The dollar and U.S. inflation: Some evidence from a VECM process (+).
Darrat, Ali F. ; Chopin, Marc C. ; Dickens, Ross N. 等
Ali F. Darrat (*)
Marc C. Chopin (**)
Ross N. Dickens (***)
1. Introduction
Since the advent of floating exchange rates in early 1973, the
values of world currencies have endured large fluctuations. Several
countries which experienced currency depreciation suffered domestic
inflationary pressures apparently due, at least in part, to the
consequent rise in import and import-related prices. When the value of
home currency falls relative to foreign currencies, domestic prices of
imported goods rise. If these imports represent a major component of
domestic consumption, prices of overall consumer goods rise, thus
increasing domestic inflation. Another channel by which movements in the
exchange rate may lead to changes in domestic inflation can be found in
the "currency substitution" hypothesis [see Cuddington (1983)
and Batten and Hafer (1986)] which contends that rational money holders
maximize their returns from holding domestic and foreign currencies.
Thus, an expected devaluation of currency could reduce the demand for
domestic currency, leading in turn to an excess supply of domestic money
and to subsequent inflationary pressures. (1)
Under floating exchange rates and with large fluctuations in the
dollar exchange rate, especially since 1985, it seems important to
investigate whether a reliable relationship exists between the dollar
exchange rate and U.S. prices. Indeed, if movements in the dollar
exchange rate substantially influence domestic inflation, achieving the
goal of price stability would become increasingly difficult with a
volatile currency value.
While a few studies, like Woo (1984) and Glossman (1985), find
little or no impact of the dollar exchange rate on U.S. prices, the body
of available evidence surveyed in Hafer (1989) overwhelmingly supports a
significant negative correlation between changes in the dollar exchange
rate and U.S. prices. Hafer reports short-run (long-run) estimates of
domestic price increases of about 2% (5%) for every 10% fall in the
dollar exchange rate. Data over 1974-1994, for example, reveal that the
correlation coefficient between changes in U.S. prices and the dollar
exchange rate is indeed negative and statistically significant (= -0.40,
t = -6.80). Such negative associations stoke fears in the financial
press that failing to maintain a strong dollar could ignite U.s.
inflation [see, for example, Boyd (1989) and Phillips (1998)].
Although the apparent correlation between changes in the dollar
exchange rate and U.S. prices cannot be denied, this relationship is
neither sufficiently tight nor persistently negative. For example, from
March 1985 to February 1989, the correlation coefficient was
significantly positive (= +0.32, t = +2.29). In addition, the
often-cited negative correlation between changes in prices and the
dollar exchange rate may be the outcome of prices influencing the
exchange rate. Some researchers, like Dornbusch and Fischer (1987),
interpret the Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) theory as implying that
higher domestic inflation "causes" higher rates of currency
depreciation in order to maintain the terms of trade constant. (2)
Therefore, the observed negative correlation between changes in the
dollar exchange rate and domestic prices may be the result of the latter
causing the former, opposite to what is commonly believed.
Instead of focusing on the direction of causality, most previous
studies confine their attention to the correlation between the dollar
exchange rate and prices [see, for example, Woo (1984), Glassman (1985),
Hakkio and Whittaker (1985), and Solomon (1985)]. Clearly, statistical
correlations between two variables, by themselves, are insufficient to
establish the direction of causality. (3) Therefore, these studies are
unable to distinguish between cause and effect. In fact, the observed
correlation between the dollar exchange rate and domestic prices is
consistent with four alternative causal hypotheses, each with quite
different policy implications. These hypotheses are: (a) changes in the
exchange rate cause the inflation rate (the conventional hypothesis),
(b) inflation causes changes in exchange rates (the relative PPP
proposition), (c) the two variables are mutually causal, and (d) the two
variables are not causally related at all. If hypotheses (a) and (b) are
jointly valid, then the correct inference i s hypothesis (c). Under this
scenario, correlationbased analysis is potentially misleading.
