The academic review process: how can we make it more efficient?
Azar, Ofer H.
I. Introduction
Recent studies suggest that in the last few decades the publication
delay has become much longer than it used to be. Both the submit-accept
time and the first-response time (from submission to first editorial
decision, henceforth FRT, or FRTs in plural) more than doubled in many
economics journals over the last twenty to forty years (Ellison, 2002a;
Azar, 2004b). Moreover, similar trends seem to exist in many other
disciplines as well (Ellison, 2002b).
Many scholars criticize the long FRT, arguing that it is
unreasonable that authors have to wait several months to receive the
first decision about their manuscript (see for example Szenberg, 1994).
This is especially annoying since the reason for the long FRT is not
that referees and editors need months to think about the paper, but that
the paper waits months just to be read. (1)
Whether as a result of this criticism or as a means to attract
authors, many journals try to reduce their FRT and promise the
prospective author an efficient review process. At first, it seems that
reducing the FRT is welfare increasing, as it allows disseminating research more quickly. This is particularly important because new
research builds on previous results, so every delay causes the entire
research chain to be delayed. Moreover, the FRT is especially important,
because it delays the average article three to six times (it delays the
article in every journal to which it was submitted, including the
journals that rejected it), whereas other parts of the publication delay
usually occur only once in the life cycle of an article (Azar, 2004a).
One way to avoid the repeated delay caused by the FRT is to allow
papers to be submitted to several journals simultaneously. This is
common in law journals, for example. This idea was discussed in the
literature before; the arguments for and against eliminating the
exclusivity of journal submissions are summarized well in the intriguing debate between Szenberg (1994) and Pressman (1994). The main reason
against simultaneous submissions, which is probably also the reason why
they are still banned, is that allowing them will increase significantly
the number of submissions and therefore also the workload of referees
and editors.
While reducing the FRT seems at first desirable, it has potential
costs. Some argue that it might reduce the quality of the review
process. If the reduction in the FRT is achieved by reducing the time
the article spends on the referee's desk waiting to be read,
however, the quality of the review process will not be hurt. Azar
(2005), however, suggests that even if the quality of the review process
is not reduced, a shorter FRT raises other problems. He argues that
reducing the FRT significantly will encourage many more submissions of
mediocre papers to top journals, increasing the workload of editors and
referees. Moreover, Azar claims that the increase in the number of
submissions will increase the rejection rates of the journals, causing
papers to be rejected more times prior to publication. Considering the
time from first submission of an article until its publication
(potentially in another journal), this will offset some, and possibly
all, of the shorter publication delay due to the shorter FRT.
In the current situation, simultaneous submissions are banned, and
the FRTs are 4-5 months and even more, resulting in many papers being
published years after they have been written. Are we doomed to live with
this situation forever? I propose below several ideas how the FRT can be
shortened. Szenberg (1994) suggests another good alternative to
shortening the FRT, which is probably even easier to implement--allowing
simultaneous submissions. The main drawback of both suggestions is
similar--the excessive number of submissions they create and the
resulting workload for editors and referees.
The main part of this article suggests four ideas how this drawback
can be overcome. These ideas can serve as complementary tools to either
a shorter FRT or to simultaneous submissions. The advantages and
disadvantages of these ideas are discussed shortly. There is a lot to
gain if we can reduce the FRT or allow simultaneous submissions without
incurring the problems caused by excessive submissions. Not only authors
will be happier, but readers will benefit as well because research will
be disseminated faster. My hope is that this article will stimulate
discussion and action among academics, as well as additional research,
which eventually will make the review process more efficient than it is
today.
II. Why Is it Important to Study the Review Process?
Since my goal is not only to present my ideas but also to encourage
others to do research on the review process, let me discuss briefly why
this area is important. There are two main reasons why research on the
academic review process is important. First, this process affects the
productivity of all economists as well as scholars in other disciplines.
Even a small improvement in productivity is very important, because the
small improvement is multiplied by thousands of scholars whose
productivity is improved. Research on the review process and the
profession more generally may suggest how to create better incentives
for researchers to publish high-quality work, reduce the time
researchers spend on refereeing tasks, reduce the time authors spend on
polishing papers (thus allowing them more time to work on new ideas; see
Ellison, 2002a; 2002b), and so on. If such research improves
productivity by 30 percent every year, the present value of it, taking a
discount rate of six percent per year, is that of five years of research
in all other areas together!
The second reason for the importance of research on the academic
review process is that of diminishing returns. The first article on any
topic is likely to contribute more to our knowledge than the thousandth
article. Obviously, this article is not the first to discuss the review
process; several others, often published in top journals, preceded it.
The literature addressed several issues in the review process, including
the use of single-blind versus double-blind review (Blank, 1991; Laband
and Piette, 1994), payment to referees (Engers and Gans, 1998; Chang and
Lai, 2001), the value-added from the review process (Laband, 1990), the
information versus selection function of journals (Meyer, 2000), and the
slowdown in the review process (Ellison, 2002a; 2002b; Azar, 2004b).
Yet, compared to its importance, the review process has received too
little attention. There is much to be added in the topics mentioned
above, and there are additional issues that have not been discussed in
the literature at all.
The importance of the production process is not limited to academic
research. In any industry, improving productivity is a very important
task. Outside academia (and government), however, firms have large
monetary incentives to invest in improving productivity. Indeed, firms
invest billions of dollars on activities that are aimed to increase
productivity. Shareholders have incentives to increase productivity, and
boards of directors and managers are appointed to supervise the
activities necessary to increase productivity and maximize profits.
In academia, there are incentives for individuals to increase their
efficiency, but hardly any incentives in the aggregate level to improve
the efficiency of the system. Moreover, no one has both the power and
the incentives to improve the system. While society may benefit from
increased productivity in academia, there are no managers with the
authority and incentives to make the production process of academic
knowledge optimal. It is therefore important that researchers will
dedicate time to think seriously about the issues involved in this
process.
