On entrepreneurship, growth and rent-seeking: Henry George updated.
Baumol, William J.
Progress and Poverty, that memorable work of Henry George, leaves
us with three main messages: first, that the rent of land is an
egregious contributor to inequality; second, that rent, unlike other
income sources, can be taxed without detrimental incentive effects; and
third, that this is so because pure rent is a payment for which the
recipient provides no production to society in return. These ideas
continue to stir his followers to this day, which at once raises a
question. Since, as a share of the Nation's income, the rent of
land has fallen to a mere two percent, how can anything so minuscule merit our attention, or the attention of the designers of economic
policy?
I will show here that George's analysis continues to be
pertinent and important, but is so primarily when it is generalized and
its applicability thereby extended well beyond its original bounds.
Economists have focused on the last of George's three observations
listed above--rent as the payment for zero contribution by the
recipient--and now use the term to refer to any such uncompensated payment. When, for example, a business conspiracy accumulates large
monopoly earnings in an industry whose output is, if anything, reduced
in the process, then economists deem that collaboration to have resulted
in the acquisition of substantial "rent." It is rent in this
generalized sense that is at the forefront of modern economic
developments, as will be shown here.
Of course, the newspapers tell us every day, in sensational terms,
that rentseeking and rent-getting are neither things of the past, nor a
source of wealth only of landowners. The "Enrons" of our
economy-along with the proffision of top corporate managements that have
been able to provide themselves with obscenely high incomes even though
the performances of their firms had little or nothing to commend
them--are today's more obvious counterparts of George's
landholders. But that is not the tale on which I want to focus. Rather
than looking at wrongdoing and flouting of the law, I will direct
attention to the development that constitutes our economy's most
dramatic success, an accomplishment not remotely replicated by any
previous economy. It is the free market's incredible outpouring of
production and innovation, and the entrepreneur's role in the
process, with which my discussion is primarily concerned.
1. Entrepreneurship as a Resource Allocable Between Productive and
Unproductive Activities
One can say of the role of the entrepreneur in mainstream
mathematical writings about the firm much what Mark Twain said of the
weather: Everyone talks about the subject but no one does anything about
it. Every economist surely must be prepared to concede that
entrepreneurs are (even if for reasons not fully specified) of great
importance. Certainly, entrepreneurs are often accepted as the critical
contributors to economic growth, particularly in the centuries of
industrial revolutions. But in standard microtheory, entrepreneurs are
completely invisible.
To begin with, let me recall the two senses in which the term is
used and indicate why neither definition permits the entrepreneur a role
in the standard microeconomic models. Sometimes, the entrepreneur is
defined as the organizer of any new firm, whether or not the enterprise
is novel in operation or organization, and that is surely the meaning of
the French or the German terms for the activity. But for other writers,
following Joseph Schumpeter, the entrepreneur is an innovator, who is
always engaged in doing something that was never done previously, and
not just founding yet another business entity of a sort that already
exists.
The classic Schumpeterian model, in which the entrepreneur finds he
can earn profits only by innovating, and can obtain an enduring flow of
profits only by constantly innovating, is the prime example. And it is
an example important for the discussion here because it is so clearly
not the end of the story. Later, I will discuss Schumpeter's
observation in his later writings that the innovation process is
undergoing routinization. The questions to which this view gives rise
are whether it is in fact true and, if so, where it leaves the
entrepreneur, i.e., whether routinization of innovation threatens to
deprive him of his role. One may well ask whether this provides some
justification for the absence of the entrepreneur from the formal models
of mainstream microtheory.
However, in this paper I will focus on another major gap in the
stories of those who do choose to write about the entrepreneur. It is
often at least implied that growth in economies tends to take off when
there has for some mysterious reason been an expansion in the number of
members of the society with entrepreneurial propensities and,
correspondingly, that economies experience decline and fall when the
share of entrepreneurs in their population for some reason collapses.
Thus, the notion is that societies can experience apparently autonomous
outbursts of entrepreneurship and equally independent declines and
near-disappearances of the entrepreneurial individuals whose activities
are so critical for growth. Is there an economic explanation for such
developments that can perhaps enable us to do something about them, or
must they be treated as fundamentally fortuitous and inexplicable
events, as phenomena of spontaneous generation and decline?
In my view, the perception that entrepreneurship has a disturbing
tendency to dry up unexpectedly or to spring forth unexpectedly, like
Athena from the head of Zeus, stems from a basic misunderstanding. The
source of this misunderstanding is a propensity to equate
entrepreneurship with virtuous behavior. Because we recognize that
entrepreneurship can bring innovation and growth, we are misled into
thinking that it must always contribute to economic abundance and
expansion. But there is no reason why this must be so, and it patently
is not true in reality.