Hypothesis (d) suggests that changes in exchange rates and inflation
lack any causal relationship and are instead influenced by other
macroeconomic variables. (4) Established theory [see Obstfeld and Rogoff
(1996)] suggests a number of factors that could influence both exchange
rates and inflation. In particular, these theories indicate the
potential importance of macroeconomic policies, interest rates, and real
income for determining inflation and exchange rates [see, for example,
Modigliani and Papademos (1980), Feldstein (1995), Darrat (1985a, 1985b,
1988), and Krugman (1995)].
In summary, then, appropriate tests of the causal relationship
between changes in exchange rates and inflation should take into account
the potential impact of monetary policy, fiscal policy, interest rates
and real income. Otherwise, causal inferences obtained from bivariate (exchange rate/inflation) models are suspect due to the
omission-of-variables' bias [see Lutkepohl (1982)]. (5)
This paper examines the causal linkage between the dollar exchange
rate and U.S. prices in a multivariate context. To avoid possible
misspecification from ignoring long-run relationships among the
variables, we also incorporate the underlying cointegratedness among the
variables and estimate a vector error-correction model (VECM). These
models place only minimum prior restrictions on the estimated
parameters. Such a feature of the VECM is particularly important since,
as Dornbusch and Fischer (1987) point out, there is a great deal of
uncertainty about the nature of the link between exchange rates and
prices, as well as about the dynamics of the exchange rate itself.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2
outlines the data and methodology. We discuss the empirical results and
policy implications in Section 3. Section 4 concludes the paper.
2. Data and Methodology
We use U.S. monthly data spanning the period April 1973 through
December 1997 to estimate a six-variable VECM model. The start of the
sample period coincides with the implementation of the floating exchange
rate regime. Adding data from the earlier Bretton Woods' (fixed
exchange-rate) era contaminates the sample with two distinct regimes,
perhaps reducing the reliability of the estimates. The variables are the
inflation rate (I), where prices are measured by the U.S. consumer price
index (CPI); the bilateral exchange rate (E) between the U.S. dollar and
the Japanese yen; the U.S. threemonth Treasury bill rate (R); the
monetary base (B) to represent monetary policy moves; the par value of
publicly held federal debt securities (F) to represent fiscal policy
actions; (6) and the Industrial Production Index (X) to measure the real
side of the economy. All data series come from the Citibase Data Tape.
Some remarks regarding our definitions of the variables seem in
order. Our inflation measure is based on the CPI, since it generally
displays the highest (negative) correlation with exchange rates perhaps
due to the fact that import prices directly enter the CPI [see Hafer
(1989)]. By contrast, import prices are reflected only indirectly in
other price measures (like the GNP deflator) through their impact upon
the prices of domestically produced goods. Consequently, most previous
studies that report a significant relationship between prices and
exchange rates use the CPI. Nevertheless, using the GNP deflator instead
of the CPI altered none of our main conclusions.
Following Hafer (1989), we employ the bilateral U.S.
dollar/Japanese Yen exchange rate to represent the exchange rate
variable in our model. We choose the $/[yen] exchange rate since Japan
claims a significant share of the U.S. overall foreign trade. Indeed,
Japan has become the largest trading partner for the U.S. in recent
years according to data from the U.S. Census Bureau. In addition, and
particularly since September 1985, major OECD countries use the $/[yen]
exchange rate as a prime tool to analyze the overall dollar behavior in
international financial markets. Numerous U.S. official statements
reveal that the $/[yen] exchange rate represents a major factor
underlying U.S. foreign and domestic economic developments. In light of
these and other arguments [see Hafer (1989)], we choose to report our
results for the $/[yen] exchange rate. It should be noted that our
results do not seem sensitive to the particular exchange rate used in
the paper. In fact, qualitatively similar conclusions emerged with the t
rade-weighted exchange rate which reflects the value of the dollar
against a basket of several foreign currencies, including the Yen (these
alternative results are available upon request). However, as a referee
insightfully pointed out, growing US trade with Canada and Mexico in the
aftermath of NAFTA may require examination of the case using the US
dollar exchange rate against the Canadian dollar and/or the Mexican
peso. This is undoubtedly an interesting topic for future research.
