? Is there anything left to be learned
from the narrative approach? In contrast to many other economic
historians, Bill was interested more in substance than methodology. He
saw the advantage of picking, choosing and blending methodologies as
appropriate for the question at hand. Once the fervor of the Cliometric
revolution died down, this was the position to which a more mature
subdiscipline gravitated. Bill got there before most, which allowed him
to pitch a large tent for students with very different analytical
inclinations.
Parker's office was divided into a large library containing
pretty much every consequential book in economic history, in which I
spent the best part of my graduate-student career, and an ante-room
barely big enough for a desk and chair, where Bill napped and
occasionally dispensed advice. My own ideas were met mainly with grunts
and nods. I learned that some graduate students, like some missiles, are
self-guiding, while others must be pointed at the target.
When it came to international finance there was no shortage of role
models. There was Carlos Diaz-Alejandro, who had already thought of
combining economic history and international economics. (7) There was
Paul Krugman, whose spell as a Yale assistant professor coincided with
the year I began searching for a dissertation topic. (8) There was
Pentti Kouri, the enfant terrible who had completed his MIT Ph.D. in two
years. Finally there was Robert Triffin, whose interests in the
historical evolution of the international monetary system were closest
to my own. Triffin had written the definitive book on the subject.
Actually, he had written it three times. (9) Triffin being on leave for
most of my years as a graduate student, I encountered him only once,
during the qualifying examination that followed coursework but preceded
the dissertation, the format for which was two hours of grilling, half
an hour from each of four professors. I was warned that Triffin would
probably spend his half an hour asking about the Triffin Dilemma, as the
dynamic instability of a gold-exchange or gold-dollar standard was
known. So I studied this issue. Fortunately, Triffin's questions
focused entirely on this one subject.
This left only finding a thesis topic. The time-tested approach to
this problem, employed by generations of graduate students, is delay. I
delayed by taking a master's in history: Yale offered a program
where graduate students in history and economics could spend a year
taking courses in the other department, permitting them to call
themselves card-carrying economic historians. I took courses from Vann
Woodward, Harry Miskimin and John Merriman but ended up no closer to a
topic.
I thought I knew what a suitable topic would entail. I wanted to
look at a different historical time and place, but I also wanted policy
relevance so that what I wrote about that episode would speak to an
audience beyond historical specialists. I hoped to draw material from
the archives in a language with which I was familiar. The problem should
have an international dimension about which I could theorize. The
statistical base had to be sufficient to permit econometric analysis.
This did not leave many degrees of freedom. I ended up writing on the
Great Depression in Britain and specifically on the decision to impose a
tariff only after the country abandoned the gold standard in 1931.
Whether the imposition of a tariff under these circumstances was
sensible was not obvious. What, after all, could a tariff do for
industries suffering from inadequate demand, partly owing to import
competition, that currency depreciation could not once sterling was free
to float? In early 1931 Keynes had written in favor of a tariff on the
grounds that the external constraint had to be relaxed in order for
monetary policy to be loosened, but he reversed course once the gold
standard was abandoned. In the late 1970s a group of post-Keynesian
Cambridge economists around Francis Cripps and Wynne Godley
rehabilitated his arguments, suggesting that the UK should impose a
general tariff to reconcile expansionary policies with the external
constraint. Although sterling had again begun to float, the Cambridge
Economic Policy Group argued that it was now real rather than nominal
wages that were rigid, the implication being that a tariff could have an
effect on relative prices that currency depreciation could not. So, in
addition to its historical interest, the topic had points of contact
with current policy. With benefit of hindsight I now see that this was
not the best way of selecting a dissertation topic. A thesis should be
driven by an interesting question, not by a long list of methodological
desiderata. (10) Given the number of self-imposed constraints, it is
perhaps not surprising that I never managed to develop that dissertation
into a book. (11)
I finished my thesis in a fellowship year in Oxford. I read files
at the Public Record Office documenting the debate over sterling and the
tariff. I visited Lionel Robbins, who recalled himself as having been on
the wrong side of his debate with Keynes. Wynne Godley explained his
position on the tariff over lunch at King's College. I struck up a
relationship with Alec Cairncross, who had studied with Keynes in the
1930s, been in government in both the 1940s and 1960s (two key periods
in the evolution of Britain's international monetary relations),
and now practiced the kind of economic history to which I aspired. (12)
I re-estimated my model of the interwar economy at the Oxford computing
center. This meant submitting the punch cards, going out for dinner at a
Chinese restaurant, and returning a couple of hours later to see if the
program had run. The supervisor that the university assigned me turned
out to be Nicholas Crafts, the leading UK-based new economic historian.
