A simple algebraic approach to teaching oligopoly models.
Chaudhuri, Ananish
1. Introduction
Any undergraduate course in Intermediate Microeconomics or
Industrial Organization devotes a considerable amount of time to
discussing the Stackelberg model of oligopoly. In this paper I develop a
simple algebraic model which provides a new perspective on (1) how we
teach the interaction between firms in a Stackelberg model; and (2) how
the same framework can be extended to a discussion of entry (such as the
Dixit-Spence model) into an industry.
Most undergraduate texts, such as Carlton and Perloff (1994),
Mansfield (1997), Varian (1996), Schotter (1997), Eaton and Eaton
(1995), and Salvatore (1997) among others, present simple and lucid
analyses of the first topic while the second is usually reserved for
graduate texts in economics.
The current paper is not intended to supplant the exposition
provided in contemporary textbooks. It does, however, intend to inform
and improve undergraduate teaching in microeconomics and industrial
organization by providing a different and intuitively appealing way of
explaining the Stackelberg model. Moreover the paradigm that I develop
can be extended to a general discussion of different modes of entry into
a market. Discussion on entry can be motivated by pointing out that
institutional factors or government regulations mandating information
disclosure may dictate whether the competition between firms is
simultaneous or sequential. For instance one firm may have a patent that
allows the firm to enter the industry first and a second firm enters the
industry after the patent expires. Economists have rationalized quantity
competition in this context to imply physical capacity--for instance
each firm decides on the size of the physical plant that they wish to
set up. Establishing capacity and expanding it i s costly so firms want
to make sure that they are establishing the optimum capacity. In
Courtnot's story both firms enter the market simultaneously and
hence have to decide on how much capacity to install without knowing the
other firm's choice. In Stackelberg, however, they make the
decision sequentially--one firm moves first and the second firm observes
the first firm's choice before choosing its own capacity. I discuss
these issues in greater detail in Section 2.2.
The value added of the paper comes from two different sources. (1)
It develops a framework that provides a different way of explaining and
a simple mathematical solution to the Stackelberg model. The same
framework also allows a simple and lucid discussion of entry into an
industry--a topic that usually requires a fair amount of technical
sophistication. This treatment of entry is not found in any of the
current undergraduate texts. (2) The paper achieves this within a simple
algebraic framework that will be accessible to undergraduates who may
not necessarily have a strong background in calculus.
Section 2 sets up the model. Section 2.1 provides a discussion of
the standard Courot model as a way of motivating the issues later in the
paper. Section 2.2 discusses a new approach to the Stackelberg model.
Section 3.1 shows how the new approach developed in Section 2.2 can be
extended to a discussion of the Dixit-Spence model of entry deterrence.
Section 3.2 shows how different modes of entry can be handled within the
same framework. Finally section 4 concludes.
2. The Model
2.1. Cournot Model of Oligopoly
Consider a market with 2 firms that produce a homogeneous product.
The inverse demand function is given by P = A - Q where Q = + [Q.sub.2]
Assume the firms to be identical in the sense that they both have a
marginal cost of $c per unit. The two firms compete in quantities as
Cournot duopolists. The solution to this problem is simple. See Carlton
and Perloff (Second Edition, 1994, pp. 233-238) for a simple algebraic
technique for deriving the best response function for the two firms. It
is not difficult to demonstrate to the students that the best response
function for firm 1 is given by [Q.sub.1]= (A- [Q.sub.2] - c)/2 and that
for firm 2 is [Q.sub.2] = (A -[Q.sub.1] - c)/2. After that one can show
how this is simply a simultaneous equation system involving two
equations in two variables which can be solved for [Q.sub.1] and
[Q.sub.2] obtaining the values [Q.sub.1.sup.*] = (A - c)/3 and
[Q.sub.2.sup.*] = (A - c)/3.
For the sake of simplicity and without loss of generality set A = 1
and c = 0. So the demand curve becomes P = 1 - Q and the marginal cost
of production is zero. In this scenario each Cournot duopolist will
produce an output of 1/3 each. Total output in the market is Q = 2/3.
The market price is P = 1/3. Each firm makes a profit equal to 1/9.
2.2. The Stackelberg Model
Next I turn to the Stackelberg model. Most textbooks present an
adequate explanation of the model. For a rigorous analysis of the model
see Carlton and Perloff, 1994, pp. 250-252.
At this juncture I will point Out the informational asymmetries in
the Cournot and Stackelberg model. Cournot is a game involving
simultaneous moves. In the Cournot model each firm moves simultaneously
and does not know the output decision of the other firm. Each firm has
to decide on its output (capacity) without knowing what the other firm
is doing. In a Stackelberg model on the other hand each firm knows what
the other firm is doing. Firm 1, when it moves, knows exactly how firm 2
will respond to its output (capacity) since firm 1 knows that firm
2's best response function is [Q.sub.2] = (A - [Q.sub.1] - c)/2.