The VECM model is a linear representation of the joint stochastic
process that generates the variables. Each of the variables in the model
is considered endogenous, comprising of two components: a linear
function of the past realization of all variables in the system
(including a variable's own lagged values), as well as an
unpredictable innovation component. Several econometricians [e.g., Sims
(1982), and Todd (1990)] recommend the use of these models as a useful
alternative to "structural" modeling. (7) Note that lags in
VECM models need not be equal across all equations and variables, as
Ahking and Miller (1985) point out. To avoid possible lag
misspecifications, we use Akaike's final prediction error (FPE)
criterion to determine the lag structure. (8) Thornton and Batten (1985)
recommend this criterion over alternative lag-selection procedures.
Generally, the FPE procedure chooses relatively long lags as it
emphasizes unbiasedness over efficiency. There is, of course, no
assurance that the lag profile ch osen by the FPE criterion in any given
case is the only appropriate profile in the lag space, and it is also
possible that the lag-length chosen may be data-specific [see Thornton
and Batten (1985)]. Therefore, we subject the FPE-lag structures to
further (over- and under-fitting) testing to ensure robustness.
We begin our empirical analysis by inspecting each of the six
variables for nonstationarity using the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF)
test. Again, we employ the FPE criterion to choose the proper lag
specification in the ADF test. The results suggest that the variables
appear stationary in logarithmic first-differences. (9) As mentioned
earlier, we determine the lag structure for each of the six equations in
the VECM model by the FPE criterion, in conjunction with the
"specific gravity" criterion of Caines et al. (1981). These
methods are well-known in applied econometrics and we therefore do not
explain them here [see Darrat and Barnhart (1989) for details].
Importantly, Engle and Granger (1987) also suggest the need to test
for cointegration prior to estimating the models. They argue that
inferences from standard VARs are incorrect if the variables are
cointegrated and no allowance is made for the cointegrating
relationships. We use the Johansen (1988) efficient procedure to test
for cointegration in a multivariate setting. The Johansen test is based
on the well-accepted likelihood ratio principle, and evidence by Gonzalo
(1994) shows that the Johansen approach performs better than several
alternative multivariate testing procedures.
The VECM model is normalized so that only lagged values of the
variables are used as explanatory variables. Note that contemporaneous relationships among the endogenous variables in the VECM model are
reflected in the innovations. We pool the six equations and estimate
them as a system using the Zellner Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR)
technique. Compared to a single-equation (OLS) procedure, Zellner's
SUR yields estimates that are both consistent and asymptotically more
efficient, provided that the errors across equations are correlated (but
errors within each equation are themselves uncorrelated). The estimated
VECM model is viewed as a maintained hypothesis regarding the causal
relationships under investigation. We perform likelihood ratio (LR)
tests within system estimations to test the joint significance of lagged
coefficients. A significant LR statistic supports the presence of a
Granger-causal ordering of the strong form.
3. Empirical Results and The Implied Causality Inferences
As we discussed earlier, a necessary prelude to investigating
causal relationships is to test for possible cointegratedness among the
variables of the model. Table 1 has the results from the Johansen test
of cointegration. As recommended by Johansen (1995), we test the joint
hypothesis of both the cointegrating rank and the deterministic components based on the Pantula principle to choose the model most
consistent with the data under investigation.
