The determinants of health status in Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA).
Fayissa, Bichaka ; Gutema, Paulos
I. Introduction
The health capital of nations serves both as an important means and
a basic end in efforts aimed at improving human welfare. Consequently,
development specialists and policy formulators have focused their
attention on a viable and efficient mechanism for improving the health
status of society, (Schultz, 2004). Over the years, such efforts have
produced impressive results in many regions of the world.
Although some African development specialists and policy makers
have also undertaken important measures for improving the quality of
life for their citizens, the health status of SSA is still considerably
low and exists below that of most parts of the world. Low life
expectancy at birth, high infant and maternal mortality rates, malaria
and tuberculosis afflictions, and the HIV/AIDS pandemic are some of the
unique images of the health status of the African content. The World
Bank (2002) data set shows that a new infant born in SSA has only 42
expected life-years to live. If the same infant were born in high-income
countries of the world during the same period, however, it would have
expected 70 years to live. The high-income groups aside, the infant
would have 46 expected years had it been from other low-income
countries. Not only is the level of expected life disappointing, but
also its dynamics is equally alarming. In low and middle-income
countries, the average life expectancy at birth has improved from about
13 to 15 life-years from the 1960s to the 1990s, respectively; in SSA,
however, it has only changed by about 7 life-years during the same
period. This change is also far below the world average of about 11
years.
A similar phenomenon can also be observed from other indicators. In
the 1960s, the average number of infants dying before reaching one year
of age per 1,000 live births was estimated to be 154, while it was only
about 27 in high-income countries. From the 1960s to 1990s, the high
income and middle income countries have reduced this figure by about 77
and 65 percent, respectively, while SSA only reduced infant mortality by
only 38 percent which is also below the world's average of almost
50 percent. The intended progress might have been hampered by different
socioeconomic, political, and environmental factors. This study,
nonetheless, perceives that the health status of SSA can be
substantially improved despite the prevailing distressing health
records.
This paper estimates the determinants of health status for the
region based on the Grossman (1972) theoretical model. The model treats
economic, social, and environmental factors as inputs of the production
system. The major advantages of identifying the determinants are that
estimates of the over-all effect of medical care utilization on the
health status of the population can be obtained (Thornton, 2002). Policy
makers and practitioners can use the above information in their search
for cost effective mechanisms for providing health services and the
reallocation of health resources in such a manner that the gains from
health spending could be optimized.
The remaining sections of the paper are organized as follows. The
next section outlines the framework, hypotheses, and data. Section three
describes the empirical method derived from the Grossman (1972)
theoretical model. The econometric results and interpretations are given
in section four. The last section summarizes and draws conclusions based
on the results.
II. The Framework, Hypotheses, and Data
To determine responsiveness of the health status of SSA to the
economic, social, and environmental factors, we specify a double
log-linear Cobb-Douglas production function based on the Grossman (1972)
model as:
Lnh = ln[OMEGA] + [SIGMA][[alpha].sub.i] (ln[y.sub.i]) +
[SIGMA][[beta].sub.j] (ln[s.sub.j]) +
[SIGMA][[gamma].sub.k](ln[v.sub.k]), (1)
Where Lnh is the natural log of individual's health status
measured by life expectancy at birth, [y.sub.i] is a vector of per
capita economic variables, [s.sub.j] is a vector of per capita social
variables, [v.sub.k] is a vector of per capita environmental factors,
and [y.sub.i], [s.sub.j], and [v.sub.k] are expressed in natural log
(where i = 1, 2; j = 1, 2; and k = 1, 2). [OMEGA] is an estimate of the
initial health stock of the region, [[alpha].sub.i], [[beta].sub.j],
[[gamma].sub.k] are elasticities.
Estimation of the health status model given by equation (1)
requires data on health status as well as on socioeconomic and
environmental variables. However, measuring health status directly is
somewhat difficult and, for aggregate studies, some researchers (1)
suggest life expectancy at birth and mortality rate for infants and
children as indicators of the health output. In our study, we employ
life expectancy at birth as the dependant variable. It indicates the
number of years a newborn infant would live if prevailing patterns of
mortality at the time of its birth were to remain the same throughout
its life. The explanatory variables and their expected coefficients are
described below.
On the right hand side of the function, as indicated in equation
(1), the health expenditure per capita to GDP ratio, per capita food
availability index, illiteracy rate, adult alcohol consumption per
capita, urbanization rate, and C[O.sub.2] emissions are used.