Prices in academia often do not reflect supply and demand. The
amount of donations and governmental financial support that universities
receive is not the true value of the research that they produce; neither
are the funds given within the university to a particular department or
a faculty member the exact value of the research of the department or
professor. The private cost of submitting a paper to a journal is not
equal to the social cost, and the private benefits from having a
publication are not the same as the social benefits. The amount journal
readers pay for the journal does not reflect the true value of the
information in the journal. Research papers are available for free on
the Internet, and so on. In short, there is no invisible hand in
academia that makes the production process of academic research optimal.
We need to be the non-invisible hand, and the more this hand is
connected with the brain, the better. In other words, we should study
seriously how the production process of academic research works today,
what can be changed, and what are the possible effects of these changes.
In the absence of market forces or central planning, there is no reason
to assume that the current processes in academia are optimal.
III. Current First Response Times and Differences between
Disciplines
Although many economics journals publish data about the dates in
which the initial and final versions of the article were received, or
the acceptance date, no economics journal I have encountered publishes
information about the FRT of each article published. Going over dozens
of journals, however, I found several journals that publish aggregate
FRT statistics; Ellison (2002a) and websites of various journals
provided me some additional data. Table 1 presents the FRT in various
journals, ranked according to the median FRT for new submissions (the
mean when the median is not available).
Table 1 suggests that the average of the mean FRT (for new
submissions when more than one figure is presented) in the top five
journals (Econometrica, AER, JPE, QJE, and REStud) is 126-133 days,
depending whether the turnaround time in the QJE is taken to be 47 days
(all papers) or 82 days (only papers sent to referees). In the other six
economics journals in the table, this average is 129 days. As explained
in the comments to the table, these numbers probably underestimate the
true FRT, although the bias is not large. Assuming that the journals in
the table are representative of other economics journals as well, we can
conclude that in most economics journals today the FRT is about three to
six months, with an average somewhere between four and five months. If a
problem of self-selection is present, however (i.e. if journals publish
turnaround statistics only when they have a relatively low FRT), then of
course the true average FRT is even higher.
Table 1 includes also FRT in journals in accounting and finance
because the short FRTs in finance and accounting journals provide an
interesting comparison with economics. While a full discussion of the
differences in FRT between disciplines and their reasons justify a
separate article and are beyond the scope of this article, I discuss
this issue shortly below.
There are various reasons why FRTs differ across disciplines. Some
reasons have to do with the nature of the discipline. We would expect
that when many researchers work on the same problem at the same time and
there is only one correct answer to the problem, it will be very
important for them to publish their results very quickly (before a
competing scholar obtains the same results and publishes them first).
This will create pressure for very short FRT, because slow journals will
not attract good papers. Moreover, when the problems under consideration
are more objective in the sense that they usually have only one correct
answer, it might be easier to evaluate whether a certain paper makes a
significant contribution or not, thus helping to attain a short FRT.
These reasons might explain why the FRT tends to be much shorter in the
hard sciences compared to economics.
Another reason why the FRT might differ among disciplines is the
extent to which scholars depend on previous results for their work. In
disciplines in which research depends more on previous results, such as
the hard sciences, there is more social gain from quick publication of
results compared to disciplines in which new research is less dependent
on previous results (the humanities, for example). Even within
disciplines we can observe differences--in game theory, for example,
papers build more on previous results than in economic history. If
actual FRTs are influenced by the socially optimal FRT, (2) we would
expect, other things being equal, to see shorter FRTs in those
disciplines in which new research is heavily dependent on previous
results.
The FRT can also differ among disciplines due to other reasons,
such as the extent of specialization in the discipline, how busy is the
average scholar in the discipline, how many publications are expected
for tenure and promotion, whether publishing books is counted seriously
for tenure and promotion, the extent of competition between journals in
the discipline, and how much time it takes (in hours) to read a paper,
think about it, and write a report on it. Generally, we can think about
the FRT in a demand and supply framework: the demand for a short FRT
comes from the authors, while the supply comes from the editors and
referees. The more important it is for authors to have a short FRT, and
the less costly (or more beneficial) it is for editors and referees to
accommodate a short FRT, the shorter we would expect the FRT to be.
The comparison between economics, finance, and accounting, however,
is very illuminating because these disciplines are quite similar to each
other. Indeed, the discipline of finance is often referred to as
financial economics, and research in accounting can often be categorized as economics of information. All three disciplines have two main methods
of inquiry: abstract mathematical models, and empirical tests using
econometric methods. A well-trained economist can probably read and
understand a paper in finance or accounting in about the same way that
he can understand a paper in economics which is not in his specific
field. Many of the finance professors were in fact trained as
economists, and even the ones that were not, usually took several
graduate courses in economics. These observations suggest that there are
very little objective differences between economics, finance and
accounting, and we should therefore expect the FRT to be similar in
those disciplines. Yet Table 1 suggests otherwise.
Why is the FRT in finance only about a third of the FRT in
economics? Finance articles are not less complex to referee than
economics articles, and finance professors are not less busy than
economics professors. There are no big differences between the
disciplines in their research characteristics. The big difference in the
FRT seems to be the result of a combination of editorial efforts, social
norms, and higher submission fees in finance.
Editors in finance seem to be much more concerned with how fast
referees respond than editors in economics. For example, the Journal of
Financial Economics publishes on its website tables with the names of
its editorial board members and adhoc referees, indicating the number of
submissions each person reviewed, and his average review time.