Nick at the time had attracted an exceptional collection of students,
including Steve Broadberry, Mary McKinnon, and Mark Thomas. The seminar
regularly adjourned to the pub, followed by the inevitable Chinese meal.
This was where I acquired the research agenda that sustained me for the
next couple of years.
What that dissertation did succeed at was getting me a job. It used
enough archival material to convince historians that I had something to
say about the context in which policy was made. And it contained a
sufficiently up-to-date theoretical model and convincing econometric
analysis of the effects to sell the economists. Or maybe it was the
archival analysis that convinced the economists and the theory that
impressed the historians. The challenge was presenting the archival
analysis, theoretical model, and econometric results in a single
seminar. The discussion of archival material typically occupied the
first half of the presentation. I can remember my Harvard job talk,
where after forty-five minutes I turned my back on the audience to write
the first equation on the chalkboard. The door clicked and a chair
scraped. The new arrival asked, sotto voice, "Is he only putting up
the first equation now?" (13)
Harvard was an exceptional place for an assistant professor of
economics. Memories of the mid-1970s, when the department refused tenure
to a contingent of radical economists led by Sam Bowles, leading to an
embarrassingly public spat, were still raw. The senior members of the
department concluded that assistant professors were more trouble than
they were worth. 1980 was the first time that the department swallowed
hard and hired a standard-sized contingent of new Ph.D.s. (14) But we
assistant professors, not being entirely trustworthy, were not invited
to faculty meetings. This of course was a great boon. Freed from
administrative responsibilities we had more time for research. (15)
What the Economics Department lacked in collegiality the economic
historians more than made up for. Bob Fogel had not participated in the
decision to hire me because he was already on his way back to the
University of Chicago. (16) But Fogel was supportive of my work and
characteristically interested in my opinions about his. (17) From Bob I
learned how to sustain a research agenda and organize large projects.
His successor Jeff Williamson was an example of how to formulate
questions of interest to economists, execute that research efficiently,
and attract students. Then there was David Landes, the eminent historian
of technology, who had moved to the Economics Department following a
falling out with his colleagues in History. David hosted the
after-seminar sherry hour in his office, where one could inspect the
latest finds that he had unearthed in Widener Library. David had little
patience for Cliometrics but could play the game. A favorite pastime was
guessing how many seconds into the seminar he would ask the first
question. If the speaker's opening line was "In this paper I
compare agrarian practice in three English villages," the question,
typically put in the first minute, was "why three?"
Peter Temin was a regular participant in the Harvard history
seminar and central to the Cambridge economic history scene. Just as one
waited each week for the David Landes question, one waited for the Peter
Temin question. Generally this came about two thirds of the way through
the seminar and took the form: "Isn't the issue that you are
really raising ...?" followed by a more interesting formulation of
the question than the author himself had offered. If the single most
important skill a scholar can acquire is figuring out what questions are
interesting and how to formulate them, then the little I know about this
I learned from Peter. (18)
After four years I had written a series of articles on
international aspects of the 1920s and 1930s: on the Bank of
England's interest rate policy, on the Bank of France's
sterilization of gold, on the collapse of the gold-exchange standard,
and on the effects of the devaluation of sterling. These were articles
in search of a book, though what form that book should take was not yet
clear. My colleague Jeff Sachs, together with Michael Bruno, had just
written a book taking an international approach to analyzing another
economic slump, that of the late 1970s and early 1980s. At some level
our interests were similar, and it seemed inevitable that eventually we
would co-author something. By the time we did, Jeff was already in
demand as a money doctor; he was spending most of his time on the plane
and phone to Bogota. We did our talking and writing between midnight and
5AM, when his more pressing duties were done. One of us then went home
to sleep, while the other got back on the phone.
What we did was a cross-country analysis, in the spirit of Bruno
and Sachs, of the effects of going oft the gold standard. The data
analysis was simple, but cross country variations (comparisons, for
example, of economic recovery in counties that were early and late to
abandon the gold standard) allowed for powerful tests of a sort that
individual country studies did not. (19) The results convinced me both
that the gold standard was central to the Great Depression and that
abandoning it had been the key to recovery. This pointed also to a
problem of political economy: given the advantages, which should have
been obvious to contemporaries, of cutting a country's links with
the deflationary gold standard system, what was it about its history and
politics that had rendered it more or less likely to take that step?
