The strategic use of convertible debt in "deep pocket" predatory games.
Gottesman, Aron A.
1. Introduction
The purpose of this study is to extend Poitevin (1989) to
demonstrate that noncallable convertible debt can be used to avoid
predation by an incumbent firm against an entrant in a "deep
pocket" predatory game. The deep pocket argument, which was first
described by McGee (1958), Telser (1966), and later by Benoit (1984), is
used to explain evidence that young firms are more vulnerable to
bankruptcy than older firms. For example, over 40% of U.S. firms that
went bankrupt in 1997 were less than five years old, while over 66% were
less than 10 years old (Dun and Bradstreet, 1998). The deep pocket
argument states that since the incumbent has greater financial resources
(a "deeper pocket") than the entrant, the incumbent is able to
exhaust the entrant financially through engaging in predatory pricing,
thereby forcing the entrant to leave the market. Predatory pricing
refers to the practice of introducing a lower priced, higher quality, or
more innovative product in direct competition with a rival after it
enters the market.
However, it is not immediately clear why the incumbent has greater
financial resources than the entrant. Telser (1966) and Benoit (1984)
simply assume the entrant is financially vulnerable and unable to
sustain a price war. A number of authors provide explanations as to why
the entrant is more vulnerable. Fudenberg and Tirole (1986) argue that
since the entrant does not have a history of cashflow generation, the
entrant finds it difficult to find equity investors. Therefore, the
entrant must borrow to finance its operations, and must satisfy interest
payments requirements. Conversely, the incumbent has a record of
cashflow generation and is able to acquire equity investment resulting
in lower interest payment requirements. The incumbent is, therefore,
able to engage in a price war, as it does not have as large an interest
obligation to satisfy.
Williamson (1974) argues that an incumbent has lower financing
costs due to its lower risk. The lower risk is due to its existing
history of cashflows. Since the entrant is a riskier investment, it must
pay a higher interest rate. Therefore, even if both firms have the same
financial structure, the incumbent is able to lower prices more
aggressively due to the lower interest requirement it faces.
Poitevin (1989) formalizes the deep pocket argument using a game in
which the riskiness of the entrant's debt is revealed through a
separating equilibrium. Debt acts as a signal of quality to investors,
allowing the entrant to receive the same interest rate as the incumbent.
However, the higher level of debt and the associated cashflow
requirements leave the entrant vulnerable to predation on the part of
the incumbent. Hence, the incumbent's reputation permits a flexible
financial structure, while the entrant's lack of reputation forces
it to use its financial structure as a signal, causing predation.
Fulghieri and Nagarajan (1996) also consider the strategic implications
of financial structure on "deep pocket" games. However, they
develop their model in the context of Benoit (1984), with the same
unsatisfying assumption that the incumbent is financially stronger.
The model developed in this study extends Poitevin (1989) to
demonstrate that convertible debt can be used advantageously in the
context of deep pocket predatory games. Through strategically choosing
convertible debt with a specific conversion ratio, an entrant may be
able to avoid predation while revealing its quality type through a
separating equilibrium. The key difference between the model developed
in this study and Poitevin (1989) is that this model allows the firm to
issue convertible debt, while the model in Poitevin (1989) does not.
Finance literature provides a number of theoretical rationales to
explain why firms issue convertible debt. Kim (1990) argues that the
conversion ratio provides a signal to the market of management's
expectations of future performance. Jensen and Meckling (1976),
Mikkelson (1978), and Green (1984) argue that convertible debt can be
used to protect bondholders against the opportunistic behavior of
shareholders. Brennan and Schwartz (1988) argue that convertible
debt's hybrid nature makes it easier for creditors and debtors to
negotiate the value of the debt when there is disagreement about the
riskiness of the company. Constantinides and Grundy (1989) discuss the
use of convertible debt to overcome problems associated with asymmetric
information.
This study is in the spirit of the delayed equity argument first
proposed by Brigham (1966) and Hoffmeister (1977). Janjigian (1987)
provides empirical support for this argument, and Stein's (1992)
backdoor equity model is a recent variant of this explanation. Stein
argues that when adverse selection causes equity issues to be untenable
and there is a high cost associated with financial distress, managers
have an incentive to issue convertible debt. In Stein's model, a
medium quality firm will not issue equity, to avoid issuing underpriced equity. At the same time, the medium quality firm will not issue
straight debt, to avoid financial distress costs. Instead, the medium
quality firm will issue convertible debt to avoid equity issue until
quality is determined. Once quality is determined, the medium firm will
force conversion through threatening to call. Davidson, Glascock and
Schwarz (1995) provide empirical support of Stein (1992) and Kim (1990).
Lewis, Rogalski and Seward (1999) find that the reaction to new
convertible debt issues depends on whether investors believe that risk
shifting or backdoor equity motivates the choice of convertible debt.