First, one must recognize that the class of individuals who
constitute the economy's entrepreneurs are not selected to be,
uniformly, a collection of do-gooders. Like professors or lawyers or
doctors or any other profession, the strength of their dedication to
morality will vary from one such individual to another. It is, indeed, a
plausible hypothesis that the typical entrepreneur has a tendency toward
amorality in his professional activities, neither accepting major
sacrifices on behalf of the general welfare nor deliberately seeking to
damage it. The entrepreneur's goal is acquisition and accumulation
of wealth, power and prestige, with innovation used as a primary weapon
in pursuit of those objectives. If the entrepreneur's innovations
happen to yield social benefits, so much the better. But if those
benefits are questionable or even nonexistent, that need not put a stop
to the activities of the entrepreneur.
The point is that entrepreneurship, like any other input in the
economy, is an allocable resource, and pursuit of profit--the profit
motive--will determine where it will be allocated. However, one can be
innovative and enterprising in a variety of different ways. The gangster
"godfather" who invents a new instrument for extortion or the
warlord who invents a new military tactic to tighten his grip on his
domain are surely being entrepreneurial. These extreme examples are
chosen deliberately, to show how far the conventional notion of
entrepreneurship invites extension.
It is, of course, true that the U.S. economy has no warlords,
though it does have its godfathers. But consider what would happen if
something were to change the situation to one resembling that of the
Middle Ages. Then, as we know, the entrepreneurial innovators were the
unruly barons, who not only conducted continual warfare with one
another, but even with their kings, as in England in the reigns of
Stephen and Matilda, John, Henry III, Richard II, Henry VI and Richard
III. The point is that society's most enterprising individuals were
in these societies driven by their ambition to innovate aggression
rather than to production. It is not that the class of entrepreneurs had
vanished from those societies. Rather, the entrepreneurs were induced to
go where the most promising opportunities for enrichment and acquisition
of power were to be found. As the notorious thief, Willie Sutton, is
reported to have answered when asked why he robbed banks: "Because
that's where the money is."
All of this may (or may not) seem convincing, but largely
irrelevant, for the most pressing economic issues facing today's
society. But that is only because of the extreme examples that I have
used to dramatize my point. Today, criminal activity aside, the primary
type of effort that competes with production as an attraction to
entrepreneurs is something far less dramatic than military violence, but
nevertheless of critical importance. This alternative is rent-seeking,
that generalization of Henry George's focus--the pursuit of
earnings primarily through redistribution in one's own favor,
rather than in return for any productive accomplishment. The lawsuit is
a prime example of such an activity, and the number of firms that
participate in such activities is hardly negligible. Vast resources are
devoted to legal representatives of business firms in the courts, the
regulatory agencies and other such instrumentalities, whose job it is to
seek special economic advantages such as court-imposed protection from
disturbingly vigorous competition and direct enrichment through vast
court-ordered damage payments. Such unproductive activities can and
often are carried out in an innovative manner with full exercise of
entrepreneurial vigor. And it is easy to provide examples of firms that
participate in both types of activity--production and litigation. But
where the damage payment being sought in a lawsuit is (as I have more
than once experienced) equal to something like a decade of the
firm's usual profits, it is easy to imagine where primary attention
is given by the firm's decision makers.
As is well recognized, rent-seeking takes many forms beyond
litigative activity. There are, for example, such rent-seeking
activities as the pursuit of an exclusive license to operate a public
utility; lobbying in Congress; efforts to extend the life of patents by
means of inventions whose primary purpose is to exclude competition; and
many additional variants, all of which are pursued entrepreneurially,
with constant alertness for innovation opportunities. The recent
economic recession that made its appearance with the onset of the 21st
century drew attention to another widespread example, the corporate
(mis)management that pursues its own wealth at the expense of the
stockholders, offering the latter little or nothing in return. All of
these are examples of significant rent-seeking activity that redirects
entrepreneurial effort away from contributions to production, economic
growth and innovation.
The central point here is that the "rules of the
game"--by which I mean the structure of the economy's
payoffs--can and do change. And when these rules change they can
confidently be expected to modify the allocation of the economy's
entrepreneurs between production and rent-seeking. History readily
provides striking examples. Thus, during the reigns of the last
Plantagenets and the early Tudors, service to the King was a primary
source of income, privilege and, perhaps most critical, landed property.