Obviously, this creates some pressure on referees not to be the culprits
who take months to return a referee report. As another example for
editorial efforts to shorten the FRT in finance, the Journal of Finance
announced in the past "We record both the time the reviewer took
and the quality of the review. The quality of the author as a reviewer
is a strong influence on our decision of to whom we will send the
manuscript. Once again, the best way to ensure a good review is to be a
good reviewer when called upon" (Elton and Gruber, 1987). Telling
the referees explicitly that responding quickly will affect the quality
and speediness they will receive when they submit their papers clearly
creates pressure on referees to respond quickly and thus shortens the
FRT.
How are refereeing practices related to social norms? When a
referee decides how quickly to referee a paper, he takes into account
how quickly others referee papers (or in other words, the social norm
about how quickly a referee should respond), for several reasons. First,
feeling uncomfortable for delaying the publication process is affected
by the social norm. If everyone else sends the referee report in two
weeks, the referee will feel much more uncomfortable sending a report
after three months, than if everyone else sends reports after three
months. Second, the editor's expectations from the referee depend
on the social norm, and the referee cares about how quickly he is
compared to those expectations because he wants to retain the
editor's good will (for example because the referee might want to
submit to the journal himself in the future, or the editor might be
asked to write a letter on him when he is up for tenure or promotion).
Third, referees might want to reciprocate (even though the authors of
the papers they referee are not exactly those who refereed their papers
in the past) and provide similar service (both in terms of the quality
of the review and in terms of how quickly they respond) to the service
they receive when they submit papers. Thus, if every time I submit a
paper I receive a response in one month I will probably feel more
obligated to be a quick referee myself than if I wait five months every
time I submit a paper.
It is quite obvious that the social norm about how quickly referees
should respond is shorter than in economics. The social norm is how much
time it takes referees to complete a report on average, and given the
different FRTs in economics and finance and the fact that most of the
FRT is due to the time it takes referees to send their reports, it is
obvious that the social norm is different. Why is it different? One
reason is the greater editorial efforts to have a short FRT in finance.
Even editorial efforts in the past can affect the current FRT, because
they have affected the social norm, and social norms take time to change
(for a model describing evolution of social norms with application to
refereeing, see Azar 2007). Another reason why the social norm might be
different in finance and economics is discussed below--the different
submission fees. We can say that for the social norm to be different a
more fundamental difference has to exist, but once the social norm is
different, it has its own dynamics and it can continue to affect
referees' behavior and the FRT even if the fundamental differences
(e.g. submission fees or editorial efforts) have changed. Consequently,
even if economics journals will adopt the same submission fees and make
the same efforts to reduce the FRT as in finance journals, it can take
many years before the FRT in economics approaches that in finance,
because the social norm in economics is different and it might change
very slowly.
Why do submission fees affect the FRT, and how are submission fees
different in economics and finance? As Table 2 indicates, submission
fees in finance (and accounting) are much higher than in economics,
creating several effects that might lead to a shorter FRT. First,
because submission fees are higher, finance journals have more
incentives to compete for submissions. A major way to compete with other
journals is to provide authors with a shorter FRT. Second, the higher
submission fees alleviate the problem of excessive submissions of
low-quality papers to top journals, so the need to use a long FRT to
prevent those submissions is not as important as in economics. Third,
the higher submission fees allow finance journals to pay referees, thus
encouraging the referees to respond in a timely manner, as their
refereeing payment might depend on responding by a certain deadline. It
should be noted, however, that paying referees does not seem to be the
major reason for the difference between the disciplines. Some economics
journals also pay referees and are far from having FRTs similar to
finance. Moreover, a comparison between an economics journal that pays
referees and those that do not suggests that the effect of paying
referees on shortening the time it takes referees to send their reports
is relatively small (see Hamermesh, 1994).
Since the difference between economics, finance and accounting seem
to come from differences in editorial efforts, submission fees, and
social norms, rather than from anything which is inherently different in
the nature of the discipline, it seems possible to reduce the FRT in
economics significantly. Editorial efforts and submission fees can be
changed quickly; the social norm about how quickly referees should send
their reports will follow more slowly, but will change eventually as
well. The next section discusses in more detail ideas how the FRT can be
shortened.
IV. How Can the FRT be Reduced?
How can we reduce the FRT? Editors have various ways to shorten the
FRT (see also Hamermesh, 1994; Pressman, 1994; Szenberg, 1994). First,
they can try to minimize the time it takes them to choose referees and
to make editorial decisions once the referee reports are received.
Second, they determine how quickly they ask the referees to respond and
how much pressure they put on referees that do not respond on time.
Third, they can provide monetary incentives for the referees to respond
quickly, as some journals do, by paying the referees for timely reports.
Fourth, editors can use electronic submissions as a way to cut the
delays imposed by the mail (this is especially helpful when the editor
does not reside in the same country as the author or the referees).
Fifth, when a referee does not respond in a reasonable time,
editors can send the paper to another referee or make an editorial
decision with the one or two reports they already have, dismissing the
tardy referee from the refereeing task. Sixth, the editors can exclude
tardy referees from being referees in the future. This idea is not new:
the editors of The Economic Journal reported in an editorial note in
1973 "The people in the third category [referees who took over 2
months to send their report] were dropped from our list of referees,
unless there was a good reason for the delay" (Champemowne, Deane and Reddaway, 1973).
The two last ideas, however, have the potential problem of inducing
referees that care neither about their relationship with the editor nor
about their colleagues (the article's authors and its potential
readers) to be tardy on purpose, to avoid the current or future
refereeing tasks. (3) But referees who do not care about the editor and
their colleagues can simply refuse to referee the paper rather than to
respond only after a very long time. Refusing seems to dominate being
tardy in all dimensions: it takes less effort, does not hurt the authors
much (I assume here that the referee is not spiteful, just too busy or
lazy, so that he prefers to hurt the authors as little as possible), and
probably makes the editor less angry.