The basic argument of this study is as follows. Following Fudenberg
and Tirole (1986), Williamson (1974), and Poitevin (1989), the
fundamental difference between the incumbent and the entrant is that the
market knows the incumbent's quality, while the entrant's
quality is unknown. Therefore, the entrant must use debt to overcome
informational asymmetries in financial markets. In particular, the firm
has information on its cost type not known to the market. Debt issued by
the entrant causes predation on the part of the incumbent monopolist, as
the incumbent is willing to sacrifice short term cashflows to receive
the reward of the entrant's bankruptcy. Using convertible debt with
a conversion ratio by which creditors have an incentive to convert only
if the entrant is a low cost producer, the entrant is able to avoid
predation while overcoming informational asymmetries. Note, however,
that the entrant's ability to use of convertible debt to avoid
predatory pricing requires the satisfaction of several conditions, as
detailed in the model. Without the satisfaction of these conditions
predation can occur. Hence, this model does not universally negate the
occurrence of predatory pricing, in the context of the deep pocket
predatory game described by Poitevin (1989), even if hybrid financial
securities are available.
This study differs from Stein (1992) as revelation of quality alone
motivates conversion, while in Stein's model a call feature is
required to force conversion. However, convertible bonds are often
noncallable for a significant period of time following the issue. Hence,
this model broadens the relevance of the backdoor equity argument to
situations in which the bond is noncallable. It suggests that in a
concentrated market, voluntary conversion can take place without a call
feature.
Besides extending the convertible debt literature, this model also
suggests that the product market competition literature cannot continue
to assume that hybrid financial securities do not exist. Instead, future
research, both empirical and theoretical, should recognize that firms
can choose from non-traditional securities to avoid predation.
The structure of the rest of this paper is as follows. The model
and notation are described in Section 2. The stages of the game and the
solution are described in Section 3. This is followed by a discussion in
Section 4. Section 5 concludes the paper.
2. Model and notation
The formalism of the model is similar to Poitevin (1989). All
parties are risk neutral, and management's objective is to maximize
shareholder value. Assume that only one entrant wishes to enter the
market. Let e refer to the entrant and i refer to the monopoly
incumbent. Throughout, any notation defined for e is similarly defined
for i unless otherwise stated.
Both the incumbent and entrant produce the same product and face
the same fixed production cost, K. There are two types of marginal
costs, high ([c.sub.H]) or low ([c.sub.L]), for each unit produced. For
the incumbent firm, the marginal cost is common knowledge as low. The
entrant's marginal cost is unknown to the market. The prior
probability distribution for the entrant's marginal costs is
characterized by equally likely occurrence of [c.sub.H] and [c.sub.L].
The aggregate output of the industry is Q, and P(Q) is the inverse market demand. Further, Q = [q.sub.e] + [q.sub.i], where [q.sub.e]
represents the output of firm e. Assume the price function is linear.
Operating cashflow includes stochastic and nonstochastic elements.
The stochastic component of operating cashflows, [a.sub.e], is random
and independent of the other choices or market variables. The support of
[a.sub.e] is A = [[a.sub.0], [a.sub.1]] and its cumulative distribution
is F([a.sub.e]). For algebraic convenience, assume F(a) is uniform. The
nonstochastic element of operating cashflow is the quantity produced
multiplied by the difference between the price and marginal cost of each
product. Define the ex-post operating cashflow as
(1) S([a.sub.e],[q.sub.e],[c.sub.e],[q.sub.i]):= P(Q)[q.sub.e] -
[c.sub.e][q.sub.e] + [a.sub.e] [for all] [a.sub.e] [member of] A
for which [a.sub.e] has been observed. Profitability is a function
of the stochastic component of operating cashflows. Hence, a high cost
entrant is willing to enter the market when the incumbent is known as
low cost, as the stochastic component ensures that there is some
probability of a high cost entrant not being forced into bankruptcy.
This formulation is based on Poitevin (1989).
Each firm is assumed to have existing equity shareholders. Each
firm chooses its capital structure following the entrant's decision
to enter the market. Cash is required to finance costs associated with
production. All debtholders invest at the beginning of the period and
receive their principal and interest at the end of the period. For
simplicity, assume the risk free rate of interest is zero.
The variable [x.sub.e] represents the percentage of shares into
which e's debt can be converted. For example, If [x.sub.e] = 0.5,
then following conversion the original equityholders own 1/(1+0.5) = 2/3
of the firm and the new equityholders own 0.5/(1+0.5) = 1/3 of the firm.
If the debt is nonconvertible, then x = 0. The variable [x.sub.e] can
range from zero to infinity. To relate [x.sub.e] to the conversion
ratio, note that the conversion ratio represents the number of shares
received upon conversion. Hence, the associated conversion ratio is
equivalent to [x.sub.e] multiplied by the number of shares currently
outstanding. The principal of the debt that firm e borrows at interest
rate [r.sub.e] is [D.sub.e]. Debt broadly refers to all types of
liabilities, including obligations to suppliers. [E.sub.e] represents
the cash raised through equity investment in the firm, with
[N.sup.x.sub.e] and [N.sup.o.sub.e] representing the number of the
shares held by new and existing equityholders, respectively. Define
[t.sub.e] = ([D.sub.e],[x.sub.e],[r.sub.e],[E.sub.e],[N.sup.x.sub.e],[N.sup.o.sub.e]) as the financial policy of firm e.