As a result, the evidence indicates, economic activity by leading
subjects of the Crown was focused in this direction, with productive
investment by the magnates a very new phenomenon, following the
innovative example of Edward IV. And during the reign of the Stuarts,
when Parliament succeeded in circumscribing the rent-granting powers of
the monarch, it is arguable that the economy's entrepreneurs'
activities were redirected toward commerce and production, thereby
providing part of the explanation for the subsequent British economic
success in the European economy of the early 19th century.
What was true on those occasions remains true now. Entrepreneurs
can still be tempted to redirect their efforts by changes in the
structure of the payoffs that they seek. It is therefore important to
avoid governmental forms of intervention that end up providing
significant opportunities for rent-seeking, and important to foreclose the rentseeking opportunities that derive from other sources. Thus, I
maintain that the analysis that treats entrepreneurship as just another
allocable resource not only possesses explanatory power, but can also be
helpful for the design of policy.
The analysis also helps us to see why free-market economies are
characterized by so much greater an abundance of productive
entrepreneurship than was found in earlier societies. The rule of law,
along with rights of property and its protection from arbitrary
confiscation, the enforceability of contracts and a variety of other
protections have made productive activities less risky and more
effective avenues to wealth than they were before. This, along with some
closing down of rent-seeking opportunities and opportunities for
respectable wealth-acquisition through organized violence have
reallocated entrepreneurial effort in directions that contribute to
prosperity and growth. Entrepreneurship in the free market was not
created by mysterious means or by spontaneous generation--it was merely
redirected from what it had previously been doing. But the threat to
this development posed by the continuing opportunities for very
lucrative rent-acquisition continues, and constitutes an ever-present
peril for economic prosperity and growth.
2. Routinization of Innovation and the Alleged Shrinking of the
Entrepreneur Role
My research on entrepreneurship has continued since I first
formulated the preceding ideas (see Baumol, 1993), and the resulting
later observations are contained in my most recent book (2002). The
central topic of that later volume is the extraordinary growth record of
the free-market economies, and the reasons why no other form of economic
organization has come close to their productive and innovative
accomplishments over any protracted period of time. The relevance to the
discussion here should already be clear from the previous observations
on the attributes of the free-market economy that apparently have
contributed so substantially to the volume of productive entrepreneurial
activity. But there is much more to the story, in particular in the
drive toward routinization of innovation and its implications for
entrepreneurship. Thus, I turn now to Schumpeter's suggestion that
entrepreneurship is becoming obsolete because the innovation process is
now predominantly routinized and is now conducted chiefly by large
corporations under the guidance of their bureaucrats, whose orientation
is the very antithesis of free-wheeling, imaginative and somewhat
irrationally overenthusiastic entrepreneurs.
The story here, in brief, is that in the market economies the most
visible and active forms of competition are found in oligopolistic
industries, where the small number of rival firms' surveillance of
one another's activities is direct and where the actions of any one
enterprise in a market can be expected to elicit rivalrous responses
from the others. Directly relevant to our discussion here is the
important subsector of the group of oligopolistic industries that are
characterized as "high-tech" and that are responsible for the
bulk of innovative activities that take place within established firms.
For many of such firms innovation is not only important, it can be a
matter of life and death. No risk to such a firm is greater than the
peril of falling behind its rivals in attractive new products and
efficient new processes.
The resulting pressures have led those enterprises to take whatever
measures they can to minimize their risk of falling behind rivals in the
innovation "arms race" that characterizes the industry. To do
so, they have, as far as they could, taken the innovative activities on
which they depend out of the hands of the independent inventors and
entrepreneurs, and brought them inside the firm, into business operated
and controlled R&D facilities.
This is the sense in which innovative activity has indeed grown
more routine and, according to government statistics, more than half of
business R&D expenditure (which itself is some 70 percent of total
U.S. R&D spending) is now provided by large firms. The activity, as
carried out by private businesses, has become routine in many ways. Its
budget is determined centrally, in competition with the firm's
expenditures on all of its other major activities such as advertising
and plant construction. The firm's management may select its
R&D subsidiary's organizational structure, decide on its
facilities and even, in a surprising number of cases, it will decide
what should be invented. One recent example is the announcement by
Microsoft Corporation that its computer software R&D efforts are
about to be redirected from the addition of new working features in the
software programs to increases in computer users' security against
the invasion of viruses, as well as improved confidentiality of what is
written and saved on users' computers. This presumably will be a
centrally directed reorientation of the activities of the firm's
R&D personnel, and it is a pattern that is to be encountered
throughout industrial research. This is a far cry from the inspired and
unorthodox efforts of the inventors of legend, toiling in attic and
basement to come up with a working version of an invention that exists
initially only in the inventor's mind, or the work of the savvy
entrepreneur whose alertness enables her to observe the existence or
prospect of this invention and whose efforts are designed to see it to
completion, all the way to the marketplace.