(20)
Finally, the fact that one country's decisions had clearly
affected outcomes in others meant that it was important to analyze the
operation of the gold standard as a system. Here the question was
whether the problem was a global gold shortage as suggested by Robert
Mundell or the intrinsic fragility of a gold-exchange standard as Robert
Triffin had argued. (21)
A thorough analysis of these issues, their interconnections, and
how they played out in different countries required a book-length
treatment. My view was and is that books should speak to a broader
audience than just academic economists. Journals, with their specialized
readership, are the best outlets for formal models and econometric
analyses. Books best omit this technical apparatus, since they are
potentially accessible to a wider audience. (22) The challenge for the
author of a monograph is how to characterize the issue, in this case how
policy toward the gold standard shaped the Great Depression and in turn
what shaped policy toward the gold standard, in a way that is internally
consistent and informed by theory but using words rather than equations.
It is to be able to sustain that characterization--to draw that red
thread through the various chapters so that they work together to
advance a single argument. Keeping the thread unbroken also means that
not all aspects of the problem can be addressed in a successful book. It
means knowing what to leave out. (23)
Some final examples may serve to illustrate how research agendas
develop. In 1990 a friend and colleague, Charles Wyplosz, became
co-editor of a new European policy forum, Economic Policy and asked me
for an article on historical precursors to a European monetary union, an
issue that was then rising rapidly on the policy agenda. Surely there
were historical precedents, he suggested, from the Latin Union to the
Scandinavian Union and the gold standard from which lessons might be
drawn. I concluded that this was not the case. If Europe was going to
succeed in creating a monetary union, it would have to establish true
transnational institution (a European Central Bank) unlike anything that
had existed under the Latin Union, the Scandinavian Union, or the gold
standard. (24) Doing so would entail significant pooling of national
sovereignty, something that was conceivable in contemporary Europe,
given the continent's history, but had not been possible in earlier
times and places. In turn these observations opened up a set of issues
about the connections between monetary, economic and political
integration in Europe that occupied me for more than a decade and
resulted ultimately in my book The European Economy Since 1945
(Princeton 2007).
Unprecedented is not the same as impossible. I was never among
those skeptical Americans who thought a European monetary union was
impossible because nothing like it had existed before and because it
would never work in North America. Floating exchange rates were not
acceptable to Europeans because of their history: the experience of the
1930s caused them to associate floating with Franco-German conflict. The
pegged but adjustable rates of the European Monetary System had been
feasible so long as capital controls were pervasive, but the Single
European Act mandated a single market in capital as well as labor and
merchandise, eliminating all scope for such controls. A close look at
the history of the gold standard served to remind one of the fragility
of pegged rates in a world of high capital mobility. This logic left
monetary union as the only alternative.
This point was driven home for me by the 1992 crisis in the
European Monetary System (EMS), whose outbreak happily (speaking from a
selfish point of view) coincided with the beginning of a sabbatical
year. This was the major financial event of my then-young professional
life, when George Soros made $1 billion betting against the Bank of
England and the process of European integration seemed to be falling off
a cliff. (25) Wyplosz and I abandoned our preexisting research agendas
to write the history of the crisis in real time. We surveyed financial
market participants: Charles' daughters licked the envelopes in
which we mailed our survey forms in these pre-Internet days. "The
Unstable EMS" appeared in Brookings Papers on Economic Activity in
1993. This was the beginning of the financial crisis industry or at
least of my involvement in it. Charles and I coauthored a series of
papers together with my Berkeley colleague Andrew Rose in which we
developed measures of currency crises and sought to identify their
economic and political correlates. (26) This sideline as financial
ambulance chaser and historian of financial crises would come in handy
in 2008.
A final episode in the development of my research agenda was when I
was asked to work as senior policy advisor at the International Monetary
Fund. It is my observation that organizations like the Fund (I would
also include the World Bank, the regional development banks, and
national central banks) quite like having economic historians around.
Economic historians are more likely than other economists to actually
know something about institutions. (27) They are likely to know which
policies are new and novel and which ones have precedents. They are in
the business of synthesizing large amounts of material. They tend to be
able to convey their thoughts in plain English.
Again the timing was fortuitous from a selfish standpoint. I
started at the IMF on July 2nd, 1998, the same day that Thailand
devalued and the Asian crisis erupted, and left a year and a few weeks
later on the day that Russia defaulted. (28) I had been hired by the
Fund's deputy managing director, Stanley Fischer, but worked for
the head of the research department, Michael Mussa. Stan and Mike could
both lay claim to being the best international macroeconomist of their
generation, except for the fact that they were both of the same
generation. It is hard to imagine two better exemplars of how to do high
quality policy research.