Seventh, when a tardy referee submits a paper to the journal, the
editor can send his paper to another referee who is known as a
procrastinator. If this policy is known, it will induce referees to
respond faster, at least if they consider the journal as an outlet for
their own papers. The Journal of Finance implemented and announced
publicly such a system, as was mentioned in the previous section.
Finally, another idea on how to shorten the FRT is that adopted by
the electronic journals The B.E. Journals in Economic Analysis &
Policy. (4) When an author submits a paper he commits to review two
other papers (unless he prefers to pay $350). If he does not do so, he
is fined $200 for each review not completed. The credit for the review
is received only if the review is sent within 21 days, giving a large
incentive ($200) to send the review quickly.
V. Why Do Lower First Response Times Increase the Number of
Submissions?
One of the main reasons for the negative relationship between the
FRT and the number of submissions is that promotion and merit-based pay
depend on the publication record. Consequently, the publication delay,
including the FRT, postpones the stream of monetary rewards, in addition
to making them last fewer years. The FRT, however, is more important to
the author than other parts of the publication delay because it delays
the publication of the paper whether the journal accepts it or rejects
it, while other parts of the delay usually affect only accepted papers.
Moreover, having the paper accepted is the critical signal regarding the
quality of the paper, not its actual publication, so the
acceptance--publication lag is less important from the author's
perspective than the submission--acceptance lag (which includes the FRT
as part of it).
The FRT can therefore be thought of as a cost of submission in
addition to the submission fee. Higher FRT increases the total
submission cost and as a result the author submits the paper more
selectively, reducing the total number of submissions. Azar (2005)
models this issue and using evidence on the costs of submissions and the
benefits of publications he obtains the result that shortening the FRT
will increase the number of submissions and the workload of referees and
editors significantly. Moreover, as a result the number of times papers
are rejected prior to publication will increase and offset some, or even
all, of the lower publication delay (each submission will take less
time, but a paper will be delayed by more submissions prior to
publication).
There are two additional reasons, however, why lower FRTs will
cause more submissions, reinforcing the conclusion of Azar (2005) about
the dangers of shortening the FRT. First, the author often wants the
paper to be published (or at least accepted) in a certain amount of
time, for example when a tenure decision is about to be made in a few
years. If the author has two years until the tenure decision and he
evaluates that it will take a year between receiving the first positive
decision (i.e. revise and resubmit) and the final acceptance of the
paper (after one or more revisions are made), then he wants to receive a
positive response in no more than one year. If the FRT is three months,
the author can plan to submit to about four journals at most; if it is
six months, he only has time to try two journals. When the author has
time for more journals, he can afford to submit to more top journals
with low acceptance rates at the beginning, hoping to reap the large
benefits of publication in a top journal. When there is time for fewer
journals, the author has to start submitting to lower-quality journals
with higher acceptance rates sooner, to avoid having no publication at
all. As a result, the paper is accepted after fewer submissions on
average when the FRT is longer, because of the submission strategy that
the author adopts.
The second reason why lower FRTs cause more submissions is that
acceptance chances are often decreasing with time. This is the case for
a policy-oriented paper that deals with a problem that may not be
interesting any loner if too much time elapses. Moreover, for any paper,
as time passes the probability that another article on the same topic
will be published (and reduce the acceptance chances of the paper) is
increased (not the probability per unit of time, but the cumulative
probability that such article preempts the author's paper). While
the author does not face a rigid time in which he wants the paper to be
published, he wants to start submitting to lower-quality journals not
too late. This creates a similar effect on submission strategy as was
discussed above, leading again to negative relationship between the FRT
and the number of submissions.
It is therefore risky to reduce the FRT if nothing else is changed.
With zero submission fees in many journals and nominal ones in others
(see Table 2), if the FRT will be very short, say a month, even authors
of papers with a very small probability to be accepted by a top journal
will find it optimal to submit the paper to almost all journals in a
decreasing order of quality, creating huge burden on referees and
editors. In fact, Azar (2005) suggests that even the current FRT may be
lower than optimal given the other characteristics of the publishing
process and the incentives to publish. The next sections describe how we
can solve the potential problem of increased number of submissions,
allowing to reduce the FRT without the risks mentioned above.
VI. Idea #1: Higher Submission Fees
A natural idea (at least for economists) is to prevent excessive
submissions by increasing submission fees. (5) In fact, increasing
submission fees, in addition to deterring low-quality papers from being
submitted to high-quality journals, also provides journals with
resources that allow them to compensate referees for timely reports,
making a reduction in the FRT more easily attainable. Hamermesh (1994)
shows that even a small monetary incentive (about $35) to complete the
refereeing task within a few weeks changes the behavior of referees,
although not of the slowest referees. (6) Higher incentives, however,
may affect also those slowest referees. Moreover, compensating referees
may also induce better refereeing from two reasons: first, being paid a
significant amount may cause referees to feel obligated to do a thorough
job. Second, if the payment is high enough, people may become interested
in serving as referees. Writing good referee reports is a way to
encourage the editor to ask for the referee's services again in the
future.
How to determine submission fees optimally is an important topic
that deserves treatment in separate articles, but I will raise a few
points here. A significant increase in submission fees, while having the
benefit of deterring excessive submissions of low-quality papers, also
creates inequality between authors with different monetary resources or
with different monetary incentives. Since the FRT is the major cost of
submission (Azar, 2005), the increase in submission fees has to be much
higher (in percentage) than the decrease in the FRT to prevent an
increase in submissions. Azar estimates, for example, that to keep the
same number and quality of submissions while reducing the FRT from four
to two months, we have to increase the submission fee from $50 to about
$375.
Authors from certain countries will not be able to afford such fees
at all. In other cases, even if the author can afford the submission
fee, he will not want to pay such a high fee. In many countries the
monetary incentives to publish are not as large as in the United States.