But this has been the direction of the large business firms, whose
routinized innovation activities have tended to follow relatively
predictable goals. These more systematic and orderly innovative efforts
have been slanted toward incremental improvements rather than
revolutionary breakthroughs. User friendliness, increased reliability,
marginal additions to application, expansions of capacity, flexibility
in design, these and many other types of improvement have come out of
the industrial R&D facilities, with impressive consistency, year
after year, and often pre-announced and pre-advertised. As one member of
the top management of a large high-tech firm commented recently:
"In established businesses, innovation is mostly shaped through
small incremental steps of additional features to augment basic
functionalities. With short product lifecycles, time to recoup R&D
investments is limited ... Success is relatively predictable through the
execution of well-defined innovation processes . . ." (Dr. A.
Huijser, Executive Vice President and Chief Technology Officer, Royal
Phillips Electronics, EFACT Conference Announcement, "Innovation
Day: Source of Prosperity," Tilburg, The Netherlands, September
2003, p. 19).
The large and growing share of R&D expenditure accounted for by
the large, bureaucratically-governed enterprises naturally leads to the
conjecture, voiced by Schumpeter, that the work responsibilities the
economy assigns to the entrepreneur are narrowing and are destined to
shrink even further. One can easily surmise what prompted him to foresee
a limited future for the entrepreneur where industry and its innovation
processes are widely characterized in the manner just described. Yet, I
will argue next that this is fundamentally a mischaracterization. Rather
than being condemned to obsolescence, a vital role continues to be
played by independent entrepreneurs.
3. Revolutionary Breakthroughs as Entrepreneurial Specialty
The routinization story by itself is surely an exaggeration.
Neither the independent innovator nor the independent entrepreneur has
vanished from the face of the earth. On the contrary, they are alive and
well and appear to be as active and productive as ever. There are lists
of the important innovative breakthroughs of the 20th century and a
substantial number of these breakthroughs, if not the majority, turn out
to be derived from these sources rather than from the laboratories of
giant business enterprises. Of course, once they become successful, the
individuals involved typically organize themselves into business firms
(think of Xerox, Polaroid, Hewlett-Packard, or Apple Computer, to name
just a few), and those firms, in turn, often redirect themselves to
routinization of their innovation activities. But they, in their turn,
are followed by still other entrepreneurs and inventors, and the process
goes on, bringing ever more new products and new processes to the
economy.
To explore the point further, it is convenient here to divide up
inventions with the aid of two polar categories: revolutionary
breakthroughs and cumulative incremental improvements. Of course, many
new products and processes fall into neither extreme category, but are
somewhere in-between. Still, it will become clear that the distinction
is useful. Moreover, there are many examples that clearly fit into one
of these categories or the other quite easily. For instance, the
electric light, alternating electric current, the internal combustion
engine, and a host of other advances must surely be deemed
revolutionary, while successive models of washing machines and
refrigerators--with each new model a bit longer-lasting, a bit less
susceptible to breakdown, and a bit easier to use---constitute a
sequence of incremental improvements.
The relevance of the distinction should be evident, given what has
been said about the working and organization of R&D in the large
business organization. The inherent conservatism of the process
naturally leads to the expectation that these firms will tend to
specialize in the incremental improvements and tend to avoid the risks
of the unknown that the revolutionary breakthrough entails. The latter,
rather, is left most often to the small or newly founded enterprise,
guided by its enterprising entrepreneur.
Though that is to be expected, the degree of asymmetry in the
apportionment of this specialized activity between large and small firms
in reality is striking. The U.S. Small Business Administration (1995)
has prepared a chart listing breakthrough innovations of the twentieth
century for which small firms are responsible, and its menu of
inventions literally spans the range from A to Z, from the airplane to
the zipper. This remarkable list includes a strikingly substantial share
of the technical breakthroughs of the twentieth century. Besides the
airplane, it lists FM radio, the helicopter, the personal computer, and
the pacemaker, among a host of others, many of enormous significance for
our economy.
