Linking labor productivity to economic freedom.
Nissan, Edward ; Niroomand, Farhang
I. INTRODUCTION
In the preface to New Economic Growth." New Factors and New
Perspectives, the editors, Bahmani-Oskooee and Galindo Martin (2006),
say that in recent decades economists have provided newer views of a
better economic future where economic growth takes center stage. When
economic growth is high, more jobs and greater income are available for
distribution, paving the way for prosperity. They observe that the
importance of growth is not new in economic discourse. Adam Smith
(1776), Ricardo (1817) and Malthus (1820) had in mind economic growth to
achieve economic progress, though they differed in the suggested tools.
Added to these are newer theoretical versions which suggest science and
technology as instruments for growth (endogenous technical progress).
These ideas are lumped under the economic theoretical name classical,
which was followed by the neoclassical exogenous economic growth,
Post-Keynesian and endogenous growth models.
This paper provides (1) a review of literature dealing with the
theories described above concerning economic growth and development, (2)
an aim and methodology section which includes statistical tools for
analysis, (3) a section providing results, followed by a concluding
remarks section (4).
II. REVIEW OF LITERATURE
In a comprehensive look at classical economics, Reid (1989) sought
to contrast two important growth themes presented by Adam Smith. The
first was classical sectoral analysis and the second was classical
aggregate growth. The sectoral takes a detailed look at the evolution of
individual industries and, even perhaps, individual firms, which may
give an account of the cumulative growth process. The aggregate growth
model provides explicitly the growth path subject to technical change
due to division of labor. The effect of division of labor transcends
from firms to industries to countries, which is the basis of endogenous
technological change.
Endogenous technological change, according to Salvatore (2007),
arose from the new endogenous growth theory introduced by Romer (1986)
and Lucas (1988). The theory postulates that lowering trade barriers
makes it possible for economic growth to be speeded up in the long run.
Mechanisms for expediting growth include the transfer of technology from
developed to developing countries and the promotion of larger economies
of scale in production. The new endogenous growth theory can explain how
endogenous technological change can create externalities that can offset
diminishing returns to capital as envisioned by the neoclassical growth
theory. The neoclassical growth theory postulates that when more units
of an input are used with fixed amounts of other inputs, the returns
diminish.
Endogenous technological change, in turn, depends on the extent of
markets which generally, but not always, leads to increasing returns by
offsetting diminishing returns as explained earlier, an effect that is
the basis of cumulative growth in an economy. The division of labor
permits the emergence of scientific, technical and commercial
specialization.
The consequence, in post-industrial society, is the emergence of
specialist skills in such fields as communication, information handling
and coordination, which facilitate the role of the entrepreneur. The
entrepreneur discovers new ways of doing things and new things to do
cheaply. A market is therefore formed and evolved with a consequence of
market success or failure. Market failure necessitates the evolution of
laws and institutions that govern market conduct where government plays
an important role. In parallel to market failure is the government
failure. Achieving improvements in both market and government is dealt
with by comparative institutional analysis.
Chaudhuri (1989) defines economic growth as the increase in output
of goods and services, total or per capita, measured in terms of value
added on a continuous basis. An increase in total output is called
"extensive," while an increase in per capita is
"intensive," where the concern is the standard of living or
the welfare of the population. Therefore, in measuring the growth of
output, it is necessary to measure the qualitative phenomenon. The
qualitative aspect of welfare is concerned with creating a better
educated and healthier population. Chaudhuri suggests three reasons for
the study of growth. The first is the understanding of historical
processes which can explain why economic growth is confined to a small
proportion of world population. The second reason concerns the
increasing total availability of goods and services. Increasing the
capacity to reach higher levels of material welfare, especially under
conditions of population growth, increases consumption and makes some
exhaustible resources scarce, creating a distribution problem. The third
reason to study growth is for the formation of economic policy in the
short and long runs. Monetary and fiscal policies could impact
consumption and investment. Recognizing that economic surplus is a
consequence of economic growth, the surplus, which is the difference
between the value of output and cost production, can be used in
alternative ways-increase in consumption or increase in investment.
Rich (1994) notes that emerging and underdeveloped countries must
rely on international macroeconomics for aid and trade. What
differentiates the two is that an emerging economy seeks a diversified
export-market to obtain foreign currencies on its merits as a producer.
Underdeveloped countries are characterized by stagnation and remain
dependent on aid. Rich adds that post-industrial economies are beset with international competition manifested by industrialization with its
consequences on employment. When industries become highly technical, it
forces more competition at home and abroad, resulting in lower revenues
and profits. When revenues and profits decline, the labor force in the
affected industries also declines, with a ripple effect to auxiliary
industries. The spread of unemployment in one post-industrial country
generates negative effects on employment in all post-industrial
societies, with a consequence of declining consumption and further
unemployment. By Merritt's (1982) assessment, squabbling over
markets for sales that make a difference between acceptable and mass
unemployment that may threaten political instability could lead to wars.
Hunt (1989) summarizes the classical view of growth to constitute
expansion of market, saving and investment out of profits, and the
determination of the capitalist to increase personal wealth. In
contrast, Schumpeter (1976) breaks with the growth theories by drawing a
distinction between economic growth and development. Economic growth
refers to expansion of production by producing more of the same output
with the same methods. Economic development is a disruptive process,
where innovation is pervasive in methods of production, products and
markets as well as industrial organization. In looking at the
mobilization of credit by an entrepreneur as opposed to savings, the
Schumpeter model is distinct from the classical economists. The
importance of entrepreneurship in his model has great relevance in the
Third World.