While a firm's credit quality depends on its marginal cost
type, firm ability to repay its creditors will depend on the realized
level of stochastic cashflows. Define
S([[bar.a].sub.e],[q.sub.e],[c.sub.e],[q.sub.i]) as the level of
operating cashflow for which
(2) S([a.sub.e],[q.sub.e],[c.sub.e],[q.sub.i]) + [D.sub.e] +
[E.sub.e] - K = [D.sub.e](1 + [r.sub.e]).
The variable [[bar.a].sub.e] is the lowest level of stochastic
cashflow for which firm e can prevent default. Note that the term
"bankrupt" is not used to describe e's situation when
[a.sub.e] < [[bar.a].sub.e], as even if e is unable to satisfy its
interest payments using the cashflow it receives from production, it can
be bailed out by its creditors. The total monopoly cashflows earned by
firm e, if i is bankrupt and e is not, is B > 0.
[V.sub.e]([t.sub.e],[t.sub.i],[c.sub.e],[c.sub.i],[q.sub.e],[q.sub.i]) represents the expected value of the position held by the
shareholders of e. The expected value of the existing shareholders'
position is
(3) [[PI].sub.e]([t.sub.e],[t.sub.i],[c.sub.e],[c.sub.i],[q.sub.e],[q.sub.i]) = [N.sup.o.sub.e]/[N.sup.x.sub.e] + [N.sup.o.sub.e]
[V.sub.e]([t.sub.e],[t.sub.i],[c.sub.e],[c.sub.i],[q.sub.e],[q.sub.i])
The expected value of the new shareholders' position is
(4) [[PHI].sub.e]([t.sub.e],[t.sub.i],[c.sub.e],[c.sub.i],[q.sub.e],[q.sub.i]) = [N.sup.o.sub.e]/[N.sup.x.sub.e] + [N.sup.o.sub.e]
[V.sub.e]([t.sub.e],[t.sub.i],[c.sub.e],[c.sub.i],[q.sub.e],[q.sub.i])
It follows [V.sub.e] = [[PI].sub.e] + [[PHI].sub.e]. Finally, note
that [[rho].sub.e]([t.sub.e],[t.sub.i],[c.sub.e],[c.sub.i],[q.sub.e],[q.sub.i]) is the expected value of the creditors' position.
3. The game and solution
The game is multistaged and nonrepeated. There are two major stages
to the game, the financing stage and the output stage. As the game
begins, the marginal cost of the entrant is unknown to the market. The
management of the entrant privately believes that the firm is a low cost
producer. The marginal cost of the incumbent firm is observed in the
market as low.
In the financing stage, the capital structure of each firm is
determined. The entrant decides which financial policy to propose to
investors. A financial policy specifies both the leverage ratio and
conversion ratio. The investors decide whether to accept the financial
policy proposed by the entrant. Only a low cost entrant receives
financing. Hence, if the proposed financial policy signals that the
entrant is low cost financing is provided. Otherwise, investors choose
not to accept the financial policy, and the incumbent continues to
receive monopoly profits. The financing stage ends with the incumbent
choosing its financial policy as well.
The output stage of the game begins with the revelation of the
entrant's cost type. Following this revelation, the convertible
debtholders decide whether to convert at the specified conversion ratio.
Next, the two firms simultaneously choose the level of output to
produce. Quantities are determined through solving for the Cournot-Nash
equilibrium.
After production, the firm must repay all of the cash it borrows
plus interest. The stochastic portion of cashflows is privately revealed
to the firm and its creditor. Based on this information, the firm and
its creditors privately know whether the firm will default. Creditors
must therefore decide whether to provide additional credit if default is
imminent. After this decision is made, the stochastic portion of
cashflows is revealed publicly. If one firm is bankrupt and the other
firm is not, the firm that has not gone bankrupt receives monopoly
cashflows. Figure 1 illustrates the sequence of moves and revelations.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The game is solved using backward induction; hence we first solve
the output stage and subsequently solve the financing stage. Kreps and
Wilson (1982) demonstrate that solving for the Nash equilibrium in every
stage using backward induction leads to a sequential equilibrium. For
each decision, we discuss each player's best strategy for every
possible situation the player is in due to previous realizations and
revelations.
Three decisions are made during the output stage. Convertible
debtholders decide whether to convert following the revelation of the
entrant's cost type. The firms next choose production quantities.
Following the revelation of stochastic cashflows, the creditors decide
whether to bailout the firm.