A very recent study, also sponsored by the U.S. Small Business
Administration (2003), provides more-systematic and powerful evidence to
similar effect. (1) This report examines technical change through
patenting and it defines "small firms" as "businesses
with fewer than 500 employees." (2) Perhaps most notably, the study
finds that "... a small firm patent is more likely than a large
firm patent to be among the top 1 percent of most frequently cited
patents." Among other conclusions, in the words of its authors,
this study reports that,
"Small firms represent one-third of the most
prolific patenting companies that have 15 or
more U.S. patents.
Small firm innovation is twice as closely
linked to scientific research as large firm
innovation on average, and so is substantially
more high-tech or leading edge.
Small firms are more effective in producing
high-value innovations--the citation index
for small firm patents averaged 1.53 compared
to 1.19 for large firms.
Small patenting firms are roughly 13 times
more innovative per employee than large
patenting firms.
A small firm patent is at least twice as likely
to be found among the top 1 percent of highest-impact
patents as a patent from a large
firm" (p. 2).
One is, then, led to the plausible observation that most of the
revolutionary new ideas of the past two centuries have been, and are
likely to continue to be, provided more heavily by independent
innovators who, essentially, operate small business enterprises.
Evidently, the small entrepreneurial firms have come close to
monopolizing the portion of R&D activity that is engaged in the
search for revolutionary breakthroughs.
4. Digression: The Critical Contribution of Large-Firm R&D
But now we seem to have leapt to the opposite conclusion, that
rather than the likely disappearance of the innovative role of the
entrepreneur and the small firm, little would appear to be left for the
large enterprise to do. That is, one is tempted to draw from this
description the conclusion that the lone inventors and the entrepreneurs
are the clear winners as prime contributors to economic growth and
standards of living. But, without in any way seeking to denigrate their
enormous contribution, it is nevertheless appropriate to reconsider what
the routine innovative activities have accomplished. And indeed, it is
possible to argue that though the routinized outputs of the large firms
have often been less dramatic, if one takes the incremental
contributions together and sums their accomplishments, one comes away
with the judgment that their accomplishment is not comparatively
minuscule. Indeed, there are many cases in which the summed incremental
contributions plainly outperform the contribution of the original
breakthrough. A very clear example is the electronic computer. The first
computer obviously constituted a revolutionary breakthrough in concept.
But, as has often been done, we can easily compare its speed, computing
capacity and memory with what is available today in instruments with
tiny fractions of the earliest instruments' bulk and weight and a
spectacular reduction in cost. We realize quickly that a fairly low-end
personal computer today can outperform the original in each of these
attributes by a vast multiple, and with far greater reliability,
user-friendliness and range of applications. Accordingly, the bulk of
the speed, computing power and memory capacity of today's computers
is probably attributable to the combined incremental additions made by
routine research activities in corporate facilities. Other careful
observers have extended such examples and have concluded that
incremental and routinized innovation activities have been responsible
for a very respectable share of the contribution of innovation to
economic growth in the 20th century.
Yet there is something misleading about such a comparison, because
it casts the innovative activity in the large firms and that of the
independent innovative in the role of rivals, as producers of substitute
products, each vying for victory over the other. It seems clear that
this is not generally what has happened. Rather, there has tended to be
specialization, with the outputs of the two groups tending to be
complementary rather than rivalrous. More than that, there is a tendency
toward serendipity between the two, with each facilitating and
supplementing the work of the other. The nature of the specialization is
suggested by the preceding discussion. The independent inventor and his
entrepreneur partner have tended to be those who produced the radical
departures from then-current products and processes. The big novel idea,
the unprecedented way of thinking, the heterodox approach, has been
disproportionately in their hands. But using these breakthroughs as
their raw materials, the groups specializing in routinized innovation
have taken over and gone on with the task of transforming the
breakthrough models into more easily usable, more powerful and more
marketable products, raising them from infancy into mature products with
substantial markets and massive outputs. Thus, the result has arguably been superadditive, with the total contribution to the economy's
productive powers greater than the sum of the contributions for which
each was individually responsible.
The firms' acquisition, typically via purchase, of the
original inventions from the unaffiliated inventors and entrepreneurs
have contributed compensation to the latter, thereby encouraging their
activity. Moreover, the inventors have often learned from the less
spectacular discoveries in the industrial labs and this has aided them
in their subsequent work. The other side of the matter is the fact that
the initial breakthrough has so often served as the vital ingredient in
the work of improvement that was subsequently undertaken by routinized
innovation activity. Thus, albeit not perfectly clean-cut, there has
been specialization, with considerable benefits to both parties and the
economy has been better off as a result.