According to the trace statistics of the Johansen test, we can
easily reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration among the
variables, in favor of the alternative presumption that there is at
least one cointegrating vector. The maximal eigenvalue test concurs with
that verdict and specifically suggests that there is one nonzero cointegrating vector in the system. (10) Consequently, each equation in
the model should include the corresponding error-correction term and we
extract those terms from the Johansen approach. Using the procedure
described above, we obtain the following VECM system for the U.S. over
the monthly sample from April 1973 through December 1997:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where L is the lag operator; D[I.sub.t] = (1 - L)log [I.sub.t], I
is the inflation rate; D[E.sub.t] = (1 - L)log [E.sub.t], E is the
$/[yen] bilateral exchange rate; D[R.sub.t] = (1-L)log [R.sub.t], R is
the three-month Treasury bill rate; D[B.sub.t] = (1 - L)log [B.sub.t], B
is the monetary base; D[F.sub.t] = (1-L)log [F.sub.t], F is the par
value of publicly held federal debt securities; D[X.sub.t] = (1 - L)log
[X.sub.t], X is the Industrial Production Index;
[[beta].sup.k.sub.ii](L) is the kth lag coefficient on variable j in
equation i; the [alpha]'s are constants; the [lambda]'s are
the coefficients on the associated lagged EC terms; (11) and the
e's are white-noise error terms. To conserve space, we relegate the
individual parameter estimates from the above system to an appendix
(available upon request). However, one must exercise some caution when
discussing these individual estimates due to the reduced-form nature of
the model [see Sims (1980)].
Before discussing the causality implications of the empirical
results, it should be pointed out that we conducted a series of over-
and under-fitting diagnostic tests within system estimations. These
tests suggested the need to introduce some minor modifications in the
lag structure of the model. This finding should not be entirely
surprising since the model was initially specified on the basis of
individual (single) equation estimations. Thus, differences may (or
perhaps should) be found between the specifications of single equations
and that of a pooled system. We incorporate the implied system
modifications and perform another round of diagnostic tests on the
resultant model. The diagnostic tests clearly favor the adjusted model
as given above. (12) In particular, various structural instability tests
(Cusum and Cusum-Square procedures) do not reveal any evidence of a
significant structural break, particularly in the exchange-rate
equation. This is important since our estimation period covers the
floating exchange-rate regime (1973-1997) which contains several
instances (e.g., the Plaza Accord of September 1985) whereby Central
Banks in the G-7 attempted to "manage" the float Absence of
significant structural shifts imply that possible biases due to the
managed floating episodes, if they existed, are likely to be minimal.
We now discuss the causality inferences implied by the VECM system.
Table 2 displays the LR statistics to test the joint significance of the
non-zero (off-diagonal) elements of the maintained model. In the
presence of cointegration, these LR statistics gauge short-run
Granger-causality, while the significance of the coefficients on the
error-correction terms in the various equations may be taken as evidence
of long-run Granger causality. (13)
The central finding from our estimations is that there exists a
substantive short-run relationship such that the dollar exchange rate
exerts a significant and unidirectional causal impact upon U.S. prices.
Specifically, we can easily reject at the 5% level the null hypothesis
that changes in the dollar exchange rate do not Granger-cause short-run
changes in U.S. inflation (see test 1 in Table 2). At the same time, we
fail to reject the reverse notion that changes in the U.S. inflation do
not Grangercause short-run movements in the dollar exchange rate. Two
specification tests support this latter inference. The FPE criterion
suggests the need to drop the price variable from the exchange rate
equation, implying the absence of even weak shortrun causal effects from
prices to exchange rates. Furthermore, this evidence from
single-equation estimations is corroborated by system estimations since
we relax the zero restriction on the price variable within the model
system, but fail to find it significant. (14)
The empirical results also suggest that the sensitivity of U.S.
inflation to movements in the dollar exchange rate is not only
statistically significant, but it is also rapid and completed within
only two months. (15) We find similar results from the associated
variance decompositions (VDCs) that show the percentage of the forecast
error variance for each variable attributable to its own innovations and
to shocks to the other variables in the model. Using the Choleski
decomposition method over several monthly horizons (one to twenty
months), and with alternate sequencing of the variables, the results
reveal large effects of changes in the dollar exchange rate on
inflation, which quickly reach their peak by the fifth or sixth month.