The decision to bailout is made in response to revelation of the
firm's stochastic cashflows. Both [a.sub.e] and [a.sub.i] are
revealed privately, and each firm's potential for default is
privately known. If the firm is facing default, i.e., if [a.sub.e] <
[[bar.a].sub.e], the creditors must either bailout the firm or allow the
fil-m to go bankrupt. Risk neutral investors are willing to invest some
amount to bailout the firm. The amount of bailout that investors are
willing to provide is equal to the probability of i's bankruptcy
multiplied by the expected value of the monopoly cashflows that flow to
e should bailout of e occur. The expected value of these monopoly
cashflows is conditional on e not going bankrupt, as the bailout
eliminates any chance of e going bankrupt. Following Poitevin (1989),
Define [[??].sub.e] as the level of a for which
(5) S([[??].sub.e],[q.sub.e],[c.sub.e],[q.sub.i],) + [D.sub.e] +
[E.sub.e] - K + F([[??].sub.i])B = [D.sub.e](1 + [r.sub.e])
where F([[??].sub.i]) represents the probability of i's
bankruptcy, and F([[??].sub.i])B represents the amount of bailout that
investors are willing to provide to e. The right hand side of equation
(5) represents the debt obligation of firm e, while the left hand side
represents the total cash, including bailout, from which e pays its debt
obligation. The creditors are effectively investing in the expected
value of future bankruptcy cashflows.
If [a.sub.e] < [[??].sub.e], the creditors will not bailout the
firm, as the expected payoff from the bailout investment is zero.
Therefore, divide A into two possible subintervals:
[[a.sub.0],[[??].sub.e]) and ([a.sub.0],[[??].sub.1]]. If [a.sub.e] is
in the subinterval ([[??].sub.e],[a.sub.1]] then [a.sub.e] >
[[??].sub.e], and the creditors expect to receive [D.sub.e]
(1+[r.sub.e]). If [[??].sub.e] is in the subinterval
[[a.sub.0],[[??].sub.e]) then [a.sub.e] < [[??].sub.e], and the
creditors expect to receive the remaining assets of the firm.
The objective function satisfied by each firm, and stated here for
e, is
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
for which
(7) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Note that if e's creditors convert their debt in an earlier
stage, then [D.sub.e] = 0 in this context.
Quantities are chosen in Cournot-Nash equilibrium. Noting equation
(5), the first order condition for firm e is
(8) [differential]/[differential][q.sub.e][V.sub.e]([t.sub.e],[c.sub.e]) = P'(Q)[q.sub.e] + P(Q) - [c.sub.e] + f([[??].sub.i])
d[[??].sub.i]/d[q.sub.e] B = 0.
As Poitevin notes, d[[??].sub.i]/d[q.sub.e] B =
-P'(Q)[q.sub.i] [less than or equal to] 0 and
d[[??].sub.e]/d[.sub.e] = 0. The second order condition is 2P'(Q)
< O.
The first and second order conditions for i are identical to those
for e. The first order conditions, acting as reaction functions for the
two firms, are solved for the Cournot-Nash equilibrium levels of
[q.sub.e] and [q.sub.i], notated [q.sup.*.sub.e] and [q.sup.*.sub.i].
If i has 100% equity in its capital structure there is no
possibility of bankruptcy, and therefore d[[??].sub.i]/d[q.sub.e] = 0
and F([[??].sub.i]) = 0. Observing equation (8), it is apparent that the
expression f([[??].sub.i]) d[[??].sub.i]/d[q.sub.e]B is only nonzero when i has a capital structure consisting of a combination of debt and
equity. This implies that firm e produces more when i uses a combination
of debt and equity than when i is fully equity financed. This excess
production is the predatory effect: in equilibrium, a firm practicing
predation increases the probability of receiving monopoly profits
through producing a greater quantity than it would otherwise.
Three additional inferences can be drawn from equation (8). First,
the reaction function is a positive function of B. This suggests that
the firm's willingness to engage in predation is a positive
function of the potential bankruptcy profits. Second, the influence of
the additional debt on quantities is unrelated to the specific level of
debt, D. This is due to the assumption of uniform distribution. Hence,
any level of debt causes the predatory effect. Third, the level of
production through which predation is achieved, includes the predation
effect regardless as to whether the cost type of the entrant is revealed
as high or low. Hence, the model permits the possibility of predation
against both high and low cost rivals.
The creditors' conversion decision follows the revelation of
the entrant's marginal costs. The payoff to e's creditors is
(9) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Define [t.sup.DE.sub.e] and [t.sup.E.sub.e] as financial policies
consisting of debt and equity and equity alone, respectively. Consider a
situation in which the marginal cost type of the entrant is revealed as
low. In this case, the creditors will be indifferent about converting
their debt at a certain level of [x.sub.e], [[??].sub.e], such that
(10) [[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L]) = [[??].sub.e]/1 +
[x.sub.e] [V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[C.sub.L]).
Hence, [x.sub.e] < [[??].sub.e] the creditors will not convert
and vice versa. Solving for [[??].sub.e], it follows
(11) [[??].sub.e] = [[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[C.sub.L]/
[V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L]) -
[[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L]
When the marginal cost type is high a similar [x.sub.e],
[[??].sub.e], can be defined. Clearly, the firm can determine whether
conversion will take place through specification of [x.sub.e] and
[D.sub.e], implicit in [t.sup.DE.sub.e]. Generally, the higher the
specification of [x.sub.e] and the lower the specification of [D.sub.e],
the more likely conversion will take place. Hence, the choice of
conversion ratio and leverage ratio, given the firm's private
knowledge of its cost type, dictates whether conversion will take place
in the future.