Firm 2, in turn, when it decides its output, knows exactly what output
firm 1 has produced.
The usual approach is to start with the profit maximization problem
for firm 2 which moves second. We show students how to solve firm
2's profit maximization exercise and obtain its reaction function
[Q.sub.2] = (A - [Q.sub.1] - c)/2. Then we work our way back and solve
firm l's profit maximization exercise by plugging in firm 2's
reaction function into firm l's profit function. We then solve for
the two firms' quantities in the usual way.
But there is a simpler way of showing this, assuming that the cost
function is linear. (1) Let us continue with the same numerical example
where A = 1 and c = 0, i.e. firms face a linear demand curve of the form
P = 1 - Q and produce at zero marginal cost.
I simply point out that when firm 1 makes its output decision it is
in fact acting as a monopolist since there are no other firms in the
market. So facing a demand curve of the form P = 1 - Q, this firm goes
ahead and produces the monopoly output which is 1/2. (Since discussions
of oligopoly models succeed monopoly, students by this time understand
why this is the monopoly output.) Once firm 1 has decided its output,
how much of the market is left? Exactly 1/2. What does firm 2 do when it
gets to move? Firm 2 is really looking at the residual demand in the
market which is of the form P = 1/2 - Q. But now firm 2 is in effect a
monopoly in this residual market. Firm 2 then goes ahead and produces
the corresponding monopoly output which is 1/4. It is easy to check that
solving the Stackelberg model in the usual way would yield [Q.sub.1] =
1/2 and [Q.sub.2] = 1/4 as the output responses of firm 1 and firm 2
respectively. The resulting market price is P = 1/4.
This price of 1/4 is lower than the Cournot price of 1/3. Firm 1
makes a profit of 1/8 while firm 2 makes a profit of 1/16. Firm 1 is
then much better off than being a Cournot competitor while firm 2 is
worse off with a lower level of profit. In Cournot both firms get a
profit of 1/9.
What if there are more than two firms moving sequentially? Consider
three firms. In that case firm 1 moves first and produces 1/2; firm 2
moves next and produces 1/4. How much of the market is left? 1/4. So
firm 3 in turn chooses the monopoly output in the residual part of the
market which is 1/8. The aggregate output is 7/8. The market price is
1/8. Firm 1 makes a profit of 1/16, firm 2, 1/32 and firm 3, 1/64. Again
it is easy to check that these are indeed the three outputs that would
prevail if we solve the model in the usual way. If the three firms
competed as Cournot oligopolists then each firm would have produced an
output of 1/4. The market price would have been higher at 1/4. Each firm
would have enjoyed a profit of 1/16. So firm 1 is equally well off as
the Stackelberg leader and as a Cournot competitor. Firms 2 and 3 are
worse off in the Stackelberg model as compared to the Cournot model.
3.1. The Dixit-Spence Model of Entry Deterrence
The Stackelberg model of the previous section can be used as a
point of departure to introduce the idea of entry deterrence. Obviously
merely moving first and producing the monopoly output is not enough to
deter entry since there is enough residual demand for a follower to
enter the market and make profit. So the question arises--what should an
incumbent firm do in order to prevent other firms from entering the
market?
Some textbooks, such as Schotter (1996), start by introducing the
Bain-Modigliani-Sylos-Labini model. The model has three periods. In
period 1 the incumbent firm chooses an output and commits to maintaining
this output even after entry has occurred. In period 2 the potential
entrant decides whether to enter or not. Then in period 3 the incumbent
firm chooses its output again. According to the BMS-L model this output
is the same as the one that the incumbent firm had committed to before.
However as we know the BMS-L model is not subgame perfect since once
entry has occurred it is not profitable to produce the pre-entry output
but rather accommodate entry and behave as a Cournot duopolist. See
Schotter (1996, pp. 409-11) for a lucid analysis of this model. The
threat of expanding output to the point where entry is not profitable
for the entrant and maintaining that output even if entry occurs is a
non-credible threat.
So what would be a credible threat? At this point we can introduce
the Dixit-Spence model. As we know, in the Dixit-Spence model firms
should overinvest in capacity and install much more capacity than they
would in the standard Cournot or Stackelberg duopoly story. Installing
this excess capacity and then threatening to expand output following
entry is a subgame perfect equilibrium.
In the Dixit-Spence model there are three periods. In period 1, the
incumbent firm decides how much capacity to install. Then in period 2,
the incumbent firm chooses its output, followed by the potential
entrant's decision to enter or not. If entry occurs then the
incumbent firm can respond by adjusting its output in period 3.