The first representative of an economic factor is the health
expenditure to GDP ratio. It constitutes both public and private health
expenditure and covers the provision of health services, family planning activities, and emergency aid designed for health. Generally, it is
considered as a measure of availability of the health production
facilities to a given society. Indeed, some empirical studies use stock
of facilities like hospital beds per 1000 people, physician per 1000
people etc. instead of expenditures on health. However, Hadley (1982)
states that using medical care expenditures as a measure of the
provision of the facilities is more desirable than using a stock of
providers because variation in expenditures across geographic areas
better reflects the differences in quality and quantity of such
services.
The expected relationship between health expenditure and life
expectancy is, however, somewhat ambiguous. On the one hand, higher
levels of per capita health expenditures may help to increase the
provision of health facilities that in turn may improve life expectancy.
However, this is only true if the increment in expenditure has no
adverse effect on the individual's health status. An adverse effect
may arise if the expenditures are financed by revenues collected from
user fees, or taxes, and if the fees and tax payments are made at the
expense of the individual preventive health cares such as food,
clothing, and housing which may occur in subsistence societies. In this
situation, unless the marginal effect of an increase in the facilities
is so high to compensate the forgone benefits from preventive health
care, it is normal to obtain a negative coefficient for the variable.
Moreover, countries with poor initial health levels may allocate more
resources to medical care than other countries. Therefore, the sign of
the coefficient cannot be predicted a priori.
The second representative of an economic factor is the food
availability index. Given that the problem of nutrition in poor
economies is more of scarcity and not of over consumption, we expect a
positive coefficient for food availability. Food production index is
used as a measure of food availability. It covers food crops that are
considered edible and contain nutrients.
Social factors are represented by variables of education and adult
alcohol consumption per capita. In using education as a social factor,
we recognize the argument of some writers that education is not an input
by itself, as Wolfe and Behrman (1984) have argued; it is considered as
a catalyst which increases the marginal efficiency of other inputs.
Adult illiteracy rate is taken as a proxy for education. It is the
percentage of people above 15 years who cannot read, write, and
understand a simple statement on their daily activities. Grossman (1972)
and other studies have argued that education influences many decisions
that impact the quality of life (such as a choice of job, ability to
select a healthy diet, and avoid unhealthy habits, efficient use of
medical care). Grossman (2004), Fuchs (2004), Berger and Leigh (1989),
Rosen and Taubau (1982) and others have provided empirical evidence in
support of this argument. We, therefore, hypothesize that the more
literate society is the healthier its people will be, and hence we
expect a negative coefficient of adult illiteracy rate.
The second social factor is life style; among others, it is
represented by adult alcohol consumption per capita. It is measured by
the amount of pure ethanol in liters of total alcohol consumed per adult
(15 years and older) in a country during a calendar year, as calculated
from official statistics on production, sales, imports, and exports,
taking into account stocks whenever possible. The source of the data is
the World Health Organization's (WHO) alcohol consumption database.
According to Fuchs (2004), Chick et al. (1986), and Choquent and Ledoux
(1989), alcohol consumption is recognized as an important risk factor
for most chronic illnesses such as diseases of the digestive system,
cancer, cirrhosis etc. as well as for accidents and violent deaths.
Thus, we expect a negative coefficient for this variable.
We consider urbanization rate or the share of the total population
living in areas defined as urban in each country and carbon dioxide emissions per capita to capture the effect of environmental factors on
life expectancy. Thornton (2002) states that urbanization is a proxy for
a collection of potential negative and positive health related factors.
On the positive side, he notes that it avails access to medical care and
health information. In a slightly different context, Rosenzweig and
Schultz (1983) argue that urban public health institutes are substitutes
for health care knowledge and management capacity that an educated
individual brings to his family. Moreover, it is argued that in urban
areas clinics are more cost-effective. On the negative side, Thornton
(2002) indicates that urbanization is associated with pollution and
congestion that have adverse effects on health. Considering both sides
of the issue, one can assert that the marginal effect of urbanization
depends on the net effect of the two contradictory factors. Hence, the
sign of urbanization rate cannot be predetermined.