Note that when [x.sub.e] > [x.sub.e] (when [c.sub.e] =
[c.sub.L]) or [x.sub.e] > [[??].sub.e] (when [c.sub.e] = [c.sub.H]),
conversion will occur, regardless of whether there is a later
opportunity to convert. This is because the conversion, in itself,
increases the expected future value of the firm through eliminating the
debt in the capital structure. As demonstrated earlier, debt in a
firm's capital structure leads to predation on the part of the
rival firm. The decision to convert has two immediate effects. First, it
converts the debt position into an equity position. Second, it
eliminates the threat of predation. These two effects are interrelated.
A decision to convert increases the value of the equity position through
eliminating the predation threat. In turn, the increased equity value
provides the convertible debtholder motivation to convert.
The observation that conversion eliminates the predation effect
dictates that the convertible debt does not have to be callable for
conversion to take place. The benefits of conversion flow to both the
existing equityholders and the convertible debtholders. Failure to
convert results in lower cashflow to the firm, which, in turn, results
in diminished ability to repay liabilities, and the inability to earn
the otherwise higher cashflow flowing to an equityholder not facing
predation.
We next solve the financing stage. Three decisions are made during
this stage. The entrant decides which financial policy to propose to
investors. The investors decide whether to accept the financial policy
proposed by the entrant. The incumbent then chooses its capital
structure. The entrant and incumbent follow different objectives when
choosing their financial policies. Each considers the impact of the
financial policy on its cashflow. However, the entrant also recognizes
that investors use the financial policy as a signal of its marginal cost
type, and true value. Since investors are only willing to invest if the
entrant is low cost, the entrant must signal.
The incumbent's choice of capital structure in this model is
identical to the incumbent's choice in Poitevin (1989). In
proposition (1), Poitevin demonstrates that the incumbent's
dominant strategy is to finance entirely using equity. While Poitevin
provides a formal proof, the intuitive explanation is as follows. As
demonstrated, the use of debt has potential benefit and cost. The
benefit, in the context of this model, is that the use of leverage sends
a signal of quality to the market. The cost is that the rival firm
engages in predation. Since the incumbent firm has no need to signal
quality, there is no benefit to the use of debt, and a full equity
policy is optimal. The entrant, on the other hand, has an uncertain cost
type, and therefore must signal quality to investors through its choice
of financial policy.
The entrant's financial policy specifies the levels of
[D.sub.e] and [x.sub.e]. We consider each in turn.
3.1. Specification of [D.sub.e]
The debt level is chosen such that only a low cost firm will use
debt. Define
(12) [[PI].sup.*.sub.e]([t.sub.e],[C.sub.e] =
[[PI].sup.*.sub.e]([t.sub.e],[t.sub.i],[c.sub.e],[c.sub.i],[q.sup.*.sub.e] ([c.sub.i],[t.sub.e],[t.sub.i],[q.sup.*.sub.e]))
as the value of the existing shareholders' position when
product price levels are chosen to maximize shareholder value. Similarly
define [[rho].sup.*.sub.e]([t.sub.e],[c.sub.e]) and
[[PHI].sup.*.sub.e]([t.sub.e],[c.sub.e]). A low cost firm wishing to
signal will choose a financial policy that will bankrupt a high cost
firm with certainty. Following Poitevin (1989), the problem to be solved
is
(13) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The value [[PI].sup.*]([t.sub.e],[c.sub.L]) is the value of a low
cost firm that has chosen a suboptimal level of debt, due to signaling
considerations. The first constraint ensures that a high cost firm is
bankrupt with probability equal to one should it attempt to take on the
debt level specified in the solution. A firm with an uncertain cost type
does not receive financing. Hence, management uses the debt to permit
financing.
To ensure that only a low cost firm uses debt, i.e., to satisfy the
constraint [[PI].sup.*]([t.sub.e],[c.sub.H]) [less than or equal to] 0,
a debt level is selected such that firm e will go bankrupt with
probability equal to one if the firm is a high cost firm and conversion
does not take place. Formally, the condition is stated as
(14) S([a.sub.1],[q.sup.*.sub.e],[c.sub.H],[q.sup.*.sub.i]) +
[D.sub.e] + [E.sub.e] - K < [D.sub.e](1 + [r.sub.e]).
The above condition states that at even the highest possible level
of stochastic cashflow, [a.sub.1], a high cost firm will not have enough
cash to satisfy its debt obligation. The key conclusion is that when a
firm's cost type is unknown to the market, a low cost firm can
signal its cost type through the level of debt it chooses. To signal
quality in order to receive financing, a firm that privately believes it
is low cost firm chooses a debt level such that bankruptcy is guaranteed
if it is a high cost firm. This level of debt is specified in equation
(14), and the low cost firm's ability to signal is conditional on
setting debt at this level. A high cost firm will never choose this debt
level, as bankruptcy is guaranteed. Hence, the high cost firm cannot
signal that it is a low cost firm, and therefore cannot receive
financing.