Let us assume at this point that the incumbent firm has the option
of installing a certain amount of capacity [K.sup.*], such that for any
output less than [K.sup.*], the incumbent firm can produce at zero
marginal cost as before. But for any quantity greater than [K.sup.*],
the cost per unit becomes 1/4. For the potential entrant the cost per
unit is 1/4 since the entrant has no installed capacity. So the
incumbent's marginal cost function is
C = 0 for q [less than or equal to] [K.sup.*]
C = (1/4)q for q > [K.sup.*].
Let us continue with our simple demand of P = 1 - Q. The first
question is--what is the output that would make entry unprofitable? The
answer is simple--set price equal to average cost. At this point the
incumbent firm breaks even and any potential entrant is faced with
non-positive profit. Since c is 1/4, then setting price equal to average
cost yields a capacity of 3/4 unit. The incumbent firm should install a
capacity of 3/4 but continue to produce its monopoly output of 1/2.
Faced with this installed capacity of 3/4, entry becomes unprofitable.
This is because if the incumbent firm does produce 3/4 then the residual
market demand is P = (1/4) - Q and even the monopoly output in this
residual market is 0. The incumbent firm can now costlessly expand its
output till 3/4 unit making such entry unprofitable. Thus in this model
the incumbent firm installs just enough capacity that will make entry
unprofitable and then in the equilibrium of this game, entry does not
occur and the incumbent firm continues to enj oy monopoly profit.
If the incumbent does not have installed capacity then it cannot
deter entry by a potential entrant. In this case the incumbent firm
produces its optimal output as the Stackelberg leader which would be 3/8
and that of the follower would be 3/16 (given a marginal cost of (1/4)
for each firm).
3.2. Handling Various Modes of Entry
The model developed in Sections 2.2 and 3.1 allows me to extend my
class discussions to a wide variety of entry sequences. One way of
motivating the idea of different entry sequences is to introduce the
idea that the firms may require a patent for their product before they
engage in output competition. Aoki and Prusa (1997) point out that
institutional factors and government regulations that mandate
information disclosure may determine whether competition takes the form
of a simultaneous move game or a sequential move game. One good example
is the differences in the timing of information disclosure between the
U.S. and Japanese patent systems. Under the Japanese system of kokai a
firm's patent application is laid open 18 months after the filing
date and before it is granted to the firm. Hence it is possible for a
firm to apply for a patent knowing the exact specifications of a rival
firm's patent application. In contrast, in the U.S., the only way a
firm learns about a rival's innovation is upon the actual gr anting of the patent to the rival. See Aoki and Prusa (1996, 1997) for detailed
discussions of the impact of patent laws on the mode of market entry.
In the U.S. context then, a firm with a patent may enter an
industry first, to be followed by others when the patent expires. But in
the Japanese context, since the patent is thrown open to a firm's
rivals before it is granted to a firm, it is not inconceivable to think
of more than one firm entering a market simultaneously to be followed by
others at a later date. Such differences in patent law could explain how
there could be different entry sequences into a market. See Chaudhuri
(2000) for a discussion of a number of related issues.
I can now discuss issues such as:
(1) Suppose firm 1 moves first and decides what output to produce;
firms 2 and 3 observe firm 1's output and then move simultaneously.
What is the output produced by each firm?
(2) Suppose firms 1 and 2 act as Cournot duopolists and decide on
their output. Firm 3 observes the output of both firms 1 and 2 and then
decides on its output. What is the output of each firm in this case?
We can address the first issue in the following way. When firm 1
makes its output decision it acts as a monopoly and as a result faces
the entire market demand P = 1 - Q and chooses the monopoly output of
1/2. How much of the market is left for firms 2 and 3? The remainder of
the market, which is (1/2). So firms 2 and 3 are facing a market demand
curve of the form P = (1/2) - Q. What output do they each produce? They
are Cournot duopolists in the market except instead of getting the
entire market demand they get 1/2 of it. So they produce [(1/3)*(1/2)] =
1/6 each. Again solving the model using the usual technique of subgame
perfection (of course using calculus) one gets the same exact answer.
Similarly, for (2), firms 1 and 2 are duopolists and will therefore
produce 1/3 each accounting for [2*(1/3)] = 2/3 of the market. So firm 3
in effect faces a market demand of the form P = (1/3) - Q. When firm 3
makes its output decision it can act as a monopolist and hence chooses
the monopoly output in the residual part of the market which is
[(1/2)*(1/3)] = 1/6. Again it is easy to check that these are indeed the
output that would be produced in the Stackelberg model.
Part of the reason for introducing issues of entry deterrence was
motivated by the way we teach our students about monopolists. In
teaching the monopoly model to our students we usually motivate our
discussion with two types of examples. We discuss the regulated
"natural monopolies," with constantly decreasing average cost,
such as public utilities. And we talk of an "unregulated monopoly" which may have obtained a patent which preserves its
monopoly position or a monopoly like De Beers, the diamond producer,
which controls almost all of the input sources.