When dealing with economic growth, a leading contributor to the
theory is Robert Solow. In the January 2006 ASSA/American Economic
Association meetings in Boston, a special 50th anniversary session was
devoted to celebrate Solow's (1956, 1957) works, considered to be
the heart of modern growth theory. Solow (2007), recognizing the 50th
anniversary celebration of his exogenous theory, explains that there
were two major innovations during the past 50 years. The first was the
endogenous growth theory pioneered by Romer (1986) and Lucas (1988) and
the second is the drawing of inferences about the determinants of
economic growth from international cross sections where Barro (1991) is
the first protagonist.
The important agents for growth, as viewed by the authors discussed
above, are the roles of capital (physical, and human), and the
entrepreneur in a capitalist frame of reference. Recently, Baumol, Litan
and Schramm (2007), henceforth (BLS), delved into the four prevalent
forms of capitalism and their implications to economic growth. On one
side, there is entrepreneurial capitalism where radical ideas of
entrepreneurs meet the test of the market place. There are also the
types where radical entrepreneurship is absent but championed by the
government through big business as in Japan and many European countries;
state-guided capitalism as a way to start growth in less developed
countries; and, finally, corrupt leaders of government who tend to keep
the spoil for themselves. A common feature to all four forms is the
allowance of private property. The four types may be described simply as
(i) entrepreneurial, (ii) big firm, (iii) state directed and (iv)
oligarchic. BLS concludes first that incentives matter. Countries that
reward activities that promote growth grow faster than other countries.
Second, the contribution to growth by the entrepreneur must be
substantial by way of big firms to mass produce and refine radical
innovations. Countries that achieve a relatively high standard of living
can maintain it only by getting rid of state guidance and adopting a
blend of entrepreneurial and big-firm capitalism.
BLS lays out four conditions for big-firm capitalism to maximize
growth. The first condition is ease of starting and growing business.
This condition includes cost of business registration, bankruptcy
protection and access to finances. The second condition is the rewards
for productive entrepreneurial activity. This condition includes the
role of law, property and contract rights; avoidance of onerous
taxation; proper regulation (deregulation); rewarding new ideas;
government-supported research and development (R&D); commercializing
university invention; and rewarding imitation. The third condition
relates to disincentives for unproductive activity and the fourth
condition relates to keeping winners in the entrepreneurial game from
rent seeking by promoting competition.
Friedman (2005) concurs with the opinion that countries with
improved standards of living over long period of time will continue to
seek open and tolerant societies and, at the same time, strive to
broaden and strengthen their democratic institutions. However, when the
majority of a country's citizens perceive that their income is
stagnant and that they are not getting ahead, democracy weakens and
society becomes rigid. In this case, public policy plays a vital role
since actions by business are not geared toward benefiting society. The
aim of business is to make profit. Left to itself, it will deliver too
little economic growth. Government alone provides safety from external
attacks and provides internal rule of law, as well as adequate
infrastructure for transportation, all of which help the pursuit of
economic initiatives. Government engages in sundry activities such as
defense, highways, space exploration, crime prevention, border patrol,
disease control, disaster relief, education assistance, food stamps,
medical care for the indigent, and, of course, Social Security and
Medicare.
According to Friedman, with a low rate of savings and a large
deficit with the added promises to working citizens, it is almost
impossible to maintain adequate capital formation. Without adequate
investment, it could prove difficult to maintain trends of increased
productivity and to improve the American standard of living in the
foreseeable future. How, then, can the position of government be
restored without draining the scarce savings? Friedman proffers four
approaches (page 414): (1) economize on government spending apart from
programs for the retired elderly, (2) raise taxes, (3) restructure
Social Security and Medicare, and (4) increase what America saves so
that the country can finance both adequate capital formation and a
chronic government deficit. In Freidman's opinion, several of these
routes are unpromising.
Friedman believes that in the twenty-first century, the problem in
the United States is not unemployment but the slow advance in the living
standards for the majority of citizens. This sense of stagnation does
not arise from national income statistics, but from an awareness of the
average citizen's experience. A rising standard of living has been
the general norm in the United States in the past, but the country is
not able to achieve that today. There is the need, therefore, to restore
confidence in moving forward, which will require hard public policy
choices. Friedman ends (page 1) in saying that, "Only with
sustained economic growth, and the sense of confident progress that
follows from the advance of living standards for most of its citizens,
can even a great nation find the energy, the wherewithal, and most
importantly the human attitudes that together sustain an open, tolerant,
and democratic society."
