The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies.
McClough, David
The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies
by Bryan Caplan. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 2007. 276
pages. ISBN 0-691-12942-8 $29.95
In The Myth of the Rational Voter, Bryan Caplan challenges economic
models explaining voter behavior. His interdisciplinary analysis
features empirical evidence reflecting deviation in economic beliefs
between the general population and economists. The deviation in beliefs
supports suspicions that the general public embodies biases that
adversely affect policy formation in democracies. Although the book is
accessible to all analysts familiar with economics and political
science, the intended audience seems to be academic economists slow to
incorporate compelling empirical results challenging the rationality
assumption.
The miracle of aggregation is a popular retort to concerns
regarding voter ignorance and apathy, behaviors economists argue to be
rational given the costs in excess of benefits associated with political
intelligence and low probability of determining an election. Caplan
observes that the miracle of aggregation is feasible only if voters are
systematically wrong thereby canceling each other out in a two candidate
election and leaving informed voters to determine election outcomes. It
is assumed that the median voter is fight and thus, the miracle is that
good policy emerges despite apathy and ignorance. Unfortunately, biases
resulting in unsystematic error may fail to cancel the effects of the
misinformed general public and overwhelm informed voters resulting in
bad policy based on incorrect beliefs. The empirical question is: does
the general public hold biased economic beliefs?
Caplan identifies four commonly suspected biases of the general
public that deviate from the economic beliefs of economists. The
antimarket bias tends to underestimate the benefits of the marketplace.
This bias seems to emerge from a distrust of profit-seeking and ignores
that profits exist and persist only for firms that deliver value to
customers. The antiforeign bias reflects underestimation of the benefits
of interaction with foreigners. This bias is motivated by belief that
foreigners exploit us despite our voluntarily engagement with them. The
more different foreigners look, act, or speak, the more nefarious their
intentions must be. The make-work bias values employment over
productivity. The value of workers is necessarily a function of the
worker's output. Strangely, consumers value labor saving appliances
but fear labor savings, if jobs appear lost. The pessimistic bias
reflects a tendency overstate economic challenges and understate future
prospects. Caplan argues that these biases crush the hope implied by the
miracle of aggregation and explain the persistence of bad economic
policies in democracies.
In addition to compelling intuition and integration of an
interdisciplinary literature, the contribution of this book is the
empirical evidence supporting the accusation of bias. Caplan uses the
Survey of Americans and Economists on the Economy (SAEE) produced by the
Washington Post, Kaiser Family Foundation and Harvard University Survey
Project to compare the economic beliefs of economists and
non-economists. The analysis is enhanced by controlling for self-serving
and ideological beliefs of economists. Caplan refers to this adjusted
belief as the Enlightened Public, in contrast to Economists and the
General Public. Review of survey results reveals that the General Public
deviates from Economists and the Enlightened Public on nearly all
questions. A technical appendix explains estimation of the Enlightened
Public beliefs.
Empowered by the underlying behavioral assumption of rationality,
Public Choice economics represents application of the prevailing
neoclassical (rational choice) model to politics and voting behavior.
The implication of Public Choice is that political ignorance is rational
because the cost to reverse ignorance exceeds the benefit associated
with political intelligence. Caplan finds Public Choice unsatisfying and
argues instead that political actors are rationally irrational.
The notion of rational irrationality is inspired by recognition
that economic policy is a public good. When a consumer makes a bad
purchase, it is the consumer who bares the full cost. In contrast, when
voters vote for bad economic policy, each voter can expect to incur only
a tiny fraction of the total cost to society. Accordingly, the utility
associated with an irrational vote may easily exceed the expected cost
to any individual voter, especially when one considers the low
probability of one's vote determining the outcome. Irrational
voting represents a low-cost, low risk opportunity for self-expression
thereby contributing to an individual's sense of identity, which is
an emotional experience rather than rational process.
Having established "the microfoundations of individual voter
irrationality" (p. 143), Caplan explores how irrationality
influences policy. He uses simple thought experiments to demonstrate how
in the presence of irrationality democracy can consistently produce bad
policy. The discussion incorporates a compelling challenge to the
self-interested voter hypothesis that mistakenly extends the behavioral
assumption of self-interest from consumer to voter. Relying upon
empirical results presented in the political science literature
suggesting that voters, in fact, focus on national rather than
individual well-being,
Caplan asserts that the self-interested voter hypothesis is wrong.
An implication of this conclusion is the unlimited potential for bad
policy in the absence of self-interest. Caplan asserts that economists
are experts and it is expert opinion that is right. Accordingly,
thinking like economists results in superior economic policy. The
defense of this position is compelling; nevertheless, readers may
disagree arguing that economists have been mistaken in the past (e.g.
mercantilism, physiocracy, advising Hoover to balance the federal budget
by increasing taxes, allowing banks to fail during the 1930s, etc.) so
there is no reason to think that economists are not wrong now. A valid
challenge to be sure. Caplan addresses this challenge convincingly for
this reviewer by reminding the reader that economists are the very ones
who identify the mistakes within the profession and strive to identify
solutions. As such, economics is a field that has progressed
considerably and contributed positively overall to the human experience.
More simply, if economists are not the experts, who are?
If expertise leads to superior economic policy, it is helpful to
know what variables predict thinking as an economist. Caplan includes an
interesting discussion examining the variables predicting convergence of
the general public with economic beliefs of economists. The data reveal
that higher education, income growth, greater job security, and male
gender predict greater agreement with the beliefs of economists.
Moreover, he notes that voters are less biased than non-voters. Given
that education is the best predictor of voter turnout, he concludes that
it is the well-educated that are most likely to make society better off.
This is a challenging conclusion in a book that asks why democracies
generate bad policy unless the author is advocating less democracy to
ensure greater influence by the economic literate. On the contrary, the
author is advocating more education to increase economic literacy. His
clarion call is for economists to present in the classroom what they
know to be correct.
The Myth of the Rational Voter is fun. It offers a refreshing look
at tired topics that have been embedded in the fabric of our
understanding of voting behavior and politics. This book makes an
important contribution to the economics literature by effectively
integrating empirical results from psychology and political science. The
intuition and reasoning are refreshing and engaging. The empirical
analysis is creative and compelling. This book arms psychologists and
political scientists with the arguments to provoke economists.
Constructive provocation often leads to remarkable achievements.
David McClough
Bowling Green State University