First, the increase in salary as a result of promotion is not everywhere
as significant as in the United States. Second, some countries do not
have personal contracts but rather a governmental imposed compensation
scheme, meaning that professors who reach the top of the scheme do not
have any monetary benefits from publications. If they continue to do
research (which is not always the case), it is because the satisfaction
they derive from doing research (and the status and respect it gives
them) exceeds the effort costs. But this does not mean that they will
still want to do research and publish if it costs them thousands of
dollars as submission fees. Sending an average paper to a top journal
implies acceptance chances of about 9 percent. A submission fee of $400
means that the author can expect to pay on average $400/0.09 = $4440
before the paper is accepted in a top journal. Many authors do not have
such strong incentives that will justify paying such huge amounts, and
they will avoid submitting their work to journals if submission fees are
around $400.
Charging differential fee according to the country of residence may
solve the geographical discrimination. The RAND Journal of Economics
(with submission fees of $50 / $85 for subscribers / non-subscribers),
for example, states, "The Editor-in-Chief may waive the submission
fee for submissions from authors in developing or transforming
countries." It is harder to solve the discrimination between
different authors in the same country, however. While journals could in
principle ask for income tax forms and charge smaller fees from authors
with smaller income, this is not likely to happen. As a result,
wealthier authors will have an advantage, as they will be able to afford
more submissions. Indeed, maybe the reason that the highest submission
fees are in finance and accounting journals (see Azar, 2005) is that
professors in these fields can afford higher submission fees than their
colleagues in economics departments because they earn more (at least in
the United States). Another problem is that certain institutions fund
the submission fees of their members / faculty; increasing submission
fees will have little effect on the submission strategy of these
authors.
VII. Idea #2: Paying by Reviewing Others' Papers
A related idea is to increase the cost of submission to the author
not by means of a monetary payment but rather by obtaining from him a
commitment to review papers in a proportion to the number of papers he
submits. (7) Journals use their authors as a main source of referees for
a long time, but this is done informally and authors do not face any
legal sanction if they refuse to referee papers for the journal. (8)
Moreover, the number of refereeing tasks someone receives is not
proportional to the number of his submissions. In particular, authors of
accepted papers are asked to referee much more than authors of rejected
papers. While this might seem reasonable because authors of accepted
papers are more grateful to the journal and therefore may accept the
refereeing assignments with more willingness to do a good job, it is
contrary to the correct incentives. To prevent submissions of
low-quality papers, a cost should be imposed on authors of rejected
papers, not those of accepted papers.
The suggested system involves an explicit commitment to referee
papers based on the number of submissions (or alternatively, on the
number of submissions that were rejected). If most papers are sent to
two referees, then the author should commit to referee two papers for
every paper he submits. If the paper has several authors, they can
decide how to split this commitment. Since a submission creates a
commitment to undertake significant refereeing work, authors will choose
to submit more selectively and therefore to fewer journals, other things
equal. This system also allows requiring timely response from the
referee for him to reduce his "refereeing debt," thus helping
to reduce the FRT.
This idea has several potential problems that should be addressed,
however. First, we cannot really make someone referee a paper seriously
against his will. So there should be sanctions against authors who
refuse to referee or who referee not seriously or not in a timely
manner. The simplest sanction, which was adopted by The B.E. Journals in
Economic Analysis & Policy, is monetary. You do not want to referee
to reduce your "refereeing debt"? Pay with money for the
refereeing services you received. (9) This, however, raises problems of
inequality in a similar manner to the idea to raise submission fees.
Wealthy authors will be able to send their papers to many journals,
paying with cash, while poorer authors will have to devote their scarce
time to referee others' papers.
Moreover, while it is easy to define what a timely report is, it is
hard to define criteria for the quality of the review. Obviously, the
editors expect a serious report, not just comments of the type "I
read the abstract and introduction and do not think the paper should be
published because it offers nothing new. Please credit my refereeing
debt for this review." So low-quality reports should not credit the
referee debt. Naturally, the editor will have to decide whether the
report is satisfying, but in the absence of clear criteria some
conflicts may arise if the editor is too tough, and if he is not, some
people may take advantage of it and devote less effort to the reports
they write than the effort others made on their papers.
Another potential problem is that the composition of the optimal
referees may be different from the pool of authors. The editor may want
to use certain referees but will not be able because they did not submit
papers to the journal, or they submitted but chose to pay with cash, or
they already paid (with reviews) their refereeing debt. Of course,
editors today also face the same problem, because today no one owes them
to referee papers. But when refereeing stops to be voluntary and becomes
a payment for refereeing services received, the willingness of people to
referee papers they do not have to referee may be reduced. An idea that
might mitigate this somewhat is to allow journals to exchange debts.
Thus, an author who owes to one journal but is essential for refereeing
in another journal can be used in the second journal and be credited in
the first one.
A smaller problem is that the editor can also get "stuck"
with authors who owe reports but cannot serve as appropriate referees.
It might not seem as a problem at first, but it is problematic in two
ways: first, each "uncollected debt" means that the editor has
to ask someone who do not owe a report to referee a paper. Second,
authors who know in advance that they will not be suitable referees will
take their commitment to referee less seriously, losing the effect of
deterrence of low-quality submissions.