III. AIM AND METHODOLOGY
In the opinion of BLS, the United States stands out as the country
most in tune to meet growth conditions. Because the conditions and their
associated subconditions constitute a large array of indicator
variables, a way to capture them is through an index. Dobeli and Kolasa
(2007) constructed such indexes to compare growth performance of new EU
countries. A useful index is provided by the Heritage Foundation (2004)
called the Economic Freedom Index. The index score for a country is
composed of 10 variables, each of which is made up of a number of
subvariables. For simplification, the variables are denoted as
[X.sub.1], [X.sub.2], ..., [X.sub.10] as follows:
[X.sub.1]: Trade Policy-tariff and non-tariff barriers, corruption
[X.sub.2]: Fiscal Burden-income and corporate taxes, government
expenditures
[X.sub.3]: Government Intervention-government consumption and
ownership
[X.sub.4]: Monetary Policy-average and current inflation
[X.sub.5]: Capital Flow and Foreign Investment-foreign investment
code, restriction on foreign ownership and investment, legal equality
between foreign and domestic companies
[X.sub.6]: Banking and Finance-government ownership and regulation,
restriction on foreign banks
[X.sub.7]: Wage and Price Controls-minimum wage laws, government
price controls, government subsidies that affect prices
[X.sub.8]: Property Rights-commercial code defining contracts,
government expropriation of property, protection of private property,
judicial delays, judicial corruption
[X.sub.9]: Regulation-licensing requirements; ease of obtaining
licenses; environmental, consumer, and worker regulation; bureaucratic corruption
[X.sub.10]: Black Market--smuggling, size of black market activity
In lieu of simply averaging the ten components to rank countries,
Nissan and Carter (2006) provide an index scheme based on the concept of
distance. To treat variables equally in the construction of the index,
raw data are transformed into standard scores by letting for country i,
[z.sub.ij] = ([x.sub.ij] - [[bar.x].sub.j] +
3[s.sub.j])/6[s.sub.j], (1)
where [[bar.x].sub.j] and [s.sub.j] are the means and the standard
deviation of the observation of the factor j = 1, ..., 10. The
[z.sub.ij] transforms an observation of country i for variable j into
standardized units. The index is constructed as the k = 10 dimensional
distance d([z.sub.ij], [z.sub.oj]) for observation [z.sub.ij] from a
reference point [z.sub.oj] given by
d([z.sub.ij], [z.sub.oj]) [[[summation][([z.sub.ij] -
[z.sub.oj]).sup.2]].sup.1/2], i = 1, ..., n (2)
where n = number of countries in the sample.
The index, d of equation (2), is the familiar Euclidean distance
between two points ([z.sub.ij], [z.sub.oj]) in the 10-dimensional space.
The reference points [z.sub.oj] are the transformations by equation (1)
of the best value in the distribution. Note that the smaller the index
score of a country, the closer the country is to the reference point and
the higher is the rank of the country. Also note that the point of
reference [z.sub.oj] is the best score rather than the mean.
This paper uses the computed index of Nissan and Carter (2006),
which is available upon request, in a slightly different way. The
computed index value for each country i is divided by the index value of
the United States. The United States, therefore, will have a value d =
1, in line with BLS's proposition that the United States represents
the optimum of desired big-firm capitalism.
A second index to be used in this paper is provided by Hummels and
Klenow (2005), henceforth (HK). HK produced a large set of data for some
126 countries. The variables to be used in this research are:
Y = Country GDP relative to the rest of the world.
L = Country employment relative to the rest of the world.
Y/L = Country GDP per worker relative to the rest-of-the-world GDP
per worker.
Again, in order to systemize the data, a country score is divided
by the score of the United States, resulting for the United States
scores of 1.00 for each of the three variables. This way, the scores for
the economic freedom index "d" and the scores of the HK
indexes on "Y," "L" and "Y/L" become
comparable. In particular among the three HK variables, "Y/L"
will receive special attention because it is an assessment of
productivity.
The methodology employed is testing for equality of means between
groups of countries as well as regression analysis. For purposes of
comparisons, the countries will be grouped in two ways. The first
grouping is by region as follows:
1. East Asia and Pacific
2. Europe and Central Asia
3. Latin America and the Caribbean
4. Middle East and North Africa
5. South Asia
6. Sub-Saharan Africa
7. High Income OECD
8. Other High Income
The second grouping is by income as follows:
1. Low Income
2. Middle Income
3. Upper-Middle Income
4. High Income
These classifications are in accordance with the World Bank (2005).
IV. RESULTS
Table 1 provides the transformed data where the scores of the
countries were altered by making the scores of the United States serve
as reference points for the variable Y (Country GDP), L (Country
employment) and Y/L ( Country GDP per worker). Note that Y/L in essence
could be referred to as productivity as provided by Hummels and Klenow
(2005), and the economic freedom index "d" provided by Nissan
and Carter (2005). Note that columns 1 and 2 in Table 1 denoted by C1
and C2 refer to classification of countries by region and income.
In Table 1, the scores for the United States are 1.00 for each of
the four variables. The United States belongs to high income OECD (7 in
C1) and high income (4 in C2). The United Kingdom was similarly situated in C 1 and C2 at 7 and 4, respectively. The GDP (Y) and employment (L)
relative to the United States are 0.1243 and 0.2071, giving Y/L
(productivity) of 0.5992. For economic freedom, the United Kingdom score
is 0.9722, implying that the United Kingdom is closer to the reference
points of the distance measure d described by equation (2). The only
country that surpasses the United States for productivity is Luxembourg
at 1.1820. China, on the other hand, has a GDP (Y) = 0.3936 and
employment (L) = 7.4226, giving productivity Y/L = 0.0530 as compared to
the United States with an economic freedom score of d = 1.9872.