In contrast, VDCs suggest that the effects of inflation on the exchange
rate are small and almost non-existent until the eighth month when
inflation begins to show some noticeable impact. (16) Such a high speed
with which the exchange rate impinges on U.S. inflation may in part ref
lect the agility of foreign exchange markets in processing new
information. Observe further that our estimation period witnessed a
dramatic increase in the volume of international trade and foreign
exchange transactions, along with growing foreign currency futures markets. These developments may invigorate the response of macroeconomic
variables, like the inflation rate, to developments in foreign exchange
markets.
Our results further suggest that, besides changes in the dollar
exchange rate, two other factors also Granger-caused short-run changes
in U.S. inflation; namely, the growth rates of the monetary base and of
the industrial production index (see, respectively, tests 2 and 3 in
Table 2). Thus, and in accordance with the familiar monetarist thesis,
monetary policy is an important tool for achieving price stability. This
inference is further supported by the results from VDCs which reveal
large and persistent effects of money on prices.
As to the factors behind short-run movements in the dollar exchange
rate, the empirical results suggest that only changes in the stance of
monetary policy exert a significant (and quick) impact upon the dollar
exchange rate. None of the other potential determinants of the exchange
rate (inflation, interest rates, federal debt, or industrial production)
appears capable of exerting significant short-run movements in the
dollar's value. Interestingly, these results are supportive of the
Ricardian hypothesis and Evans' (1986) conclusion in regards to the
irrelevance of the federal government budget to the determination of the
dollar exchange rate.
In addition to the above short-run causality findings, the results
from the VECM further imply interesting long-run causality inferences.
In particular, while the EC term is statistically significant in the
inflation equation ([[lambda].sub.1] [not equal to] 0), the
corresponding EC term fails to achieve statistical significance in the
exchange rate equation ([[lambda].sub.2] [approximately equal to]
0).Therefore, the potent unidirectional causal impact of the dollar
exchange rate on U.S. inflation discussed earlier is not limited to the
short-run, but it apparently extends to the long-run as well. (17)
Besides the relationship between the dollar exchange rate and U.S.
inflation, the estimated VECM process yields other interesting results.
For example, we find that fiscal policy directly influences real output
(see test 22 in Table 2). By contrast, monetary policy appears neutral
for real output as reflected in a zero cell for the base money in the
real output equation (an over-fitting test also yields an insignificant
statistic). Consequently, the VECM results are consistent with the
dominance of fiscal policy over monetary policy for stabilizing real
economic activity, whereas the reverse is true for stabilizing inflation
[see Darrat (1986) for a similar conclusion drawn from a different
model]. However, observe that while monetary policy does not directly
influence real output, it nevertheless exerts some real indirect effects
through interactions with interest rates (see tests 10 and 21 in Table
2). Moreover, the Federal Reserve appears to react primarily to
developments in the financial market since on ly interest rates
significantly influence the base money (test 14 in Table 2). By
contrast, the reaction function of fiscal policy is a little more
involved, with fiscal policymakers reacting to movements both in the
exchange rate and in real output.
4. Concluding Remarks
This paper uses monthly U.S. data over the period April 1973
through December 1997 to investigate the interrelationship between the
dollar exchange rate and U.S. inflation. The results, obtained from a
cointegration and error-correction multivariate model, consistently
indicate the presence of a unidirectional and significant causal effect
flowing from changes in the dollar exchange rate to U.S. inflation both
in the short- and in the long-run. Indeed, recent statements in the
popular press are consistent with our conclusion regarding the presence
of a potent impact of changes in the dollar's value on U.S.
inflation. (18)
Econometrically, these findings support the use of exchange rates
as an exogenous variable in modeling U.S. inflation. From the
perspective of policymaking, our empirical results suggest that
movements in the dollar exchange rate should be taken into account when
forming anti-inflation policy. Analysis of recent policy actions of the
Federal Reserve suggests that some weight has indeed been given to
exchange-rate movements in pursuing domestic inflation goals. In
particular, the Federal Reserve has raised its interest-rate target at
least six times since June 1999 in an attempt to restrict growth in
money stock and stave off potential inflation pressures. Apparently,
these restrictive policy actions were induced, at least in part, by
faster than expected economic growth and by an exceedingly strong dollar
relative to most world currencies.