3.2. Specification of [x.sub.e]
The entrant will only use convertible debt when its use negates
predation while sustaining the intended quality signal. The convertible
debt will only negate predation if conversion takes place. As
demonstrated earlier, this will occur when x is specified such that
[x.sub.e] > [[??].sub.e] or [x.sub.e] > [[??].sub.e], depending on
the value of c. Hence, firm e can ensure conversion through
specification of [x.sub.e], given the specification of [D.sub.e] as
deemed in equation (14).
The convertible debt will sustain the intended quality signal if
conversion only takes place when the firm is a low cost firm. This
condition is satisfied through specifying such that
(15) [[??].sub.e] > [x.sub.e] > [[??].sub.e].
Recall that conversion takes place when [x.sub.e] > [[??].sub.e]
or [x.sub.e] > [[??].sub.e], depending on the value of [c.sub.e].
Hence, when [[??].sub.e] > [x[sections]e] > [[??].sub.e],
conversion will only take place if the firm is low cost, as [x.sub.e]
> [[??].sub.e]. Conversion will not take place if the firm is high
cost, as [x.sub.e] < [[??].sub.e]. Noncallability ensures that a high
cost firm does not force conversion when [x.sub.e] < [[??].sub.e].
The opportunity to select [[??].sub.e] > [x.sub.e] >
[[??].sub.e] depends on the existence of [[??].sub.e] > [[??].sub.e].
By definition of [[??].sub.e] and [[??].sub.e] (equation (11)),
[[??].sub.e] > [[??].sub.e] occurs when
(16) [[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.H]
/[V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.H]
-[[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.H]) >
[[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L]/[V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],
[c.sub.L] -[[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L])
It follows that [[??].sub.e] > [[??].sub.e] exists when
(17) 0 > [[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L][V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.H] -
[[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.H])[V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L])/ ([V.sub.e][t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L]) -
[[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L][V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.H] - [[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.H])
The denominator of the above expression is positive. Hence, the
relation exists when the numerator is less than zero. Rearranging the
numerator, it follows [[??].sub.e] > [[??].sub.e] will occur when
(18) [V.sub.e][t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L])/
[V.sub.e][t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.H]) >
[[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L]/[[rho].sub.e]
([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.H])
In words, [[??].sub.e] > [[??].sub.e] exists when the percentage
increase in value as [c.sub.e] shifts from [c.sub.H] to [c.sub.L] is
greater for [V.sub.e] than for [[rho].sub.e].
A cost associated with the use of convertible debt is that a low
cost firm wishes to retain as much of the risky stake for existing
shareholders as possible. The firm is, therefore, reluctant to
relinquish part of the stake through issuing convertible debt, and
prefers to use straight debt. However, note that when the use of
convertible debt negates predation and sustains the intended quality
signal, there exists [x.sub.e] such that the benefit to existing
shareholders from negating predation outweighs the cost associated with
issuing convertible debt. To demonstrate, observe that for the
shareholders of firm e, the benefits associated with negating predation
outweigh the costs when owning part of a debt-free firm is superior to
owning all of a leveraged Firm. Formally, shareholders prefer to use
convertible debt when
(19) 1/1 + [x.sub.e] [V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L]) >
[V.sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L])
Rearranging, it follows
(20) [V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L])/[V.sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L]) - 1 > [x.sub.e].
In words, shareholders prefer to use convertible debt when the
percentage increase in value due to the elimination of predation,
[V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L])/[V.sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L]), is greater than the percentage of equity sacrificed to offer the
conversion feature, x. Consider [x.sub.e] = [[??].sub.e]. Noting
equation (11), it follows from equation (20) that, when [x.sub.e] =
[[??].sub.e], shareholders prefer to use convertible debt when
(21) [V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L])
/[V.sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L]) - 1 >
[[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L])/
[V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L] -
[[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L]).
Rearranging, restate the above as
(22) [V.sub.e]([t.sup.E.sub.e],[c.sub.L]) >
[V.sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],[c.sub.L]) + [[rho].sub.e]([t.sup.DE.sub.e],
[c.sub.L]).
The right hand side of the above equation is the value of a firm
that uses both debt and equity, while the left hand side is the value of
a firm that uses equity exclusively. This condition is always satisfied,
as the use of debt in the capital structure is costly, in terms of
predatory pricing, while the signal can be sent using convertible debt.
This implies that equation (20) is satisfied when [x.sub.e] =
[[??].sub.e]. It follows that there exists some [x.sub.e] >
[[??].sub.e] for which shareholders are indifferent regarding the use of
convertible debt.
To summarize, the firm will choose to use convertible debt if the
conditions specified in equations (14), (15), and (18) are satisfied.
Equation (14) stipulates that a high cost firm will never issue debt, as
issuing debt ensures that a high cost firm is bankrupt with probability
one, given the specified debt level. Because of this, the issuance of
debt sends a signal to the market about the entrant's quality.
Equation (15) stipulates that conversion will not take place if the
entrant is high cost. This ensures that a high cost firm using
convertible debt will never have its debt converted. It also stipulates
that conversion will take place if the entrant is low cost. Satisfaction
of this condition ensures that a low cost firm does not face predation
if it issues convertible debt, as the debt will definitely be converted.