If the IMF is a rolling deck, then the senior policy advisor is its
loose cannon. Members of the hierarchy have an incentive to go along in
order to get along, not to mention in order to be promoted. But the
senior policy advisor has tenure at his university, where he can return
after a year. This allows him to say what he thinks. As a reviewer he is
expected to criticize and raise objections to policy memos and in-house
research products. Not a bad job if you can get it. (29)
In my case the review function was overtaken by events. No sooner
did the Asian crisis erupt than the prime minister of Malaysia, Mahathir
bin Mohamed, accused hedge funds of fomenting the crisis and demanded
that the IMF to investigate. The IMF asked me to investigate, which
meant giving me a corporate credit card and a team of Ph.D. economists.
(30) We visited the regulators. We visited George Soros in New York. We
visited Long-Term Capital Management in Greenwich. (31) We visited Bear
Stearns, which booked the majority of the trades for the hedge fund
industry. The experience was eye opening for someone who had studied
financial markets exclusively through the lens of theoretical models and
historical documents.
The exercise was also not unproblematic. It would have been naive
to sit down with the manager of a hedge fund and say "We're
from the IMF, and we'd like to know whether you and your friends
colluded in causing the Asian crisis." These people knew who had
sent us and were cagey with their answers. At the same time, seeing that
many of the fund managers in Manhattan had offices in the World
Financial Center and could be found at 5PM on Friday drinking together
in the atrium bar did convey a certain amount of information. It
impressed one with the importance of collective psychology. It
couldn't help but incline one to the view that there existed such a
thing as herd behavior in financial markets.
Our report concluded that while a number of important hedge funds
had taken positions against Asian currencies, they were far from alone.
We learned, for example, that the same investment bank that was advising
an Asian government on how to fend off speculation was itself the main
speculator taking a position against it. More generally investment banks
took many of the same positions as hedge funds, and they were at least
as highly leveraged. The Malaysian constituency was not pleased by the
conclusions, which appeared to let the hedge funds off the hook. Others
criticized us for lumping hedge funds and investment banks together.
After the crises of Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers in 2008, it is hard
not to feel vindicated.
In February 1998, six months into the Asian crisis, then U.S.
Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin made a speech at the Brookings
Institution calling for a new international financial architecture.
Michel Camdessus, the ambitious French technocrat who headed the IMF,
wasn't sure what this new financial architecture might entail but
he was certain that the Fund should be in charge of it. I was
commissioned to write a series of papers on the subject. (32) These soon
came to be known as "the non-papers," since papers in the Fund
have to undergo interdepartmental review before they can be widely
circulated and no radical ideas about a new international financial
architecture could have ever survive this vetting. The non-papers called
for the IMF to take the lead in promulgating standards for securities
market regulation, corporate governance and auditing and accounting
practice, and for it then to actively monitor compliance. They called
for a greater focus on supervision and regulation of banking systems,
banking-sector weaknesses having been at the center of the Asian crisis.
They called for the Fund to push its members harder to adopt more
flexible exchange rates so that there would be a stronger incentive for
banks and corporations to hedge their currency exposures.
Whether these non-papers had any impact on the policy debate is for
the reader of this essay to judge. (33) The author, for his part, was
characteristically unable to write four extended memos without also
seeing the outlines of a book. Toward a New International Financial
Architecture was published by Fred Bergsten's Institute for
International Economics late in 1999, just three months after I returned
to academia. Books like this having a relatively short shelf-life, time
was of the essence. I learned that when an author is prepared to give up
his royalties, a publisher can move very fast. (34)
As will be clear to those who have gotten to this point, at some
level I feel most comfortable in the historian's world where one
tells a story, leavens it with anecdotes, and leaves the reader to draw
out the broader implications. But the economist in me yearns for general
conclusions about how research agendas are formed.