Besides the dollar exchange rate, the results further show that
monetary policy significantly influences U.S. inflation. We may infer
that it is primarily these potent monetary policy effects that have
insulated U.S. prices from recent pronounced changes in the dollar
value. Indeed, in light of our finding of a significant and a rapid
impact of money growth on U.S. inflation, it seems that the Federal
Reserve has shouldered much of the responsibility with respect to
promoting price stability in recent years.
(*.) Professor of Economics, College of Administration and
Business, Louisiana Tech University
(**.) Associate Professor of Economics, College of Administration
and Business, Louisiana Tech University
(***.) Associate Professor of Finance, Mitchell College of
Business, University of South Alabama
(+.) We wish to thank an anonymous reviewer for helpful comments.
The usual disclaimer applies. Corresponding author: Ali F. Darrat,
Department of Economics and Finance, Louisiana Tech University, P.O. Box
10318 T.S., Ruston, Louisiana 71272. Tel.: 318-257-3874; Fax:
318-257-4253, e-mail: Darrat@cab.Latech.edu.
Notes
(1.) Hafer (1989) provides a lucid theoretical discussion of
several other channels (both direct and indirect) through which the
dollar exchange rate can impinge on domestic inflation.
(2.) As Dornbusch and Fischer (p. 757) put it "exchange rate
changes are caused by divergences in inflation rates between countries,
with the exchange rate changing in a way that maintains the terms of
trade [(exchange rate x foreign prices)/domestic prices] constant"
(emphasis added). Similar statements can be found in popular textbooks
like Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996). However, other researchers [e.g.,
Yarbrough and Yarbrough (1997)] reject the above argument and contend
instead the PPP has no bearing on the direction of causality between
exchange rates and prices.
(3.) Two recent studies employ a causality approach to examine the
relationship between changes in exchange rates and prices; namely Whitt,
Koch and Rosenweig (1986) for the U.S., and Kholdy and Sohrabian (1990)
for Canada, Germany, and Japan. However, both studies use the
restrictive bivariate causality framework and, as such, their results
may suffer from an omission of variables' bias as we discuss below.
(4.) As Granger (1980) and Lutkepohl (1982) demonstrate, it is
possible for variables to be highly correlated, yet causally
independent. Lutkepohl (1982, p. 367) writes, "this conclusion is a
consequence of the well-known problem that a low dimensional subprocess
contains little information about the structure of a higher dimensional
system," p. 367.
(5.) We, of course, do not imply that the variables we consider
here exhaust all potentially important factors. Nevertheless, we believe
that the proposed variables are well grounded in theory and the
resultant multivariate model does represent a clear improvement over
bivariate-based studies.
(6.) Since issues of new U.S. Treasury securities generally sell at
prices close to par value, changes in the par value of outstanding
Treasury securities can provisionally represent fiscal policy (federal
budget deficit) moves.
(7.) Clearly, this procedure lacks universal acceptance and many
researchers, including Cooley and LeRoy (1985), remain skeptical.
(8.) We search for proper lags within a lag space of sixteen
months. If we find the lag length for any variable to be sixteen months,
we extend the lag profile for that variable by at least two more lags to
check whether the sixteen-month lag is indeed appropriate.
(9.) The results from the ADF test (available upon request) are
robust to Schwert's (1987) criticism, as well as to the inclusion
or exclusion of a time trend. Note that logarithmic first-differences of
the variables approximate their percentage changes (growth rates).