Equation (18) stipulates the scenario under which it is possible to
satisfy equation (15). Without the satisfaction of these conditions,
predation can occur.
4. Discussion
The model presented in this paper argues that an entrant can use
noncallable convertible debt to avoid predation in entry deterrence games. A model is presented in the spirit of Poitevin's (1989) deep
pocket formalization in which adverse selection problems force the
entrant to enter the market heavily leveraged when compared to the
incumbent. The model demonstrates that there exist conversion ratios for
which creditors have an incentive to convert only if the entrant is a
low cost producer. The low cost entrant can therefore issue convertible
debt to signal quality to investors. Before production decisions are
made, the creditors will convert, preventing predation.
The model is highly formalized. For example, the stochastic
component of operating cash flows is independent of the other choices or
market variables. Alternatively, stochastic component of cash flows can
be defined as containing two elements: an element positively correlated
with the parallel stochastic profit element of the rival, and an
independent element. The first would reflect underlying influences that
lead to higher stochastic profits for both firms, while the second would
reflect idiosyncratic stochastic profits. However, the independent
stochastic component is used, as the inclusion of the positively
correlated element would increase the complexity and magnitude of the
equations, without added insight. Earlier studies, such as Poitevin
(1989) and Dasgupta and Titman (1998), do not use positively correlated
profit elements.
While the model is highly formalized, the conclusions are relevant
to both the convertible debt literature and the product market
competition literature. (1) We consider each contribution in turn.
4.1. Contribution to the convertible debt literature
An interesting contribution is the idea that convertible debt does
not have to be callable to force conversion after revelation of firm
type. Contrast this conclusion with the Stein (1992) model, in which
convertible debt must be callable to force conversion. The root of the
difference between the callability status of the convertible debt in
this model and Stein's model is that in the Stein model only
equityholders benefit from conversion, through a reduction of financial
distress costs upon conversion. Therefore, a call feature is required to
motivate conversion by debtholders. In this model, both equityholders
and debtholders benefit from conversion, due to the elimination of the
predation threat upon conversion. Hence, there is no need for the debt
to be callable.
Support for the idea that convertible debt does not have to be
callable comes from Nyborg (1995). Nyborg provides empirical evidence
questioning Stein's argument that using convertible debt with
forced conversion can preserve the initial advantage associated with the
convertible debt. Nyborg demonstrates that, in terms of the adverse
impact on prices, issuing equity is preferable to issuing callable
convertible debt and later forcing conversion.
Note that while in our model the firm does not need a call feature
to force conversion, it is conceivable that a firm will wish to include
a call feature for some exogenous reason. In such a case, following
Stein, the exercise price associated with the call must be greater than
the value received, upon conversion, by debtholders of a high cost firm.
Otherwise, the high cost firm can force conversion through threatening a
call, even when the conversion value of the debtholders' position
is below the nonconversion value.
Note as well that in both Stein (1992) and in the model presented
in this study, the signal of quality is provided through the issuance of
debt, not through the convertibility feature. Instead, the
convertibility feature is used to offset the downside associated with
straight debt issuance. In Stein (1992), the downside is financial
distress. In the model presented in this study, the downside is
predation by the incumbent firm.
4.2. Contribution to the product market competition literature
The model demonstrates that consideration must be given to the role
of hybrid financial securities, such as convertible debt, when
evaluating the influence of capital structure decisions on product
market competition. The model demonstrates that convertible debt can
reduce an incumbent's ability to practice predation. While the
model is an entry game, the conclusions have implications for any game
in which debt is used for signaling purposes in a concentrated market.
Most notably, a number of recent empirical and theoretical studies
have challenged the argument that leveraged transactions executed in
response to unwanted takeover attempts lead to predatory pricing on the
part of a competitor. Empirical studies by Chevalier (1995) Phillips
(1995) and Khanna and Tice (2000) find that prices generally increase
following leveraged transactions executed in response to an unwanted
takeover attempt. The evidence also suggests that prices do not increase
when the rival firm is relatively unleveraged and has very large market
share. In response to this empirical evidence, recent theoretical models
demonstrate how increases in debt can result in increased prices. These
include Dasgupta and Titman (1998), Chevalier and Scharfstein (1996),
and Showalter (1995).
However, none of the empirical or theoretical studies consider the
influence hybrid securities have on product market competition following
highly leveraged transactions. As demonstrated, hybrid securities, such
as convertible debt, can drastically limit or alter the degree to which
a rival can practice predation following a leveraged transaction.
Clearly, future research should incorporate hybrid securities when
testing the relation between capital structure and product market
competition.