Remembering that the larger d implies farther distance from the best
score in economic freedom, it seems that China is way out of step
implementing desired conditions for economic freedom. Twelve countries
out of 116 for the d index had scores lower than the United States, with
the implication that these countries had better economic freedom
practices. Hong Kong leads with a score d = 0.4541, followed by Ireland
at d = 0.6643 and Singapore at d = 0.8201.
Table 2 provides descriptive statistics for country GDP per worker
(Y/L) relative to United States, giving the mean, the standard
deviation, the Coefficient of Variation CV and the minimum and maximum
of the groups of countries classified by region (Panel A) and by income
(Panel B). Not surprisingly, High Income OECD and Other High Income
groups score well at averages 0.6550 and 0.5518; Latin America and the
Caribbean follow at 0.2178. South Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa score last
at 0.0818 and 0.0787, respectively. By income category, high-income
countries are in the lead at 0.6350 followed by the middle-income group
of countries at 0.2893. Of interest are the values of the Coefficient of
Variation CV suggested as a measure of convergence (Friedman 1992,
Drennan and Lobo 1999), which is relatively small for all the groups in
Table 2, with the exception of Sub-Saharan Africa at CV = 1.2084. For
all the countries, CV = 0.9237. The indication here is that the groups
of countries grouped by region or income (as well as all countries)
converge to their respective means for the factor Y/L.
Table 3 provides similar information as Table 2, this time for the
economic freedom index d. The closest score to that of the United States
is for Other High Income at 1.0600 and High Income OECD at 1.0962. The
Coefficient of Variation for all the groups of countries as well as all
countries is relatively small, again giving an impression of
convergence.
The question is whether the averages by group of countries for Y/L
in Table 2 and d in Table 3 differ significantly. The test is done by
the method of analysis of variance and the results, shown in Table 4,
indicate that a hypothesis of equality of means must be rejected at
P-value = 0.000 in every case. Utilizing multiple comparisons procedures
by way of confidence intervals, the means for High Income OECD and Other
High Income groups of countries are way out as compared to the other
groups, indicating substantial gaps, especially for productivity (Y/L)
by income with F = 274.63. Again, this result is expected because the
productivity level is what differentiates the poor countries from the
rich countries.
Finally, by use of regression methodology, a relationship between
productivity (Y/L) and economic freedom (d) is in order, with the
assumption that the two variables are random variables with the
expectation
E[Y/L|d] = [[mu].sub.1] + [rho]([[sigma].sub.1]/[[sigma].sub.2])(d
- [[mu].sub.2]) (3)
where Y/L and d have the respective means and standard deviation
([[mu].sub.1], [[sigma].sub.1]) and ([[mu].sub.2], [[sigma].sub.2]) and
[absolute of value of [rho] < 1 is the correlation coefficient. For
simplicity, equation (3) is written as
E[Y/L|d] = [[mu].sub.1], + [beta](d - [[mu].sub.2]) (4)
estimated by least squares as
[([??]/L).sub.i] = [m.sub.1] + b([d.sub.i] - [m.sub.2]) (5)
which, after further simplifications, takes the form
[([??]/L).sub.i] = [b.sub.0] + [b.sub.1][d.sub.i]. (6)
It is expected that b1 in equation (6) will take on a negative
sign, which is the case upon regressing the values (Y/L) on (d) in Table
1. The result, using all the 116 countries for which comparable data
were available is
([??]/L) = 0.990 - 0.475d, (7)
where [b.sub.1] = -0.475 is statistically significant at P-value =
0.000 and correlation coefficient r = -0.714 with p-value = 0.000.
Remembering that Y/L and d operate inversely, the negative sign of
d indicates that productivity and, by implication, growth are tied to
the openness and freedom of the economies, giving credence to BLS's
contentions that capitalism is the way to follow to generate economic
growth.
V. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The focus of this paper is economic growth as it relates to
capitalist form of economies. The review of literature suggests that
economic freedom, as represented by the variables in the Economic
Freedom Index, is the main engine for economic growth. Through the use
of indexes reflecting productivity and economic freedom, the paper has
shown that such a relationship is strong even though the gaps between
groups of countries assembled by region and income for both variables
remain significant.
BLS, recognizing that failure of governments and international
agencies to help the two billion individuals who still live on less than
$2 per day, has some suggestions and broad approaches to transform their
economies. Particular attention is paid to economies that are run by
government ministries or powerful oligarchies. BLS contends that
regardless of level of development, less developed countries can benefit
by promoting entrepreneurship of replicative (borrowed from abroad) and
innovative types of technology. The second suggestion by BLS for the
least developed countries is to introduce the principles of
entrepreneurial capitalism "at the margin" or
"incremental" policies.
For oligarchic economies where the gaps between the rich and the
poor are large, the two options available for change mentioned by BLS
are revolution from within or outside pressure from other countries.
Foreign aid should be targeted for health systems, sanitation, roads and
the like when it can be delivered in a constructive way. Finally,
micro-credit financial institutions should be introduced where
replicative small businesses can thrive.