More than that, it follows that the growth of routinization in the
innovation process has not threatened the entrepreneur with
obsolescence. The entrepreneur seems in no danger of disappearance or of
being' deprived of a market for his or her activities. In this
respect, Schumpeter's remark on the growth of routinization, while
not incorrect, is at least somewhat misleading.
To summarize, these developments have evolved in a way that appears
to fall into a pattern. Rather than serving primarily as substitutes,
the continuing contributions to economic growth of the entrepreneurs and
inventors have followed a direction rather different from the routinized
activities of the large firm's innovating personnel. In the larger
firms, innovative activities are carefully designed to prevent unwelcome
surprises and to keep risks to a minimum. As a result, there is little
of the freewheeling, imaginative, and risk-taking approach that
characterizes the work of the entrepreneur, but the incremental and
cumulative improvements, many unimpressive by themselves, often add up
to important and substantial contributions.
On the other hand, if we look at any of the lists of the primary
conceptual breakthroughs of the 20th century--those great leaps forward
in unanticipated directions--we see that an impressive proportion of
them have stemmed from the independent entrepreneurial sector, as has
just been said. It is the unaffiliated inventors and entrepreneurs who
have tended to be the suppliers of the dramatic breakthroughs, the ones
that deservedly receive the most attention and are most widely
recognized and remembered. Their work is a necessary ingredient of the
growth process.
5. The Bottom Line: Rent-Seeking Is a Critical Threat to Growth
Entrepreneurship is widely accepted as a vital activity, an
activity without understanding of which the market economy's
workings really cannot be comprehended. But my earlier discussion has
shown how readily the prospects of rent earnings can lure entrepreneurs
away from their productive activities. One may well argue that the poor
record of technological progress in ancient Rome, Medieval China and the
more recent Soviet Union, despite the many impressive inventions that
each of them was able to generate, is attributable in good part to the
ready availability of rent-earning opportunities. This, together with
the obstacles to earning of profit and respectability through productive
entrepreneurship in those economies, arguably go far in accounting for
the failure to put their remarkable inventions to productive use.
For us, the immediately most important Henry George insight is that
rents in the broader sense are still widely available in the free-market
economies. There is good reason to believe that pursuit of those rents
occupies many capable and imaginative members of their societies,
thereby handicapping prosperity, growth, and their contribution to the
elimination of poverty. The conclusion is that vigilance will be
required to prevent expansion and facilitation of rent-earning
opportunities and rent-seeking activities. For that is a development
that will predictably siphon off the entrepreneurs from their vital
contribution to economic growth and innovation, misallocating them into
pursuit of rent rather than promotion of progress.
Notes
(1.) Quoting the press release describing the study, "A total
of 1,071 Srms with 15 or more patents issued between 1996 and 2000 were
examined.
A total of 193,976 patents were analyzed. CHI [the firm that
carried out the study] created a database of these firms and their
patents. This list excluded foreign-owned firms, universities,
government laboratories, and nonprofit institutions" (p. 2).
(2.) It may strike the reader that a firm with 500 employees is not
particularly small. However, in terms of R&D spending in the U.S.,
the choice of that number is not inappropriate. In 2000 in the U.S., 46
percent of total business R&D spending was by 167 firms that each
had more than 25,000 employees. Eighty-one percent of the total was
spent by 1,990 firms that each had more than 1,000 employees, while
32,000 R&D-performing firms with less than 500 employees accounted
only for 15 percent of total R&D spending by business (National
Science Board, 2000, chapter 2, p. 24).
References
Baumol, William J., Entrepreneurship, Management and the Structure
of Payoffs, Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1993.
--, The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth
Miracle of Capitalism, Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2002.
Economic Report of the President, January 2001, Washington, D.C.:
U.S. Government Printing Office, 2001.
George, Henry, Progress and Poverty, New York, 1879 (1992).
Horrox, Rosemary, Richard 111: A Study of Service, Cambridge,
United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press, 1989.
National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators 2000,
Arlington, Virginia: National Science Foundation, 2000.
Schumpeter, Joseph A., The Theory of Economic Development,
Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1934.
--, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, New York: Harper and
Brothers, 1942. U.S. Small Business Administration, The State of Small
Business: A Report of the President, 1994, Washington, D.C.: U.S.
Government Printing Office, 1995.
William J. Baumol, Professor of economics, New York University; and
senior research economist and professor emeritus, Princeton University.