Succeeding in economics.
Demsetz, Harold
The editors of American Economist invited me to discuss
professional aspects of my life as an economist as part of an ongoing
series of similar discussions by others. They thought readers might find
this of interest and might even benefit from learning how contributors
to this series go about their work. My intent here is simply to
highlight some aspects of my career that have helped me progress in the
profession. What has helped me may not be equally helpful to others,
each of us being unique in experience, capability, and interest. Indeed,
some conditions that have helped me along have not been of my own
making. Each of us, for example, is born at a particular time in a
particular place and to a particular set of parents. Although we can
influence the views of our parents as we mature, we are powerless to
affect time and place of birth. Yet, these do influence what we will do
and how well we will do it.
The first full year of the Great Depression, 1930, is the date of
my birth and the city of Chicago is the place. The decade of the 1930s,
of course, began a long period of hard times for a great many families,
including mine. Although hard times make success more difficult in ways
that are well known, the 1930 birth date made success in academia
easier. One advantage of this date is that I became a member of an age
cohort group that was made smaller by the Depression. When I entered the
academic marketplace in 1958 I faced fewer competitors than would have
been the case if prior years been more prosperous. Another advantage was
that the GI bill, which offset what would have been the impact of prior
Depression years, was still channeling very large numbers of WWII and
Korean War veterans into college as I sought my first professional
teaching position. These consequences of my birth date put me in the
academic marketplace when the entering supply of new PhDs was relatively
small and the demand for their services was relatively large. Adjusting
for quality of training, most graduating PhDs enjoyed an abundance of
job offers that lasted for the better part of a decade.
Being born in a large city was also advantageous. The neighborhood
of my youth was largely populated by immigrant families from Europe who,
though not very knowledgeable about post high school educational
institutions, were self-selected for their willingness and ability to
deal with circumstances new to them. College presented such
circumstances. The first year of my college education took place at an
essentially free nearby public city college, one, as it turned out,
attended by ample numbers of bright students and serviced by capable
teachers who probably would have secured better positions if prior years
had been better. The second year of my education was at the Chicago
undergraduate division of the University of Illinois, where tuition at
the time was about $100 per semester. The cost of going to college in a
large city at that time was also kept low by being able to live at home
with the family on Chicago's West Side.
A large city also offers opportunities to pay for an education
through part time work; during summers I drove a Checker cab and during
the school year I ushered evenings at the Chicago Civic Opera House. I
studied engineering during these two years and, therefore, learned some
mathematics. As part of the distribution requirements for the
engineering degree, I took a course in economics. This was taught well
by an instructor who was then working on his PhD at the University of
Chicago.
I found economics interesting and enjoyable. The Opera House job
helped round out my education in the arts as I pursued work in the
engineering program. Financing an education this way has its downsides.
Commuting took the better part of three hours a day and so did part time
work. Being raised as a user of urban transport, I did not fully
appreciate the weight of this burden until I continued my education at
the Champaign-Urbana campus of the University of Illinois. After a brief
tour with the U.S. Army, which made me eligible for G.I. bill aid, I
went on to secure an MBA and PhD from Northwestern University.
I did not consciously engage in the long-run planning of my
teaching-research career when I entered the profession, as I did not
begin my career with any expectation or intent of making a
"mark" in the profession; indeed, I saw college teaching as a
comfortable job to which a three month vacation was attached. As things
turned out, I became increasingly interested in economics as I read more
of it and taught my classes. I began writing on topics I found
especially interesting, and perhaps because of being raised on
Chicago's West Side I experienced little apprehension about going
public with my work. As things have turned out, I have never, I say
never, taken even a month away from work. Economics turned out to be too
interesting and idea production too stimulating. Not everyone can find a
remunerative work that keeps a person busy and satisfied at the same
time, but I did. It is difficult, I think, to make a confident judgment
about this without first really working the tasks that a career sets
before a person.
Although I have written on many topics, my writings are mainly
contained within three categories of subject matter: (1) markets and
firms; (2) property rights and externalities; and (3) financial markets
and transaction costs. This degree of concentration has worked well for
me. It offers a comfortable compromise between interesting targets of
opportunity and continuity of knowledge accumulation.