Theories and data examined in this paper highlight the importance
of economic policies that promote capitalism and competitive markets and
encourage and support entrepreneurship and discourage greed and market
failure through regulatory, tax and financial incentives and
disincentives. Rajan and Marwah (1988), noting the broad consensus for
countries to pursue market-oriented policies and economic liberalization to gain economic growth, observe that lack of credibility and durability
of policy reforms in some countries could hinder foreign investors from
entering their markets. In addition, Habib and Zurawicki (2002) point to
corruption in host countries as a deterrent to attracting foreign direct
investment, especially because of the intensification of contacts
between less corrupt and more corrupt countries.
Kaushik (1996) presents India as a success story for a country that
overcame lack of credibility and durability in policy reforms as well as
corruption. India followed a hierarchy of liberalization for building
confidence, which Kaushik depicts as a pyramid. At the base is
credibility, consisting of policies that include deregulation,
privatization, the creation of physical infrastructure, and an open
trading and monetary system. The next stage in the pyramid is credit
from external sources where foreign banks and international financial
markets in the mid 1980s found India attractive for business because of
its credibility and credit worthiness. This ushered in the third stage
in the pyramid, capital inflows in the form of portfolio and direct
investment. The fourth stage is the building of confidence, where India
practices open trade, competition, open financial flow and linkage of
capital markets. In other words, a market economy. Furthermore, Kaushik
addresses the other lingering corruption problem that India strives to
prevent by making politicians and the political processes accountable
for their actions.
REFERENCES
Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Galindo Martin, M.A. (2006)
"Preface," in New Economic Growth: New Factors and New
Perspectives, Eds.: M.
Bahmani-Oskooee and M.A. Galindo Martin, New York: Nova Science
Publishers, Inc.
Barro, R.J. (1991) "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of
Countries," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106: 407-43.
Baumol, W.S., Litan, R.E., and Schramm, C.J. (2007) Good
Capitalism, Bad Capitalism, and the Economics of Growth and Prosperity,
New Haven and London: Yale University Press.
Chaudhuri, P. (1989) Economic Theory of Growth, Ames, Iowa: Iowa
State University Press.
Dobeli, B. and Kolasa, M. (2007) "Comparing the Growth
Performance of the New EU Countries," Eastern European Economics,
45: 55-68.
Drennan, M.P. and Lobo, J. (1999) "A Simple Test for
Convergence of Metropolitan Income in the United States," Journal
of Urban Economics, 46: 350-59.
Friedman, B.M. (2005) The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth,
New York: Alfred A. Knopf.
Friedman, M. (1992) "Do Old Fallacies Ever Die?" Journal
of Economic Literature, 30: 2129-32.
Habib, M. and Zurawicki, L. (2002) "Corruption and Foreign
Direct Investment," Journal of International Business Studies,
33:291-307.
Heritage Foundation Index (2004), "Index of Economic Freedom
2004," www.heritage.org/about/advancedsearch.cfm.
Hummels, D. and Klenow, EJ. (2005) "The Variety and Quality of
Nations Exports," The American Economic Review, 95: 704-723.
Hunt, D. (1989) Economic Theories of Development: An Analysis of
Competing Paradigms, New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Kaushik, S. (1996) "India's Democratic Economic
Transformation," Challenge, 39, 54-61.
Lucas, R.E., Jr. (1988) "On the Mechanics of Economic
Development," Journal of Monetary Economics, 22: 3-42.
Malthus, T. R. (1820) Principles of Political Economy, New York: W.
Picketing (1986).
Merritt, G. (1982) World out of Work, London: William Collins Sons
& Co. Ltd.
Nissan E. and Carter, G. (2006) "Economic Freedom and Economic
Growth across Countries," In Next Economic Growth: New Factors and
New Perspectives, Eds.: M. Bahmani-Oskooee and M.A. G. Martin, New York:
Nova Science Publishers, Inc.: 11-25.
Rajan R.S. and Marwah, S. (1998) "The Effects of Policy
Uncertainty on the Choice and Timing of Foreign Direct Investment: An
Exploratory Firm-Level Assessment," Journal of Economic
Development, 23: 37-56.
Reid, C. (1989) Classical Economic Growth: An Analysis in the
Tradition of Adam Smith, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Ricardo, D. (1817) Principles of Political Economy and Taxation,
New York: Prometheus Books (1996).
Rich, D.Z. (1994) The Economic Theory of Growth and Development,
Westport, Connecticut: Prager.
Romer, P. (1986) "Increasing Returns and Long Run
Growth," Journal of Political Economy, 94: 1002-1037.
Salvatore, D. (2007) International Economics, Hoboken, NJ: John
Wiley & Sons, Inc.
Schumpeter, J.A. (1976) History of Economic Analysis, New York:
Oxford University Press.
Smith, A. (1776) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of Wealth of
Nations, Oxford: Clarendon Press (1976.)
Solow, R.M. (2007) "The Last 50 Years in Growth Theory and the
Next 10," Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 23: 3-14.
Solow, R.M. (1956) "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic
Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70: 65-94.
Solow, R.M. (1957) "Technical Change and the Aggregate
Production Function," Review of Economics and Statistics, 39:
312-20.
World Bank (2005) World Development Report 2005, New York: Oxford
University Press.
Farhang Niroomand, The University of Southern Mississippi 118
College Drive # 5072 Hattiesburg, MS 39406 USA
Corresponding author: farhang.niroomand@usm.edu
TABLE 1.