VIII. Idea #3: Differential Delay--Let Low-Quality Papers Wait More
An intriguing idea that retains the role of the delay in preventing
excessive submissions of low-quality papers while not increasing the
delay in publication of accepted papers is the following. Referees will
send their referee reports shortly after they receive the paper. The
editor will reach his editorial decision based on the reports, and if it
is positive (accept / revise and resubmit), he will mail it immediately
to the author. If it is negative (reject), he will wait some time before
sending the decision. Therefore, the delay for papers that are
eventually published in the journal will be minimal, and yet the delay
for low-quality rejected paper will be high enough to deter excessive
submissions. The delay can even be gradual--the lower the quality of the
paper, the higher delay the editor will impose on the author. One can
argue that in equilibrium any author who does not receive a decision in
a short time will infer that the paper is going to be rejected and will
withdraw it. But the journal can institute a policy that a paper cannot
be withdrawn within a certain period of time after submission (and if it
is withdrawn, the author can be punished in future submissions or
otherwise, just as authors who are caught submitting simultaneously to
different journals face potential punishment).
There are several problems with this idea, however: first, it seems
unfair. This is especially true in those cases where the editor and
referees make a mistake (for anecdotal evidence of such mistakes, see
Gans and Shepherd, 1994; Shepherd, 1995); not only they reject a good
paper, but also they delay the editorial decision unnecessarily. But
editorial delays for rejected papers can be similar to what they are
today for all papers (so rejected papers are not worse off than today),
and using a gradual delay makes it unlikely that a good paper, even if
not accepted, will be delayed for a long time.
A second problem is that even a paper that is not suitable for
publication in a top journal may be good enough to be published in a
lower-quality journal, and it seems a waste to delay it. Once again,
however, the delay can be roughly what it is today anyway, so there is
no disadvantage in the suggested review process compared to the current
situation. Moreover, a paper that is generally good will have only a
short delay. In addition, the authors of the low-quality papers that
wait for relatively long times should have realized that they are
wasting scarce resources and that their papers are of much lower quality
than that expected in a top journal.
IX. Idea #4: Limiting the Number of Rejections a Paper is Allowed
to Receive
An additional way to prevent excessive submissions is to limit the
number of rejections a paper is allowed to receive. Suppose that a paper
will be able to receive at most four rejections. If it is rejected four
times, the author will have the option of posting it on a central
non-reviewed electronic database or discarding the paper altogether.
Most authors will not spend all their four trials on top journals. After
one or two rejections from top journals, they will try lower-quality
journals, because a second- or third-tier journal is still better than
no journal at all.
Such a system has several advantages. The number of submissions of
low-quality papers will be reduced both because the authors will be more
selective in their submissions and because no paper will be submitted
more than four times. This will save the scarce time of referees and
editors. Yet, even those papers who were rejected four times and are
presumably of low-quality will not be lost - upon the authors'
consent, they will be available electronically. Readers who are
interested in the subject area will easily find the paper in this
central database by searching the relevant keywords or even words in the
abstract or the full text.
Moreover, implementing such a system is achievable. Every author
will have a unique ID, and every paper will get a unique ID. A central
institution (let us denote it by ECD for Economics Central Database)
will handle the database about submissions in all journals as well as
the non-reviewed database of electronic papers that were rejected four
times.
Any submission to a journal will require also submission of an
electronic version of the paper. The journal will send the electronic
version of the paper together with the authors' ID and the
paper's ID to the ECD, which will add the information to its
database. The ECD will not inform the journal how many times the paper
was rejected, unless it was already rejected four times, so no bias in
the journal's decision can occur. If the paper was rejected four
times, the journal will refuse to consider it for publication. Once the
journal makes an editorial decision about a paper it will inform the ECD
whether it is a rejection or not, so that the ECD can update its
database. As a by-product, this system will also enable to verify that
authors do not submit the paper simultaneously to two or more journals.
One of the nice things about this system is that it does not
require full cooperation of all economics journals, only cooperation of
most of the good journals. Suppose that a low-quality journal, the
Journal for Moon Economics (a fictitious journal, of course), does not
want to participate. So the ECD does not know about rejections from the
Journal for Moon Economics. But papers that were rejected from a
low-quality journal are not likely to be submitted to high-quality
journals anyway, so it does not really hurt the system that the
rejection from the Journal of Moon Economics was not recorded.
Consider now a paper that was submitted to four high-quality
journals participating in the ECD and rejected from all of them. Suppose
that the author then submits to a journal that does not participate in
the ECD. If all high-quality journals are part of ECD, then it must be a
low-quality journal, and there is no harm in low-quality papers being
sent to low-quality journals. Any high-quality journal that will not
want to be part of the ECD will automatically be the natural submission
candidate for papers that received four rejections, which are presumably
not of high quality. Moreover, authors will not want to spend one of
their four allowed submissions on such a journal (because they can
submit to it on their fifth submission), so this journal is not likely
to receive many submissions of papers that were not rejected four times
before. Consequently, the quality of a non-participating journal will
become very low even if initially it was a good journal, so no editor
will want to remain outside the ECD if most high-quality journals
participate in it. Moreover, a condition for submission to participating
journals can be that the authors commit not to submit more than four
times even to non-participating journals. Whether authors obey their
commitment is easy to observe because published articles in
non-participating journals can be compared to the electronic versions of
rejected papers.
There are some technical issues, of course. One has to prevent
authors from changing the title and submitting a paper that received
four rejections as a new one. Here the electronic versions submitted
will play a role. A few graduate students employed by the ECD will
sample authors (with an emphasis on those with papers who received
multiple rejections) and check that submissions under different titles
are of different papers. It is even simpler to catch such cheating if
the paper is co-authored, because two papers at about the same time by
the same authors raise immediate suspicion. Minor changes will not be
considered a new paper. Major changes might be approved but the author
will have to ask permission from the ECD in advance. The incentive to
cheat is not big, however, since a paper that already received four
rejections is not likely to be accepted in a good journal anyway. And
scholars, after all, are usually honest people (see also Laband and
Piette, 2000). The very rare occurrence of plagiarism and simultaneous
submissions of papers shows this. With little resources dedicated to
supervision, the occurrence of cheating by changing the title of the
manuscript is likely to be very rare.