Sources of potential topics to work on are many. Examples of where
some of my ideas have come from may be given. One of my earliest
publications arose from my studies at Northwestern University while
working toward my PhD. I had been reading Edward Chamberlin's
Theory of Monopolistic Competition (1933), a book that had become a
mainstay of industrial organization theory during the 1950s. An aspect
of the way Chamberlin developed his notion of excess capacity
equilibrium puzzled me, and I kept mental note of this. The cost curve
he used to describe his excess capacity theorem assumed
implicitly--without his taking note of it--that promotional expenditures
are held constant while a firm varies its output rate; otherwise how
could the demand curve facing the firm remain in the fixed position
given to it by Chamberlin? In contrast to this, all costs are allowed to
vary optimally when discussing the cost curve of the perfectly
competitive firm. Yet, despite the difference in the implicit
definitions of these two cost curves, Chamberlin's notion of excess
capacity was based on the supposed deduction that the equilibrium rate
of output of the monopolistically competitive firm is less than that
which would bring unit cost to its minimum if the market were perfectly
competitive; true, but this minimum cost is associated with a very
special cost curve, one which holds promotional cost constant. The
incompatibility between the two cost curves made me wonder about the
equilibrium of a monopolistically competitive firm if full consideration
is given to the variation in optimal promotional expenditures that
surely would take place as output rate varies. At a later time, but
before I had completed my PhD work, I returned to this question. The
result was publication of "The Nature of Equilibrium in
Monopolistic Competition" (J. Pol. Econ. Feb. 1959).
The teaching experience is a second source. An essay titled
"Purchasing Monopoly," in my Efficiency, Competition, and
Public Policy (Oxford: Basil Blackwell Ltd. 1989), comes from a mental
note I made while teaching graduate students at UCLA. The textbook
treatment of the reward to monopoly is calculated as the difference
between revenue received by a monopolist and cost incurred by the
monopolist. In this calculation, cost is treated as expenditures made to
produce the monopolist's profit maximizing rate of output, and the
cost conditions that determine these expenditures are those that would
define the supply curve of the competitive industry that would exist if
their were no monopoly. This would be correct if monopolizing a market
required no special expenditures, as if the monopoly were a gift of
nature or of a costless conversion of a competitive industry. While
discussing the case, I realized that a "free" monopoly would
not ordinarily be the case. Rivals will need to be defeated or
purchased, and would be entrants would need to be bought off.
Monopolizing would at least require the payment of Ricardian rents to
firms in the competitive industry that is being transformed into a
monopoly. These monopolizing costs are not incurred by firms in a
competitive market. I returned later to examine the issues raised by
this realization. The essay that came from this shows, or course, that
the return to monopolizing is much less than the return to the receiver
of a free gift of monopoly, so the customary measure of monopoly profit exaggerates the true return to the monopolist who, in one way or
another, must buy the right to exclude rivals. More than this, the essay
also shows that the use of deadweight loss triangles to measure the
social loss of monopoly yields a biased estimate.
A third idea source is conversation with colleagues. At a lunch
shared with colleagues at the University of Chicago, discussion turned
to a report about antitrust that had just been written by a committee
headed by Phil Neal, then Dean of the University of Chicago Law School.
One part of the report endorsed the market concentration doctrine. This
well-known doctrine had guided thought about the relationship between
market structure and pricing power when I was a young man, and to some
extent it still does. An observation was made by one of my colleagues at
this lunch. This was that domestic auto industry profits were
comparatively high only because GM's profit was high. Neither Ford
nor Chrysler, for example, earned exceptionally high profits. I began
investigating whether this observation had generalizing power when I
arrived at UCLA in 1971. In the absence of governmentally imposed
barriers to entry, market concentration may be expected to arise if
scale economies are important or if innovation has resulted in a
superior product or way of producing an existing product. Competitive
responses to these sources yield not just variation in market structure
across industries but also variation in measured industry profit rates.