Country GDP, Employment, and Productivity Relative to World
(U S. Reference)
Number Country C1 C2 Y L
1 ALBANIA 2 2 0.0010 0.0101
2 ANGOLA 6 1 0.0014 0.0370
3 ARGENTINA 3 3 0.0377 0.1027
4 AUSTRALIA 7 4 0.0426 0.0640
5 AUSTRIA 7 4 0.0178 0.0269
6 BANGLADESH 5 1 0.0184 0.2071
7 BARBADOS 3 3 0.0004 0.0017
8 BELGIUM 7 4 0.0223 0.0303
9 BELIZE 3 3 0.0001 0.0000
10 BENIN 6 1 0.0006 0.0185
11 BOLIVIA 3 2 0.0020 0.0202
12 BOTSWANA 6 3 0.0009 0.0034
13 BRAZIL 3 2 0.1164 0.4226
14 BULGARIA 2 2 0.0059 0.0286
15 BURKINA FASO 6 1 0.0009 0.0337
16 CAMEROON 6 1 0.0026 0.0455
17 CANADA 7 4 0.0718 0.1061
18 CAPE VERDE IS. 6 2 0.0001 0.0017
19 CENTRAL AFR.R. 6 1 0.0004 0.0118
20 CHAD 6 1 0.0006 0.0168
21 CHILE 3 2 0.0127 0.0387
22 CHINA 1 2 0.3936 7.4226
23 COLOMBIA 3 2 0.0222 0.1246
24 COMOROS 6 1 0.0001 0.0017
25 CONGO 6 1 0.0005 0.0084
26 COSTA RICA 3 3 0.0019 0.0084
27 CYPRUS 8 4 0.0012 0.0017
28 DENMARK 7 4 0.0130 0.0202
29 DOMINICA 3 3 0.0000 0.0000
30 DOMINICAN REP. 3 2 0.0030 0.0168
31 ECUADOR 3 2 0.0046 0.0253
32 EGYPT 4 2 0.0221 0.1212
33 EL SALVADOR 3 2 0.0025 0.0118
34 ETHIOPIA 6 1 0.0031 0.1751
35 FIJI 1 2 0.0004 0.0017
36 FINLAND 7 4 0.0100 0.0185
37 FRANCE 7 4 0.1293 0.1902
38 GABON 6 3 0.0010 0.0034
39 GAMBIA 6 1 0.0001 0.0034
40 GERMANY 7 4 0.1890 0.2912
41 GHANA 6 1 0.0023 0.0589
42 GREECE 7 4 0.0137 0.0303
43 GRENADA 3 3 0.0000 0.0000
44 GUATEMALA 3 2 0.0039 0.0202
45 GUINEA 6 1 0.0018 0.0219
46 GUINEA-BISS 6 1 0.0001 0.0034
47 GUYANA 6 2 0.0002 0.0017
48 HAITI 3 1 0.0011 0.0219
49 HONDURAS 3 2 0.0012 0.0118
50 HONG KONG 8 4 0.0166 0.0219
51 HUNGARY 2 3 0.0093 0.0286
52 ICELAND 7 4 0.0006 0.0017
53 INDIA 5 1 0.2032 3.0337
54 INDONESIA 1 2 0.0754 0.5572
55 IRAN 4 2 0.0311 0.1246
56 IRELAND 7 4 0.0065 0.0101
57 ISRAEL 8 4 0.0094 0.0152
58 ITALY 7 4 0.1258 0.1650
59 IVORY COAST 6 1 0.0027 0.0370
60 JAMAICA 3 2 0.0010 0.0084
61 JAPAN 7 4 0.3341 0.5825
62 JORDAN 4 2 0.0016 0.0067
63 KENYA 6 1 0.0036 0.0943
64 LESOTHO 6 1 0.0003 0.0067
65 LUXEMBOURG 7 4 0.0015 0.0017
66 MACEDONIA 2 2 0.0009 0.0067
67 MADAGASCAR 6 1 0.0011 0.0404
68 MALAWI 6 1 0.0007 0.0303
69 MALAYSIA 1 3 0.0188 0.0522
70 MALI 6 1 0.0008 0.0337
71 MALTA 8 4 0.0005 0.0017
72 MAURITANIA 6 1 0.0003 0.0084
73 MAURITIUS 6 3 0.0013 0.0034
74 MEXICO 3 3 0.0695 0.2239
75 MOROCCO 4 2 0.0095 0.0589
76 MOZAMBIQUE 6 1 0.0013 0.0556
77 MYANMAR 1 1 0.0004 0.0219
78 NAMIBIA 6 2 0.0007 0.0034
79 NEPAL 5 1 0.0028 0.0623
80 NETHERLANDS 7 4 0.0341 0.0505
81 NEW ZEALAND 7 4 0.0067 0.0118
82 NICARAGUA 3 1 0.0001 0.0101
83 NIGER 6 1 0.0008 0.0320
84 NIGERIA 6 1 0.0108 0.3855
85 NORWAY 7 4 0.0109 0.0152
86 PAKISTAN 5 1 0.0245 0.2458
87 PANAMA 3 3 0.0015 0.0067
88 PAPUA NEW GUINEA 1 1 0.0016 0.0152
89 PARAGUAY 3 2 0.0027 0.0152
90 PERU 3 2 0.0109 0.0724
91 PHILIPPINES 1 2 0.0224 0.2020
92 POLAND 2 3 0.0296 0.1229
93 PORTUGAL 7 4 0.0135 0.0320
94 ROMANIA 2 2 0.0113 0.0808
95 RUSSIA 2 2 0.1147 0.5320
96 RWANDA 6 1 0.0005 0.0219
97 SENEGAL 6 1 0.0013 0.0286
98 SEYCHELLES 6 3 0.0001 0.0000
99 SIERRA LEONE 6 1 0.0004 0.0118
100 SINGAPORE 7 4 0.0084 0.0152
101 SLOVAK REPUBLIC 2 3 0.0053 0.0185
102 SLOVENIA 8 4 0.0026 0.0067
103 SOUTH AFRICA 6 2 0.0298 0.0943
104 SOUTH KOREA 7 4 0.0651 0.1347
105 SPAIN 7 4 0.0682 0.1111