X. Conclusion
One of the main criticisms of the academic review process in
economics (and in some other disciplines as well) is the long time it
takes to receive a decision about a submitted manuscript. Since many
papers are rejected from a few journals prior to publication, a FRT of a
few months can delay publication by a year or two, delaying the
dissemination of research significantly. Several journals make efforts
to reduce the FRT, but reducing the FRT significantly has the risk of
inducing many more submissions of low-quality papers, increasing
considerably the workload of referees and editors. Moreover, the
increased submissions will increase rejection rates and delay the
publication process because papers will be rejected more times prior to
publication.
The question how to prevent submissions of low-quality papers to
high-quality journals is an important question and addressing it can
help reduce the cost of the review process, especially if we want to
reduce the FRT significantly, but even without such a reduction. This
article discusses four ideas that might help achieving this goal:
increasing submission fees, requiring authors to review papers in
proportion to the number of papers they submit, using differential delay
conditional on the paper's quality, and banning papers from being
submitted after a certain number of rejections. I hope that these ideas
will stimulate further discussion and research, and that consequently
the review process will be more efficient than it is today, increasing
the contribution of academia to society.
Finally, I want to propose a few ideas for future research. First,
all the ideas mentioned in the article deserve additional discussion.
Another topic that should be discussed is how much time referees should
invest in suggesting improvements to a paper they recommend to reject.
There is a trade-off between giving the author as much helpful feedback
as possible, and saving the referees' time. In addition, too much
helpful feedback for rejected papers may induce people to submit
premature papers just to receive feedback.
Empirical research of the review process is also important. Knowing
more about the review process is essential in order to determine whether
the process is optimal and if not what can be done. How many times is a
paper rejected on average before being accepted? What portion of the
editorial delay is caused by referees and what portion by editors? How
much time does it take referees to review a paper and write the referee
report? Do more experienced scholars write better reports, or maybe
since they are busy they write less helpful reports? To what extent do
authors revise a rejected paper according to the referee report before
sending it to another journal? How similar are the reports by different
referees on the same paper? Compared to the importance of the subject,
so little work was done that the opportunities for future research are
abundant. Such research can suggest changes that will improve the
efficiency of the review process and the productivity of scholars in all
areas.
References
Azar, Ofer H. (2004a) "Rejections and the importance of first
response times," International Journal of Social Economics 31(3):
259-274.
Azar, Ofer H. (2004b) "The slowdown in first-response times of
economics journals: Can it be beneficial?," working paper,
Northwestern University.
Azar, Ofer H. (2005) "The review process in economics: Is it
too fast?," Southern Economic Journal 72(2): 482-491.
Azar, Ofer H. (2007) "Evolution of Social Norms with
Heterogeneous Preferences: A General Model and an Application to the
Academic Review Process," Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, forthcoming.
Blank, Rebecca (1991) "The effects of double-blind versus
single-blind reviewing: Experimental evidence from the American Economic
Review," American Economic Review 81(5): 1041-1067.
Champernowne, D. G., Deane, P. M. and Reddaway, W. B. (1973)
"The Economic Journal: Note by the editors," The Economic
Journal 83(330): 495-504.
Chang, Juin-jen and Lai, Ching-chong (2001) "Is it worthwhile
to pay referees?," Southern Economic Journal 68(2): 457-463.
Ellison, Glenn (2002a) "The slowdown of the economics
publishing process," Journal of Political Economy 110(5): 947-993.
Ellison, Glenn (2002b) "Evolving standards for academic
publishing: A q-r theory," Journal of Political Economy 110(5):
994-1034.
Elton, Edwin J. and Gruber, Martin J. (1987) "Report of the
managing editors of the Journal of Finance for 1986," Journal of
Finance 42(3): 805-808.
Engers, Maxim and Gans, Joshua S. (1998) "Why referees are not
paid (enough)," American Economic Review 88(5): 1341-1349.
Hamermesh, Daniel S. (1994) "Facts and myths about
refereeing," Journal of Economic Perspectives 8(1): 153-163.
Gans, Joshua S. and Shepherd, George B. (1994) "How are the
mighty fallen: Rejected classic articles by leading economists,"
Journal of Economic Perspectives 8(1): 165-180.
Laband, David N. (1990) "Is there value-added from the review
process in economics?: Preliminary evidence from authors,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics 105(2): 341-352.
Laband, David N. and Piette, Michael J. (1994) "Does the
"blindness" of peer review influence manuscript selection
efficiency?," Southern Economic Journal 60(4): 896-906.
Laband, David N. and Piette, Michael J. (2000) "Perceived
conduct and professional ethics among college economics faculty,"
American Economist 44(1): 24-33.
Meyer, Dirk (2000) "On the information and selection function
of economics articles--claims and reality," Journal of Post
Keynesian Economics 23(1): 49-75.
Pressman, Steven (1994) "Simultaneous journal submissions: the
case against," American Journal of Economics and Sociology 53(3):
316-333.
Shepherd, George B. (1995) Rejected: Leading Economists Ponder the
Publication Process, Sun Lakes, Arizona: Thomas Horton and Daughters.
Szenberg, Michael (1994) "Disseminating scholarly output: The
case for eliminating the exclusivity of journal submissions,"
American Journal of Economics and Sociology 53(3): 303-315.
Thomson, William (2001) A Guide for the Young Economist: Writing
and Speaking Effectively about Economics, Cambridge, Massachusetts: The
MIT Press.
Notes
(1.) Pressman (1994) claims that usually the delay is caused by the
referees and not by the editors.
(2.) The reason that the socially optimal FRT is strictly positive
is that a very short FRT will cause excessive frivolous submissions of
low-quality papers to top journals and consequently a large waste of
editorial and refereeing efforts. The trade-off between this cost and
the benefit of having new research disseminated faster is different in
different disciplines, leading to different optimal FRT.