Lastly, carbon dioxide emission per capita is another variable we
considered as an environmental factor. Emissions from the burning of
fossil fuels and the manufacture of cement are used as a proxy for the
environmental factors. They include contributions to the carbon dioxide
produced during consumption of solid, liquid, and gas fuels and gas
flaring. Since emissions cause air pollution that results in health
hazards, we expect a negative coefficient for the variable. Data for the
above variables were taken from World Bank (2002), unless otherwise
stated. The study is confined to the period of 1990-2000 for a
cross-section of 33 Sub-Sahara African countries (2) due to data
incompleteness.
III. The Empirical Estimation Method
For estimation of the parameters under consideration, a panel data
analytic approach is employed. In forming the panel, time series data of
each country were averaged over two years and a total of five periods
were formed for each country; an econometric model is specified for
equation (1) in its general form. In order to provide an empirical
exposition of the model, the specification is given as follows:
h *(g,t) = [delta](g) + [GAMMA](t) + X *(g,t). [PHI] + [PSI](g,t)
(2)
Where h *(g,t) is natural logarithm of life expectancy in country g
at year t, and X *(g,t) is vector of explanatory variables
([y.sub.1],[y.sub.2],[s.sub.1],[s.sub.2],[v.sub.1],[v.sub.2]) for g =
1,2, ... m (number of countries), t = 1,2 ... T (number of years), [PHI]
is vertical vector of parameters ([[alpha].sub.1], [[alpha].sub.2]
[[beta].sub.1], [[beta].sub.2], [[gamma].sub.1],.[[gamma].sub.2]);
[PSI](g,t) is a classical stochastic disturbance term with E[[PSI](g,t)]
= 0 and var[[PSI](g,t)] = [[delta].sup.2.sub.[epsilon]], [delta](g) and
[GAMMA](t) are country and time specific effects, respectively. Instead
of an a priori decision on the behavior of [delta](g) and [GAMMA](t),
five different types of the most common assumptions are separately
imposed on the model and the one that gives a superior estimate is
selected based on statistical rules.
The first assumption is that all of the country specific effects
are constant and equal across the countries; and the time specific
effects are not present, i.e. [delta](g) = [lambda] and [GAMMA](t) = 0,
for some constant [lambda]. Under this assumption, model (2) is
estimated by ordinary least squares (OLS) method and the results are
reported as the Restricted OLS Model.
The second and third alternative specifications assume absence of
time specific effects, which is basic attribute of One-Way
specification. The second estimation technique assumes that country
specific effects are constant like the first one, but not necessarily
equal, i.e. [delta](g) = [lambda](g) and [GAMMA](t) = 0, for some
constants [lambda](g). Under this case, equation (2) is estimated by a
partitioned OLS. The estimates are reported under One-Way Fixed-Effects
Model.
The third assumption type tested in the analysis is that country
specific effects are not constants, but rather are disturbances; and the
time specific effects are not present here again i.e., [delta](g) =
[lambda] + w(g) and [GAMMA](t) = 0, where E[(w(g)] = 0, and var[w(g)] =
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.w]. and cov[[PSI](g,t),w(g)] = 0. Unlike the previous
cases, equation (2) is estimated by a feasible a 2-step Generalized
Least Squares (GLS). The results of this estimation are given under the
One-Way Random-Effects Model.
The fourth and the fifth assumptions differ from the first three in
their time specific effects components (a basic feature of Two-Way
specification). The fourth assumption requires that both country and
time specific effects are constants, but are not necessarily equal; and
there is an overall constant, i.e., [delta][delta](g) + [GAMMA](t) =
[lambda]' + [lambda]'(g) + [gamma](t), where [lambda]',
[lambda]',(g) and [lambda](t) are some constants. The results of
this estimation are reported under the Two-Way Fixed-Effects Model.
The last assumption is that both the country and time specific
effects are disturbances with [delta](g) + [GAMMA](t) = [lambda]" +
w' (g) + [tau](t), where [lambda]" is some constant, and
w' (g), [tau](t) are disturbances. In this case, just as in
assumption three above, eq7uation (2) is estimated by 2-step GLS model.
The results of the estimation are reported under Two-Way Random-Effects
Model. After estimating the parameters based on the above five
assumptions, the superior specification is selected on the basis of a
suitable statistical test.
IV. Econometric Results and Interpretations
Equation (2) is estimated using the data and method described
above. The empirical results are given in tables 1 and 2. To choose from
One-Way and Two-Way specifications, we use the F-statistics. The
statistics tests the significance of any time specific effect that is
not included in One-Way regression specification. The test result given
at the bottom of table 2, suggests that Two-Way error component
regression model is superior to the One-Way, (p = 0.0016).