Examined in more detail, market concentration as an outcome of efficient
structure is consistent with a correlation between profit rate and
market concentration if the correlation is calculated only for the
larger and historically more successful firms in the markets being
compared, but the efficient structure hypothesis would not lead to an
expectation of this correlation for middle sized and smaller firms. The
higher profits received by the larger, historically more successful
firms is to be attributed to their lower costs or their superior
products given that product price is determined by cost at the margin in
an industry. In contrast to this explanation, a pure collusion explanation would lead one to expect a positive correlation between
profit and market concentration for all size classes of firms; evidence
for this is nowhere found in the data (see, Demsetz, H. "Industry
Structure, Market Rivalry, and Public Policy," J. of Law &
Econ. April 1973 and Demsetz, H. "Two Systems of Belief about
Monopoly" in Goldschmid, Mann, and Weston (Industrial
Concentration: The New Learning; Little, Brown, 1974).
This example is especially useful in revealing a characteristic of
some of my work. I tend to push an argument or a model back to an
earlier analytical step than is presently covered by it; rather than
take market concentration as a given when evaluating data, I first
sought to explain variation in market concentration. This tendency is
also illustrated by my article "Toward a Theory of Property
Rights" (AER. May 1967). While I was at Chicago, R. H. Coase, who
arrived a year after I did, amazed the profession by demonstrating, in
the context of the externality problem, that who does (and who does not)
possess a fight to impose a cost on others is irrelevant to efficient
resource allocation. (This result obtains if transaction cost is zero
and if income effects on demands for goods involved in the interaction
are unaffected by wealth redistribution.) Coase's work took the
private property fight system as an "existing" given when
making his point. I began to think about moving the problem to a prior
step by seeking to understand the emergence of a private fight system
from a preexisting communal right system. This resulted in a simple
efficiency explanation for the rise of private rights (and, under
specifiable conditions, also for the persistence of communal rights). I
explained how changing conditions brought about by the development of
the fur trade in the new world affected ownership of land arrangements
among Native Americans on the American Northeast and failed to do in the
American Southwest.
One more tendency of mine might be noted. The interesting problems
seem me to be those that begin with observation of an unexpected
practice, organization, or business policy. In attempting to make sense
of these, I usually begin by seeking an explanation that reconciles the
anomaly with efficient allocation of resources. In the Native American
land ownership example discussed above, the problem was to explain why
Native American's of the Northeast came to treat land differently
from Native American's of the Southwest. I found my answer in the
different habits of forest animals and animals of the great plains. Each
land ownership arrangement seemed efficient in the context of the animal
habits facing Native Americans in the two locations.
The work I choose to do is not heavily armored with math and
econometrics. It is focused on empirical and policy problems and on the
logic of the theory that bears on these. Cold logic, imagination, and
exposition by way of words, simple geometry, and basic statistics are
the tools on which I have mainly relied throughout most of my career. I
do not feel fully in command of a problem or of a resolution of it until
I can state both clearly in words and/or geometry. This gives my work a
wider audience but probably also limits the nature of the problems on
which I choose to work. Not many young economists adopt this working
methodology today, and I am not sure it is suitable for an initial job
search in today's market. Today, prospective employers seem to
strongly emphasize demonstrable ability in econometrics and mathematics.
I suspect that the large degree of specialization across fields of
economics explains this, since it is now more difficult to have the
knowledge of material in the many fields in which the renderer of
judgment is not a specialist. Technical tooling offers a substitute, but
heavy attention to these tools often hampers discovering the economist.
Quality of economic thinking is more likely to be revealed by the way
the underlying problem to which the tools are applied is conceived and
analyzed. Economists in training seem to seek a body of data that is
appropriate for the exploitation of technical tools rather than one
which offers intrinsic economic interest. Not frequently, but still on
occasion, a seminar is given by a young economist who has uncovered such
a problem and is now busily engaged in a thorough investigation of it;
this person has a good chance of becoming a successful economist.
I do regularly attend workshops in my field, and I recommend this
as a method for keeping in touch with the profession, for learning from
other attendees, and for exposing others to ideas that may come to your
mind. A second method is to become a member of dissertation committees
and eventually to become a chair of some of these. This is an effective
way to learn one's own strengths and weaknesses as well as those of
students. It is the most efficient way to learn about the intellectual
history of the topic featured in the dissertation. Beyond this, graduate
students whose dissertations you chair become well acquainted with your
work, ideas, and methods and they carry these to other institutions.