106 SRI LANKA 5 2 0.0058 0.0539
107 ST. VINCENT & GRE 3 3 0.0001 0.0000
108 SWEDEN 7 4 0.0192 0.0320
109 SWITZERLAND 7 4 0.0182 0.0269
110 SYRIA 4 2 0.0058 0.0253
I11 TAIWAN 8 4 0.0331 0.0657
112 TANZANIA 6 1 0.0014 0.0993
113 THAILAND 1 2 0.0425 0.2256
114 TOGO 6 1 0.0004 0.0118
115 TRINIDAD & TOBAGO 3 3 0.0012 0.0034
116 TUNISIA 4 2 0.0052 0.0202
117 TURKEY 2 2 0.0398 0.1919
118 UNITED KINGDOM 7 4 0.1243 0.2071
119 UNITED STATES 7 4 1.0000 1.0000
120 UGANDA 6 1 0.0016 0.0657
121 URUGUAY 3 3 0.0030 0.0101
122 VENEZUELA 3 3 0.0163 0.0539
123 YEMEN 4 1 0.0014 0.0269
124 ZAIRE 6 1 0.0015 0.1532
125 ZAMBIA 6 1 0.0008 0.0219
126 ZIMBABWE 6 1 0.0030 0.0370
Number Y/L d
1 0.0983 1.5033
2 0.0387 *
3 0.3669 1.7048
4 0.6748 0.9630
5 0.6670 1.1671
6 0.0893 2.0213
7 0.4145 1.3697
8 0.7438 1.3001
9 0.2782 1.2558
10 0.0325 1.8716
11 0.0979 1.3015
12 0.2585 1.2437
13 0.2748 1.4508
14 0.2062 1.4372
15 0.0266 1.7102
16 0.0555 1.9601
17 0.6738 0.9480
18 0.1221 1.4331
19 0.0339 1.8140
20 0.0380 1.8568
21 0.3251 0.8373
22 0.0530 1.9872
23 0.1780 1.5883
24 0.0551 *
25 0.0529 2.1846
26 0.2035 1.1936
27 0.5118 0.8263
28 0.6565 1.0506
29 0.2331 *
30 0.1749 1.8109
31 0.1879 1.7495
32 0.1821 1.7640
33 0.1978 1.0298
34 0.0178 1.7403
35 0.2277 1.5886
36 0.5649 0.9910
37 0.6793 1.5436
38 0.2682 1.9118
39 0.0341 1.8968
40 0.6499 1.0881
41 0.0389 1.6895
42 0.4534 1.4113
43 0.1605 *
44 0.1947 1.5877
45 0.0806 1.7809
46 0.0249 2.0695
47 0.1058 1.6040
48 0.0515 1.9805
49 0.0982 1.7901
50 0.7562 0.4541
51 0.3160 1.1887
52 0.5531 0.9324
53 0.0670 1.8308
54 0.1354 1.9610
55 0.2491 2.3360
56 0.6622 0.6643
57 0.6355 1.3209
58 0.7660 1.1650
59 0.0721 1.6931
60 0.1136 1.4084
61 0.5732 1.3720
62 0.2400 1.3923
63 0.0377 1.6493
64 0.0426 1.7710
65 1.1820 0.9942
66 0.1548 1.4752
67 0.0279 1.5843
68 0.0233 1.7543
69 0.3670 1.6714
70 0.0249 1.7604
71 0.5062 1.3440
72 0.0388 1.4408
73 0.3700 1.5557
74 0.3112 1.4480
75 0.1593 1.4925
76 0.0243 1.6527
77 0.0197 *
78 0.2176 1.4768
79 0.0438 1.8628
80 0.6652 1.2305
81 0.5463 0.9695
82 0.0863 1.4592
83 0.0252 1.8421
84 0.0281 2.0124
85 0.7127 1.3314
86 0.1000 1.7773
87 0.2242 1.4454
88 0.1113 *
89 0.1807 1.6747
90 0.1508 1.4252
91 0.1111 1.5440
92 0.2420 1.3687
93 0.4287 1.1487
94 0.1404 1.8038
95 0.2154 1.6731
96 0.0222 1.8647
97 0.0450 1.6391
98 0.3159 *
99 0.0362 2.0761
100 0.5794 0.8201
101 0.2976 1.0942
102 0.4000 1.2518
103 0.3159 1.3404
104 0.4853 *
105 0.6126 1.1594
106 0.1087 1.4637
107 0.2181 *
108 0.5897 1.1329
109 0.6562 0.9531
110 0.2360 2.1271
I11 0.5011 1.1647
112 0.0145 1.7177
113 0.1882 1.4038
114 0.0321 2.0268
115 0.3478 1.2098
116 0.2479 1.5057
117 0.2082 1.7009
118 0.5992 0.9722
119 1.0000 1.0000
120 0.0245 1.3316
121 0.2905 1.1718
122 0.3018 2.2219
123 0.0525 1.9129
124 0.0096 *
125 0.0359 1.7688
126 0.0805 2.4409
Notes: C1 Classification of Economies by Region:
1-East Asia and Pacific, 2-Europe and Central Asia, 3-Latin
America and Caribbean, 4-Middle East and North Africa,
5-South Asia,6-Sub-Saharan Africa, 7-High Income
OECD, 8-Other High Income
C2 Classification of Economies by Income: 1-Low Income,
2-Middle Income, 3-Upper-Middle Income, 4-High Income
Y = Country GDP relative to the rest of the world (U.S. Reference).