(3.) Future refereeing tasks are avoided in two ways: first, other
things equal, the editor will prefer to send an article to a referee
that was efficient in the past rather than to one that was tardy.
Second, as long as the referee does not return the report, he is less
likely to receive another refereeing task (see Thomson, 2001, 116).
(4.) See http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/policies. html.
(5.) The Journal of Financial Economics explicitly makes use of the
connection between submission fees and number of submissions. In a
managing editor's note about its decision to raise submission fees
to $400 (subscribers) and $450 (non-subscribers) (on-line at
http://jfe.rochester. edu/submfee.htm), Schwert writes "The
continued rise in submissions is putting a lot of pressure on the
resources of the journal (particularly the referees and the editor). I
hope you understand that increasing submission fees is a necessary step
to deal with this situation." It is interesting that the journal
that finds it essential to increase its submission fees is the one that
had the highest submission fees also before the increase, while some top
journals (such as Econometrica, QJE and REStud) do not charge submission
fees at all. In July 2004 the journal raised its submission fees again,
to $500 and $550 for subscribers and non-subscribers, respectively.
(6.) For theoretical work on paying referees see Engers and Gans
(1998) and Chang and Lai (2001).
(7.) This idea was adopted from the policies of the electronic
journals named The B.E. Journals in Economic Analysis & Policy, see
http://www. bepress.com/bejeap/policies.html.
(8.) The Canadian Journal of Economics makes this commitment a
little more explicit than in other journals, writing in the Submission
Guidelines for Authors (see http://economics.ca/cje/en/ submission.php):
"Perhaps 50% of refereeing is done by authors of recently accepted
manuscripts. Taking account of the fact that the CJE has an acceptance
rate of around 25% and that the median paper has two authors and two
referees, this implies that an author of an accepted paper would, on
average, referee two or three papers for the Journal. This is
statistical information only, as there is no formal or contractual
linkage between acceptance of a paper and refereeing. However, there is
an informal relationship. Basically, if you want to get a paper accepted
in the CJE you should expect to do your share of refereeing, and should
be willing to do it promptly. Submission of a paper should be treated as
an indication of willingness to do some refereeing for the CJE if the
paper is accepted for publication."
(9.) The B.E. Journals in Economic Analysis & Policy charge
$350 for each submission if the author does not want to owe reviews (in
addition to a $75 submission fee), but $400 if the author chooses to
commit to review and later does not do so.
Ofer H. Azar *
* Ofer H. Azar, Department of Business Administration, School of
Management, Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, P.O.B. 653, Beer Sheva 84105, Israel. Tel.: +972-8-6472675; Fax: +972-8-6477691. E-mail
address: azar@som.bgu.ac.il. I thank Gadi Barlevy, James Dana, Eddie
Dekel, Glenn Ellison, Ricky Lam, Robert Porter, William Rogerson, Asher
Wolinsky and an anonymous referee for helpful discussions and comments.
Financial support from The Center for the Study of Industrial
Organization at Northwestern University is gratefully acknowledged.
TABLE 1.
First Response Times in Various Journals (in Days)
Source/
Median Mean journal
FRT FRT Period issue Comments
Economics
Journals
Quarterly Journal NA 47 1997 Ellison All papers.
of Economics (2002a).
114 Accepted papers
only.
82 Papers sent to
referees.
Canadian Journal 91 1/1/02- The
of Economics 12/1/02 journal's
website.
Journal of 103 108 2000/ September Including
Economic History 2001 2001. re-submissions.
Southern Economic 107 122 2001 October New submissions
Journal 2002. only.
American Economic 109 122 7/1/00- May 2002. Rejected papers
Review 6/30/01 only.
Econometrica 110 122 2000 January New submissions
2002. only.
98 92 Revisions only.
108 122 All papers.
Economic Journal 137 137 2000 RES All papers.
Newsletter
(Jan
2003).
137 125 Letters advising
rejection.
168 188 Letters inviting
revision.
European Economic 143 165 2000 May 2002.
Review
The RAND Journal 153 131 2000 Summer Simple average
of Economics 2002. of the four
quarters of the
year.
Economic Inquiry NA 159 1/1/02- October
4/15/02 2002.
Journal of NA 167 2000 Ellison
Political Economy (2002a).
Review of 175 171 9/2000- The New submissions
Economic Studies 2/2001 journal's only.
website.
194 198 First revision.
159 138 Second revision.
Accounting
Journals
The Accounting 51 52 3/1/01- July 2002. Including
Review 2/28/02 re-submissions.
Journal of 52 53 12 August
Accounting and months 2002.
Economics ending
4/2002
Finance Journals
Journal of 37 43 10/2001- The
Financial 9/2002 journal's
Economics website.
The Journal of 39 44 3/1/00- The Including
Finance 7/31/02 journal's re-submissions.
website.
Details about the data and how it was computed are available from the
author upon request.
TABLE 2.
Submission Fees in Various Journals
Submission fee--
members / Submission fee--
The Journal subscribers others
Economics Journals
AER $75 $150
Econometrica $0 Must be members
to submit
Intl. Econ. Review $55 $120
J. Econ. Theory $0 $0
J. Monetary Econ. $100 $175
JPE $50 $50
QJE $0 $0
RAND J. Econ $50 $85
REStat $0 $50
REStud $0 $0
Accounting Journals
The Accounting Rev. $75 $100
J. Acc. & Econ. $250 $300
J. Accounting Res. $200 $200
Finance Journals
J. Finance $70 $140
J. Financial and Quantitative $200 $260
Analysis
J. Financial Econ. $500 $550
Rev. Financial Stud. $125 $175