But it is important and instructive to point out to students that
there is yet another reason why a firm may enjoy a monopoly
position--because it has successfully prevented other firms from
entering. But if one introduces that idea then that automatically
necessitates talking about entry and entry-deterrence. The model most
often referred to is the Dixit-Spence model where firms hold excess
capacity to deter entry. As I pointed out above, the usual discussion of
such models is beyond the grasp of less sophisticated students and is
therefore left out of most lectures. My model has the advantage that I
can incorporate questions of entry deterrence and the Dixit-Spence model
in a simple yet intuitive way.
The new approach also allows me to discuss more advanced topics
such as different entry sequences or the presence of more than two firms
(Section 3.2). This, normally, would be beyond the scope of
undergraduate classes due to the technical nature of the material.
I typically introduce the above topics after I have thoroughly
covered monopoly, monopolistic competition and given the students a
rudimentary introduction to simultaneous move games and sequential move
games. I make sure that the students understand my discussion of how a
standard unregulated monopolist makes his decision regarding price and
output. Since my subsequent discussion of oligopoly models is dependent
on the students having a good grasp on this topic. Then I use simple
games to highlight the relevant game theoretic concepts such as best
responses. By this time I want my students to have an intuitive
understanding of the Prisoner's Dilemma, as well as the concepts of
Nash Equilibrium and backward induction. It is after these topics that I
introduce the Coumot model. Then I discuss the Stackelberg model. First
I discuss the standard textbook approach and then I show the students
the new method. At which point I can extend my lectures to topics that
are usually never included in most undergraduate co urses. I talk about
the rationale and incentive for deterring entry to perpetuate a monopoly
position which guarantees higher profit. Then I can also talk about
different sequences of entry into the product market.
4. Conclusion
In this paper I have provided a simple algebraic framework for
teaching the Stackelberg model where firms move sequentially instead of
simultaneously. This framework provides a different way of thinking
about the Stackelberg model. The framework can be extended to undertake
a discussion of various modes of entry. Moreover the model has the added
advantage that it takes topics which can be technically sophisticated
and provides an intuitive and computationally simple way of dealing with
them. This makes the topics much more appealing to students who may not
have a strong background in calculus and hence the framework has the
potential of improving undergraduate instruction in the area.
Note
(1.) It should be noted that the results derived in the following
pages about the Stackelberg and Dixit-Spence models are based on the
assumption of a linear cost function and may not work for non-linear
costs. But given that in both undergraduate, as well as graduate,
classes we exclusively use linear cost functions to motivate these
models, this assumption is justified. Also this assumption allows us to
extend the discussion to a number of issues that would, usually, be far
outside the scope of a typical undergraduate course.
References
Aoki, R and T. Prusa (1996), "Product Development and the
Timing of Information Disclosure under U.S. and Japanese Patent
Systems," Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, v
10, pp. 233-49.
Aoki, R and T. Prusa (1997), "Sequential versus Simultaneous
Choice with Endogenous Quality," International Journal of
Industrial Organization, v 15, pp. 103-121.
Browning, Edgar and Mark Zupan (1999), Microeconomic Theory and
Application, 6th Edition, Addison Wesley. Reading, Mass.
Carlton, D. W. and J. M Perloff (1994), Modern Industrial
Organization, 2nd edition, Harper Collins College Publishers, New York.
Chaudhuri, A. (2000) "Endogenous Quality Choice and the Impact
of Quantitative Restrictions," The International Trade Journal,
Volume XIV, No. 4, Winter 2000, pp. 377-397.
Eaton, B. C. and D. F. Eaton (1995), Microeconomics, 3rd edition,
Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey.
Mansfield, E. (1997), Microeconomics, 9th edition, W.W. Norton, New
York.
Pepall, Lynne, Daniel Richards and George Norman (1999), Industrial
Organization: Contemporary Theory and Practice, 2nd Edition,
Southwestern College Publishers, Cincinnati, Ohio.
Salvatore, D. (1997), Microeconomics, 3rd edition, Addison-Wesley,
Reading, Mass.
Schotter, A. (1997), Microeconomics, 2nd edition, Addison-Wesley,
Reading, Mass.
Varian, H. R. (1996), Intermediate Microeconomics, 4Th edition,
W.W. Norton, New York.
Ananish Chaudhuri *
* Department of Economics, Washington State University, 2710
University Drive, Richland, WA 99352. Phone: 509-372-7238, E-mail:
achaudh@tricity.wsu.edu.
I would like to express my sincerest thanks to Partha Deb for
excellent and extensive feedback regarding both substance and
exposition. I also want to thank Thomas Prusa, Debajyoti Chakrabarty and
Achintan Dey for valuable insights and feedback. I would also like to
thank my students at Washington State University for the feedback they
have provided over the years and also for helping me develop and focus
the ideas contained in this paper. All remaining errors are mine alone.