L = Country employment relative to the rest of the world
(U.S. Reference)
Y/L = Country GDP per worker relative to rest-of-world GDP per worker
(U.S. Reference).
d = Economic Freedom Index (U.S. Reference).
Sources: Hummels and Klenow (2005) and Nissan and Carter (2006).
TABLE 2.
Descriptive Statistics
Country GDP per Worker Relative to World (Y/L)
(U.S. Reference)
Panel A: Region n Mean Std CV Min
East Asia & Pacific 8 0.1517 0.1096 0.7225 0.0197
Europe & Central Asia 9 0.2088 0.0710 0.3400 0.0983
Latin America & Caribbean 26 0.2178 0.0931 0.4275 0.0515
Middle East & N. Africa 7 0.1953 0.0721 0.3692 0.0525
South Asia 5 0.0818 0.0263 0.3215 0.0438
Sub-Saharan Africa 40 0.0787 0.0951 1.2084 0.0096
High Income OECD 25 0.6550 0.1574 0.2403 0.4287
Other High Income 6 0.5518 0.1250 0.2265 0.4000
All Countries 126 0.2648 0.2446 0.9237 0.0096
Panel B: Income n Mean Std CV Min
Low 41 0.0438 0.0243 0.5548 0.0096
Middle 34 0.1793 0.0643 0.3586 0.0530
Upper Middle 20 0.2893 0.0649 0.2243 0.1605
High 31 0.6350 0.1554 0.2447 0.4000
All Countries 126 0.2648 0.2446 0.9237 0.0096
Panel A: Region Max
East Asia & Pacific 0.3670
Europe & Central Asia 0.3160
Latin America & Caribbean 0.4145
Middle East & N. Africa 0.2491
South Asia 0.1087
Sub-Saharan Africa 0.3700
High Income OECD 1.1820
Other High Income 0.7562
All Countries 0.4541
Panel B: Income Max
Low 0.1113
Middle 0.3251
Upper Middle 0.4145
High 1.1820
All Countries 0.4541
Source: Hummels and Klenow (2005).
TABLE 3.
Descriptive Statistics
Economic Freedom Index (d)
(U.S. Reference)
Panel A: Region n Mean Std CV MW
East Asia & Pacific 6 1.6927 0.2348 0.1387 1.4038
Europe & Central Asia 9 1.4717 0.2342 0.1591 1.0942
Latin America & Caribbean 23 1.4833 0.3135 0.2113 0.8373
Middle East & N. Africa 7 1.7900 0.3550 0.1983 1.3920
South Asia 5 1.7912 0.2044 0.1141 1.4637
Sub-Saharan Africa 36 1.7546 0.2486 0.1417 1.2437
High Income OECD 24 1.0962 0.2003 0.1827 0.6643
Other High Income 6 1.0600 0.3520 0.3321 0.4541
All Countries 116 1.5072 0.3748 0.2487 0.4541
Panel B: Income n Mean Std CV Min
Low 36 1.9483 0.2119 0.1088 1.3316
Middle 34 1.7531 0.2833 0.1616 0.8373
Upper Middle 16 1.6425 0.3079 0.1875 1.0942
High 30 1.2638 0.2309 0.1827 0.4541
All Countries 116 1.5072 0.3748 0.2487 0.4541
Panel A: Region Max
East Asia & Pacific 1.9872
Europe & Central Asia 1.8038
Latin America & Caribbean 2.2219
Middle East & N. Africa 2.3360
South Asia 2.0213
Sub-Saharan Africa 2.4409
High Income OECD 1.5436
Other High Income 1.3440
All Countries 2.4409
Panel B: Income Max
Low 2.4409
Middle 2.3360
Upper Middle 2.2219
High 1.5436
All Countries 2.4409
Source: Hummels and Klenow (2005) and Nissan and Carter (2006).
TABLE 4.
F-Tests for Equality of Means
F P-value
Y/L by Region 73.11 0.000
Y/L by Income 274.63 0.000
d by Region 17.79 0.000
d by Income 45.56 0.000
Note: Y/L = Country GDP per worker relative to world
(U.S. reference), d = economic freedom index.
Source: Hummels and Klenow (2005) and Nissan and
Carter (2006).