The most general conclusion is of course that there are no general
conclusions. There are no universally applicable guidelines for finding
a topic, settling on an approach, and moving from one topic to another
so that a research question turns into a research program and eventually
a body of work. The ideas that engage the researcher's imagination
will be shaped by the circumstances in which he lives. The 1970s were
when the Bretton Woods System of fixed exchange rates gave way to
generalized floating; it is not surprising that these events provoked
historical research on the performance of alternative exchange rate
regimes. That the 1990s were a decade of financial instability sparked
new research on the history of financial crises. The global credit
crisis and recession of 2008-9 will undoubtedly trigger new research on
the Great Depression. The scholar seeking to speak to a broad audience
is always on the lookout for events that will resonate with readers. The
economic historian is always on the lookout for precedents. These
tendencies are healthy if they are kept in check and do not lead the
researcher to leap from topic to topic, a problem with which I am not
entirely unfamiliar.
It helps of course to have a core question, as in my case the role
of the gold standard in the Great Depression, substantial enough to
sustain one's research for a period of years. If that question is
sufficiently rich and suggestive, links to other important questions
will suggest themselves. In my case those links ran backward to the
classical gold standard of the pre-1914 period, which evidently
functioned more smoothly and endured longer than its short-lived
interwar successor; the questions thrown up by this contrast are
obvious. The links also ran forward from the 1931 financial crisis that
shattered the gold standard system to the 1992 crisis that shattered the
EMS. They ran from there to the incidence of financial crises, both
historically and contemporaneously, and to the possibility that the
further progress of European integration, extending to the creation of
an economic and monetary union, might repair the fissures in the EMS.
This is how my own research agenda grew, unpredictably but not entirely
without logic.
If one is lucky this process will be pushed along by impetus from
outside not just in the form of current events but also in the form of
commissions and requests for conference papers. These may come from
someone with more detachment and therefore insight into how the
researcher's past and future work may link to other issues and who,
not incidentally, attaches lower value to the researcher's time.
The trick of course is deciding which commissions to accept--those which
require extending one's scholarly range in limited but significant
ways--and which ones to reject--those which would force the researcher
to move far out of his comfort zone and turn into a time sink. (35)
The other problem with commissions, conference papers and coauthors
is that they are too interesting. They make it more difficult to pursue
to conclusion the task of answering the big question that is at the
heart of one's research program. Big questions require sustained
attention--for an economic historian they require book-length treatment.
And a serious book requires effort over a period of years. My own most
intellectually productive periods have been when I attempted to write a
big book--in 1985-92 on the gold standard and the Great Depression, in
2000-2007 on the European economy since 1945--while at the same time
pursuing other topics, some old and some new.
The challenge is keeping these different balls in the air, all at
the same time. It is devoting much of one's research time and
effort to a single topic for a sustained period while also working on
other subjects. It may be one month on the book followed by one month on
other projects. More likely, it will less regular alternation.
Either way, I like to think that I turned out the best appetizers
and side dishes when I also had the main course in the oven.
Barry Eichengreen, George C. Pardee and Helen N. Pardee Professor
of Economics and Political Science, University of California, Berkeley.
Notes
(1.) Factory-like environment notwithstanding, sometimes I think
that I would have been better off with an actual college education.
(2.) The observant reader will have noted that luncheon and dinner
party conversation play an ongoing role in this essay.
(3.) One thinks only of Charles Kindleberger and his student Carlos
Diaz-Alejandro.
(4.) This had its disadvantages: where graduate students elsewhere
were already being taught about rational expectations, Yalies remained
largely ignorant of this development, still fighting as we were a
rear-guard action against monetarism.
(5.) I myself didn't have any of these eminences as teaching
assistants in Bill's course; instead I had Rick Levin, an excellent
section leader who eventually chose to forsake economic history for the
presidency of Yale.
(6.) The comparison would have annoyed him: whenever he heard
Gerschenkron's name, Bill would remind the listener that he himself
had been a student of Gerschenkron's predecessor, Abbot Peyton
Usher.
(7.) Carlos had organized his Essays on the Economic History, of
the Argentine Republic, published in 1970, around the country's
terms of trade.
(8.) I remember Paul writing equations on the chalkboard of the
seminar room in the Cowles Foundation--a model of balance-of-payments
crises, a model of imperfect competition and trade--and claiming that he
had come up with these ideas over the preceding weekend.
(9.) Gold and the Dollar Crisis (1960), The Evolution of the
International Monetary System: Historical Reappraisal and Future
Perspectives (1964), The World Money Maze (1966),
(10.) Though the broad area, the economics and history of the Great
Depression, was hardly uninteresting--and it has hardly lost salience in
light of subsequent events.
(11.) It also was not accepted for the dissertation session of the
Economic History Association, a fact which I happily recount to students
when their own dissertations are passed over.
(12.) This resulted in my first book, Sterling in Decline: The
Devaluations of 1931, 1949 and 1967, published in 1983.