The next step will be selecting an appropriate estimator from the
three given estimators. To start with, the poolability or
appropriateness of the constrained model, or OLS estimator is tested. In
other words, this test helps us to examine the hypothesis of absence of
country specific effects. With N = 33 T = 5 and k = 7, a
Lagrange-multiplier test for significance of country specific effects
yields a [chi square]-value of 155.86, p = 0.0000. This is distributed
as [[chi square].sub.(2)] under the null hypothesis of zero country
specific effects. The null is soundly rejected, and the within or the
random effect model is preferred to OLS estimator. That is, the test
does not support the poolability of the data set, suggesting that there
are strong country-specific effects.
Next, for the choice between random-effects (GLS estimator) and the
within effect estimator a Hausman-test is performed. The basic
assumption associated with random-effect is that there is no correlation
between the regressor and country specific effects. If such assumption
is violated, then the GLS estimator will be biased and inconsistent. The
test shows a [chi square] value equal to 3.88, (p = 0.6935). This is
distributed as [[chi square].sub.(2) under the null hypothesis of
absence of the indicated correlation. The null hypothesis of no
correlation between the country specific effect and the regressor is
strongly accepted. This implies that the GLS estimator in this case is
unbiased and consistent. As a result, the preferable estimates of the
parameters in equation (2) can be given by the two-way random-effects
models.
Accordingly, the coefficient of the per capita food availability is
found to be positive and statistically significant, suggesting that the
variable favorably influences the health status of the region in the
periods of good economic performance. The results suggest that a one per
cent increment in food availability per capita can generate a 0.13
percentage improvement in health status. The estimate further suggests
that if the region's economies are able to repeat their food
production performance during the second half of 1980s (about 0.53%
growth on food production per capita), then it is possible to improve
life expectancy by about 2.5 life-years, other things remaining
unchanged. In short, the parameter estimate of this variable suggests
that successful policies directed towards increasing food availability
of the region can have an impressive impact on the health status of the
region.
On the other hand, the table reports a negative and statistically
significant coefficient for the health expenditures variable. Such a
relationship could occur if the society is close to subsistence, i.e.
has meager, or no savings, and if the expenditures are financed through
fees or taxes collected from the users. In this case, an increase in the
expenditures will have a consumption reducing effect of life nurturing
and sustaining goods such as food, clothing, housing etc, as it competes
for the budget allocated for such types of amenities. If the marginal
effect of the latter types of goods exceeds that of the former types
(the health facilities to be provided by increased expenditures), then
it is not surprising to get a negative coefficient for the health
expenditures variable.
The analytical argument given in above suggests that the negative
coefficient is due to the cost ineffective provision of health
facilities, when seen from its opportunity cost perspective. In other
words, the facilities could not restore the forgone health benefits that
arise in the process of obtaining them. Moreover, the negative
relationship between life expectancy and the per capita medical
expenditures may be attributed to the fact that countries with poor
initial health levels may allocate more resources to medical care than
others. Thus, we argue that reversing the existing trend is one of the
areas that deserves a special attention in efforts directed to the
improvement of the health status of the region.
Table 2 also reports that the coefficient of the illiteracy ratio
has a statistically strong impact on health status, (P = 0.0000),
suggesting that a one percent reduction in the illiteracy ratio (which
is an approximation of the 1990s educational performance of 1.17
percent) would lead to 0.004% increment in life expectancy. As
previously discussed, this is possible as more education gives the
people more awareness about their own health status and of what
preventive measures would improve their own health.
Furthermore, the table indicates that alcohol consumption has a
statistically strong negative impact on health status (p = 0.0308).
Lastly, the table indicates that an increase in urbanization rate and a
decrease in carbon dioxide emissions may contribute to the improvement
of health status. This suggestion is, however, not supported by a
statistical test of significance.
V. Summary and Conclusion
The study has investigated the determinants of health status in
Sub-Sahara Africa in line with the Grossman (1972) theoretical model
using socioeconomic and environmental factors as determinants of health
status. The main data source for the study is the World Bank (2002) data
set, with the exception of the alcohol consumption data which were drawn
from the WHO's database. To overcome data limitation, we used
pooled cross-section time series for 33 SSA countries covering the
1990-2000 periods.