One reason I came to UCLA from Chicago is to have the opportunity
to interact with students in their dissertation writing stage. My
position at Chicago was in the Graduate School of Business, a fine
school with fine students and colleagues, but most of these students
sought only the MBA degree. Those who went for the PhD wrote
dissertations in accounting, marketing, management, and finance; few
wrote in economics. Chicago, after all, had a world class Department of
Economics to service students seeking to become economists. My position
at UCLA, in contrast, was in the Economics Department, where I managed
to supervise the dissertations of almost 80 students. Times are
different now, I suppose; a few more students in business schools seek a
PhD in something called business or managerial economics.
A position in a top business school has an important advantage.
This is to encourage work on puzzles involving business and market
arrangements and on public policies toward business. Economists in
economics departments have a stronger tendency to look within economics
itself for the problems they study. The issue is not which of these
problem sets is better, but which mixture of them works best for you. My
personal development has benefitted much from practicing my discipline
not only in a fine business school and fine economics department but
also from teaching in fine law schools. The topics on which I have
written reflect this three-fold institutional involvement. I began work
in two economics departments, continued in Chicago's business and
law schools, and then returned to economics. Along the way, I did my
share of consulting on antitrust cases and institution building. Engaged
thus, it is not easy to become bored. It goes without saying that one
must publish to succeed in economics within academic institutions.
Quality teaching performance and involvement in academic institutional
problems count, but these provide no answer to the question "Is he
or she a fine economist?" Quality of writings supplies this
information.
One may write for different audiences. An economist who is good in
writing for one audience may not be equally good for another. I recall
George Stigler asking me more than once if I thought Milton Friedman will be most remembered for his scientific work (say, on the consumption
function and monetary theory) or for his reformist policy work (as in
his Capitalism and Freedom)? The answer George sought was
"Milton's scientific work," but the answer, I think,
depends on the audience being asked the question. The Nobel Prize Committee, representing the economics profession, stressed
Friedman's professional work, and it may well be that future
economists will do so also. But I think a broader "committee"
of influential intellectuals might well value his reformist work more.
To succeed professionally in your own terms, know your audience. Not
many of us are as capable as Friedman was in serving two such different
groups so well.
It is extremely important to become associated with the best
economists available to you. This usually means appointment at the best
universities possible. People think about puzzle resolution in different
ways. Only by reading what others write and by engaging in discussion
with them can you begin to discover different ways of looking at a
problem. You also learn to disagree with your colleagues and to bear
their disagreement with you--all in proper spirit. It does not do you or
them much good if you to keep your thoughts to yourself. For a month or
two I sat quietly, saying nothing, in Chicago's Industrial
Organization Workshop. One day, George Stigler, the creator and director
of the workshop, leaned over to me and whispered "You owe it to
others to make your thoughts known." Except for those few months, I
always do. Association with the best also broadens the invitations you
will receive to make your thoughts available at other institutions.
I have been able to interact with some very fine economists while
learning my trade. Perhaps this reflected an ample share of luck.
Perhaps it reflected my ability and willingness to engage. However it
came about, this has proved extremely important to my professional
progress. Surely other "things" also matter, but I strongly
advise young economists to increase the weight they give to associating
with the best possible economists when seeking a position.
My work habits are not atypical. I do not often work into the
evening hours, preferring instead to do my professional work during
daytime in my office at the university. I come to my office almost every
weekday, and I hardly ever take off more than a week or two during the
calendar year. This remains my pattern even though I am now several
years past official retirement. I see myself as a "long distance
runner" when it comes to work; I read and writing regularly during
daytime hours through most of the year. Once a work project is completed
I quickly search for another if I do not already have one in inventory.
Weekends are spent at home with my family, sometimes tending to repair
work but always enjoying their company. On several evenings of each week
my wife and I take three-mile hill walks. On the occasion of these walks
we sometimes discuss the new work I am doing. Rita is quite good at
understanding what I am saying and often senses problems that I have not
dealt with. Having a great partner in life makes it much easier to
succeed professionally. I have no personal experience with and can only
imagine the considerable difficulties that face colleagues whose minds
are occupied with problems at home or who do not look forward to closing
the office door after a good day's work and returning home.
Harold Demsetz, Professor Emeritus, UCLA