5. Conclusion
A model is developed to argue that an entrant can use convertible
debt to avoid predation in entry deterrence games. The model, in the
spirit of Poitevin's (1989) deep pocket formalization, demonstrates
that there exist conversion ratios for which creditors have an incentive
to convert only if the entrant is a low cost producer. The low cost
entrant can therefore issue convertible debt to signal quality to
investors, as creditors will convert before production, preventing
predation. The conclusions differ from Stein (1992) as revelation of
quality alone motivates conversion, while in Stein's model a call
feature is required. It suggests that in a concentrated market,
voluntary conversion can take place without a call feature. Besides
extending the convertible debt literature, the model also suggests that
the product market competition literature cannot continue to assume that
hybrid financial securities do not exist. Instead, future research, both
empirical and theoretical, must recognize that firms can choose from
nontraditional securities to avoid predation.
Note
(1.) Please see Gottesman (2004) for a case study that applies this
paper's conclusions to Euro Disney's 1991 convertible debt
issue.
References
Benoit, J.P., 1984. Financially constrained entry in a game with
incomplete information. RAND Journal of Economics 15, 490-499.
Brennan, M.J., Schwartz, E., 1988. The case for convertibles.
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 1, 55-64.
Brigham, E.F., 1966. An analysis of convertible debentures: Theory
and some empirical evidence. Journal of Finance 21, 35-54.
Chevalier, J.A., 1995. Do LBO supermarkets charge more? An
empirical analysis of the effects of LBOs on supermarket pricing.
Journal of Finance 50, 1095-1112.
Chevalier, J.A., Scharfstein, D., 1996. Capital market
imperfections and countercyclical markups: Theory and evidence. American
Economic Review 86, 703-725.
Constantinides, G., Grundy, B., 1989. Optimal investment with stock
repurchase and financing as signals. Review of Financial Studies 2,
445-465.
Dasgupta, S., Titman, S., 1998. Pricing strategy and financial
policy. Review of Financial Studies 11, 704-737.
Davidson, W.N., Glascock, J.L., Schwarz, T.V., 1995. Signaling with
convertible debt. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 30,
425-440.
Dun & Bradstreet, 1998. Business Failure Record. Dun &
Bradstreet Corporation.
Fudenberg, D., Tirole, J., 1986. Predation without reputation.
Working paper No. 377, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute
of Technology.
Fulghieri, P., Nagarajan, S., 1996. On the strategic role of high
leverage in entry deterrence. Journal of Banking and Finance 20, 1-23.
Gottesman, A.A., 2004. Euro Disney's 1991 convertible debt
issue and the backdoor equity argument. Working paper, Pace University.
Green, R.C., 1984. Investment incentives, debt and warrants.
Journal of Financial Economics 13, 115-136.
Hoffmeister, J.R., 1977. Use of convertible debt in the early
1970s: A reevaluation of corporate motives. Quarterly Review of
Economics and Business 17, 21-31.
Janjigian, V., 1987. The leverage changing consequences of
convertible debt financing. Financial Management 16, 15-21.
Jensen, M.C., Meckling, W.H., 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial
behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial
Economics 3, 305-360.
Khanna, N., Tice, S., 2000. Strategic responses of incumbents to
new entry: The effect of ownership structure, capital structure, and
focus. Review of Financial Studies 13, 749-779.
Kim, Y.O., 1990. Informative conversion rations: a signaling
approach. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 25,229-243.
Kreps, D., Wilson, R., 1982. Sequential equilibria. Econometrica
50, 863-894.
Lewis, C.M., Rogalski, R.J., Seward, J.K., 1999. Is convertible
debt a substitute for straight debt or for common equity? Financial
Management 28, 5-27.
McGee, J.S., 1958. Predatory price-cutting: the Standard Oil (N.J.)
case. Journal of Law and Economics 1, 137-159.
Mikkelson, W., 1978. Agency Costs and convertible securities.
Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation.
Nyborg, K.G., 1995. Convertible debt as delayed equity: Forced
versus voluntary conversion and the information role of call policy.
Journal of Financial Intermediation 4, 358-395.
Phillips, G.M., 1995. Increased debt and industry product markets:
An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 37, 189-238.
Poitevin, M., 1989. Financial signaling and the deep-pocket
argument. RAND Journal of Economics 20, 26-40.
Rasmusen, E., 1994. Games and information. Blackwell Publishers
Inc., Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Showalter, D., 1995. Oligopoly and financial structure; comment.
American Economic Review 85, 647-653.
Stein, J.C., 1992. Convertible bonds as backdoor equity financing.
Journal of Financial Economics 32, 3-22.
Telser, L.G., 1966. Cutthroat competition and the long purse.
Journal of Law and Economics 9, 259-277.
Williamson, O.E., 1974. Book review of Patents and Antitrust Law by
W. Bowman, Yale Law Journal 83, 647-661.
Aron A. Gottesman, Lubin School of Business, Pace University, 1
Pace Plaza, New York, New York, 10038. E-mail: agottesman@pace.edu. Tel:
212-346-1912. Fax: 212-346-1573. The author thanks an anonymous referee,
Gordon Roberts, Michel Poitevin, Moshe Milevsky, Pauline Shum, Yisong
Tian, and participants at the 2002 Financial Management Association
meetings. The author also thanks Social Sciences and Humanities Research
Council of Canada for financial support. All errors are the exclusive
fault of the author.