The results obtained from two-way random-effect regression model
suggest that an increase in food availability per capita and literacy
rate and a decrease in alcohol consumption have a significant favorable
effect on life expectancy. Health expenditure has shown a strong
negative relationship with life expectancy, which possibly arises from
the inefficient health service provision systems. Moreover, an increase
in urbanization and a decrease in Carbon dioxide emissions per capita
are found to improve life expectancy, though this argument cannot be
supported based on the statistical significance of the tests.
In general, the results suggest that a health policy which mainly
focuses on provision of health services, family planning programs, and
emergency aids and ignores the marginal efficiencies of the services,
and other socio-economic aspects may serve little in efforts directed to
improve the existing health status of the region. Lastly, from the
analyses and the region's past socioeconomic performances, we
observe the fact that making substantial improvements of the health
status of SSA are within the realm of possibility.
References
Auster, R, Levenson, I., and Sarachek, D. (1969), "The
Production of Health, an Exploratory Study," Journal of Human
Resources, 4:411-36.
Berger, M. and Leigh, J. (1989), "Schooling, Self-selection,
and Health," Journal of Human Resources, 24: 433-55.
Behrman, Jere R. and Anil B. Deolalikar (1988), "Health and
Nutrition," in Hollis Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan, eds., Hand-book
of Development Economics, Volume I: 1988, Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Chick J., J. Duffy, G. Lloyd, B. Ritson (1986), "Medical
Admissions in Men: The Risk Among Drinkers," The Lancet, ii:
1380-83.
Chistiansen, T. (1994), "Distribution of Health Status by
Income. Result from Denmark," in A. Mielck and R. Maria, eds.,
Health inequalities: Discussion in Western European countries, Waxmann,
Munster/New York.
Choquet, M. and S. Ledoux (1989), "Alcohol Related Problems in
France" in WHO EURO Reports and Studies, 109: 45-63.
Fuchs, V., (1994), The Future of Health Policy, Harvard University
Press: Cambridge.
--. (2004), "Reflections on the Socio-Economic Correlates of
Health," Journal of Health Economics, 23 (2004): 653-661.
Grossman, M. (1972), The Demand for Health." A Theoretical and
Empirical Investigation, NBER: New York.
--. (2004), "The Demand for health, 30 Years Later: A Very
Personal Retrospective and Prospective Reflection," Journal of
Health Economics, 23 (2004):629-636.
Hadley, J. (1982), More Medical Care, Better Health, Urban
Institute: Washington DC.
Rogers, G. B. (1979), "Income and Inequality as Determinants
of Mortality: An International Cross- Section Analysis," Population
Studies, 33(2): 343-52.
Rosen S. and Taubman, P. (1982), "Some Socioeconomic
Determinants of Mortality," in J. Van der Gagg, W. B. Neeman and T.
Tsukahara, eds., Economics of Health Care: 1982, New York, Preager
Publishers.
Rosenzweig, M. R. and T. P. Schultz (1983), "Estimating a
Household Production Function: Heterogeneity, the Demand for Health
Inputs, and Their Effects on Birth Weight," Journal of Political
Economy, 91 (1983):723-746.
Schultz, T. P. (2004), "Health Economics and Applications in
Developing Countries," Journal of Health Economics, 23 (2004):
637-641.
Thornton, J. (2002), "Estimating a Health Production Function
for the US: Some New Evidence," Applied Economics, 34: 59-62.
Wilkinson, R. G. (1992), "Income Distribution and Life
Expectancy," British Medical Journal, 304:165-68.