(13.) This was Jeff Sachs, a member of the Society of Fellows, late
not for the first time.
(14.) The others were Jeff Sachs, Andy Abel and Mark Watson, all of
who went on to distinguished careers and from whom I learned certain
basics of research to which I had not been exposed in New Haven.
(15.) I was also blessed with an appointment as a Faculty Research
Fellow of the National Bureau of Economic Research's international
finance program. I had to lobby Marry Feldstein, who wasn't
entirely sure whether an economic historian qualified for membership in
an international finance program (or whether I had the qualifications to
function as an NBER research fellow at all). Appointment as a fellow
admitted one to the Bureau's summer camp in international finance,
attended by the field's leading figures, which helped me to develop
contacts and credentials as an international economist and learn more
methods.
(16.) Chicago offering more resources for his labor-intensive
research.
(17.) I strongly suspect that he still has his tape recordings of
the lunches we had at the Harvard Faculty Club to discuss his work.
(18.) When he started working on the connections between the gold
standard and the Great Depression, I knew I had made a sensible choice.
(19.) Embarrassingly so. On presenting the paper at the 1984
Cliometrics Conference I was given the "Peter Temin award for
drawing the strongest conclusions on the basis of the least data."
(20.) This problem of political economy, with its answer rooted in
history and politics, was important in and of itself. But in addition
its answer could be used to solve the identification problem.
Technically, the problem that the decision to abandon the gold standard
might affect the course of a country's depression, but that the
depth of its depreciation might also affect its decision of whether to
abandon the gold standard.
(21.) It was clear in which direction a Yalie would gravitate.
(22.) In Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great
Depression, 1919-1939 (Oxford 1992), I at least succeeded in omitting
the technical apparatus if not always in making the material accessible,
or so my wife, who has tried to finish the book several times, likes to
remind me.
(23.) But that, of course, is where subsequent research agendas
come from.
(24.) I ended up instead writing for Economic Policy an article on
the 50 U.S. states as a monetary union, which became part of a rapidly
growing literature comparing asymmetric shocks, adjustment through
capital and labor mobility and fiscal self-insurance in the United
States and the European Union.
(25.) Along, perhaps, with the 1987 stock market crash when the Dow
declined by 500 points, a very large amount given the levels of the era,
in a single day. That was the same day that I gave my undergraduate
lecture on the Great Crash in 1929 for the first time. When I gave the
lecture again in 1988, the Dow declined by 250 points.
(26.) I claim credit for having first employed the now-standard
indicator of exchange market pressure as a measure of crisis incidence
and for the labels now conventionally attached to "first- and
second-generation" models of financial crises.
(27.) In a policy environment pure theory only takes one only so
far.
(28.) I leave it to the reader to infer cause and effect.
(29.) And a positive reflection on an institution, the IME that
does not always enjoy the best image.
(30.) Both were firsts for someone whose experience had been
limited to academia.
(31.) Some nine months before its failure. Had we seen that train
wreck coming we would have been golden. My report to the Board contained
a sentence, reflecting our interviews with regulators, stating that
"regulators are confident that hedge funds are prudently managing
their risks." This statement was entirely accurate so long as one
recalls the first four words, which was not always the case of my
subsequent interlocutors.
(32.) Who better, one might ask, than an economic historian to
ruminate on the past and future of the international financial
architecture?
(33.) Camdessus found their conclusions exciting. This agenda
implied an expanded role for the IMF, and along with more
responsibilities would come a bigger budget and more staff. He proposed
convening an "informal lunch" in his private dining room. The
informal lunch turned out to involve three dozen department heads,
microphones and a stenographer. The overwhelming reaction was that my
ideas were unrealistic. The IMF had always focused on monetary and
fiscal policies. To imagine that it could now also focus on the plumbing
of financial markets was to misunderstand its role. The Fund had always
favored stable exchange rates; to it make it an active proponent of
greater flexibility was beyond the pale.
(34.) Even then, not everyone disseminates research like Fred
Bergsten. My Berkeley colleague Janet Yellen, who was then chair of Bill
Clinton's Council of Economic Advisors, told me about walking into
the Oval Office in late 1999 and finding the president with his yellow
highlighter and a mysterious black and yellow book. Seeing that the book
was called Toward a New International Financial Architecture, she
whispered to Robert Rubin, "We'd better get a copy of that and
find out what he's reading."
(35.) The trick of course is recognizing which requests are which,
something I have never entirely mastered.