Notes
(1.) See, for example, Beherman and Deolalikar (1988: 698-701)
(2.) Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape Verde,
Central African Republic, Chad, Cote d'Ivoire, Equatorial Guinea,
Ethiopia, Gambia, Ghana, Kenya, Madagascar, Malawi, Mall, Mauritania,
Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Senegal, South
Africa, Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe
Bichaka Fayissa, Department of Economics and Finance, Middle
Tennessee State University, Murfreesboro, Tennessee 37132, Tel. (615)
898-2385, Fax: (615) 898-5596, e-mail: bfayissa@mtsu.edu
Paulos Gutema, Addis Ababa University, Ethiopia, E O. Box 33229,
Tel. (251-1) 55 68 22, Fax 251-1-55 13 33, e-mail: pgutema@hotmail.com
TABLE 1
One-Way Error Component Regression Model Estimates for Equation (2)
Estimate of St. error of
Estimators Parameters the parameter the parameter
Restricted [[alpha].sub.1] -0.0206 0.0064
Model OLS [[alpha].sub.2] 0.2122 0.0682
[[beta].sub.1] -0.0032 0.0006
[[beta].sub.2] -0.0160 0.0071
[[gamma].sub.1] 0.0029 0.0010
[[gamma].sub.2] 0.0122 0.0081
Constant 3.1046 0.3125
Fixed Effect [[alpha].sub.1] -0.0350 0.0092
Model [[alpha].sub.2] 0.1511 0.0675
[[beta].sub.1] 0.0019 0.0021
[[beta].sub.2] -0.0331 0.0221
[[gamma].sub.1] -0.0036 0.0032
[[gamma].sub.2] 0.0164 0.0204
Random [[alpha].sub.1] -0.0337 0.0069
Effect [[alpha].sub.2] 0.1645 0.0486
Model [[beta].sub.1] -0.0018 0.0010
[[beta].sub.2] -0.0165 0.0118
[[gamma].sub.1] -0.0018 0.0015
[[gamma].sub.2] 0.0448 0.0125
Constant 3.5110 0.2322
Estimators Parameters T-ratio p-value
Restricted [[alpha].sub.1] -3.2135 0.0016
Model OLS [[alpha].sub.2] 3.1115 0.0022
[[beta].sub.1] -5.4849 0.0000
[[beta].sub.2] -2.2335 0.0269
[[gamma].sub.1] 2.9619 0.0035
[[gamma].sub.2] 1.5163 0.1315
Constant 9.9342 0.0000
Fixed Effect [[alpha].sub.1] -3.8227 0.0002
Model [[alpha].sub.2] 2.2376 0.0266
[[beta].sub.1] 0.9025 0.3682
[[beta].sub.2] -1.4960 0.1366
[[gamma].sub.1] -1.1300 0.2602
[[gamma].sub.2] 0.8081 0.4203
Random [[alpha].sub.1] -4.8924 0.0000
Effect [[alpha].sub.2] 3.3841 0.0007
Model [[beta].sub.1] -1.8298 0.0673
[[beta].sub.2] -1.3919 0.1639
[[gamma].sub.1] -1.1976 0.2311
[[gamma].sub.2] 3.5923 0.0003
Constant 15.1220 0.0000
Lagrange Multiplier test of RM vs. FE/RE
[[chi square].sub.(1)] = 139.24, p = 0.0000
Hausman test of FE vs. RE; [[chi square].sub.(6)] = 0.00, p = 1.0000
TABLE 2
Two-Way Error Component Regression Model Estimates for Equation (2)
Estimate of St. error of
Estimators Parameters the parameter the parameter
Fixed Effect [[alpha].sub.1] -0.0343 0.0079
Model [[alpha].sub.2] 0.1147 0.0515
[[beta].sub.1] -0.0105 0.0042
[[beta].sub.2] -0.0294 0.0218
[[gamma].sub.1] 0.0016 0.0034
[[gamma].sub.2] 0.0120 0.0259
Constant 3.9852 0.3464
Random [[alpha].sub.1] -0.0302 0.0067
Effect [[alpha].sub.2] 0.1337 0.0474
Model [[beta].sub.1] -0.0042 0.0010
[[beta].sub.2] -0.0255 0.0118
[[gamma].sub.1] 0.0026 0.0016
[[gamma].sub.2] 0.0115 0.0135
Constant 3.5610 0.2279
Estimators Parameters T-ratio p-value
Fixed Effect [[alpha].sub.1] -4.3539 0.0000
Model [[alpha].sub.2] 2.2283 0.0273
[[beta].sub.1] -2.4819 0.0141
[[beta].sub.2] -1.346 0.1802
[[gamma].sub.1] 0.4735 0.6365
[[gamma].sub.2] 0.4624 0.6444
Constant 11.5032 0.0000
Random [[alpha].sub.1] -4.5223 0.00001
Effect [[alpha].sub.2] 2.8211 0.0048
Model [[beta].sub.1] -4.1052 0.0000
[[beta].sub.2] -2.1603 0.0308
[[gamma].sub.1] 1.6058 0.1083
[[gamma].sub.2] 0.8555 0.3923
Constant 15.6230 0.0000
F-test of One-Way vs Two-Way F[4.122] = 4.633, p = 0.0016
Lagrange Multiplier test of RM vs. FE/RE
[[chi square].sub.(2)] = 155.86, p = 0.0000
Hausman test of FE vs. RE; [[chi square].sub.(6)] = 3.88 p = 0.6935