Taking prices as an example, the logarithmic first-difference yields the
inflation rate.
(10.) Following Gonzalo (1994), we use lag specifications in the
Johansen test that jointly minimize the Akaike Information Criterion (MG) as well as whiten the residuals. A lag of seven months achieves
both goals in our case. The results, however, are not significantly
different with other reasonable lag specifications.
(11.) We lag the EC terms only once since additional terms are
already reflected in the distributed lags of the first-differences of
the variables. See Miller (1991).
(12.) The final model receives further support from a battery of
tests that generally show no evidence of autocorrelation, omission of
variables, or structural instability. Details of these tests are
available upon request.
(13.) Granger (1988) supports this interpretation of short-run
versus long-run causality, and Jones and Joulfaian (1991) use it.
(14.) It appears that such pronounced effects of the dollar
exchange rate on U.S. prices are transmitted primarily through price
importation rather than via currency substitution. We state this since
currency substitution between the dollar and the yen appears weak, at
least during the estimation period. In separate estimations of U.S.
money demand (using, alternatively, M1 and M2), currency substitution as
measured by the differential between inflation rates in U.S. and Japan
proves statistically insignificant (details are available upon request).
Several recent empirical studies also draw similar conclusions regarding
the minimal role of currency substitution in a variety of contexts. See,
for example, Mizen and Pentecost (1996) and Arnold (1996). Of course,
our results are confined to the U.S. dollar/Japanese yen case and do not
necessarily preclude the presence of significant currency substitutions
involving the dollar against other non-yen currencies.
(15.) In contrast, Whitt, Koch, and Rosenweig (1986) report a
rather long lag of more than twenty-four months for the effect of
changes in exchange rates on U.S. inflation. A number of factors may
contribute to this apparent disparity in the lag lengths. Note first
that our model is multivariate compared to their admittedly biased
bivariate model. Their long lag may also be reflecting the complex, yet
overlooked, process by which omitted variables impinge on inflation.
Furthermore, we determine our lag structure using the FPE criterion and
unconstrained OLS estimations, while they determine their lag structure
by means of a combined Almon/Koyck scheme. Recent applied literature
criticizes both Almon and Koyck procedures on the ground that they
suffer from potentially serious drawbacks.
(16.) We derive similar conclusions from estimating the associated
impulse response functions (IRFs) that measure how the dependent
variables respond over time to a one-standard deviation change in each
shock. To conserve space, we do not report results from VDCs and IRFs,
but they are available upon request. Note that Runkle (1987) and Spencer
(1989) raise serious doubts on the usefulness of the VDCs and IRFs.
(17.) The VECM results render a similar conclusion for the effect
of the base money on prices. That is, growth in monetary base exerts a
significant and a unidirectional effect on inflation both in the short-
and in the long-run.
(18.) See, for example, Phillips (1948). In a recent episode aired
on May 11, 1999, commentators on the CNN program, Moneyline Focus, also
argued that the strong dollar in the late 1 990s is primarily credited
for stifling U.S. inflation.
References
Ahking, F. W., and S. M. Miller, 1985. The Relationship Between
Government Deficits, Money Growth, and Inflation. Journal of
Macroeconomics 7, 447-467.
Arnold, I. J. M., 1996. Fallacies in the Interpretation of a
European Monetary Aggregate. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 132, 753-763.
Batten, D. S., and R. W. Elafer, 1986. The Impact of International
Factors on U.S. Inflation: An Empirical Test of the Currency
Substitution Hypothesis. Southern Economic Journal 53, 400-412.
Boyd, J., 1989. Economic Beat. New York Journal of Commerce.
Caines, P. E., C. W. Keng, and S. P. Sethi, 1981. Causality
Analysis and Multivariate Autoregressive Modeling with an Application to
Supermarket Sales Analysis. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 3,
267-298.
Cooley, T. F., and S. F. LeRoy, 1985. A Theoretical
Macroeconometrics: A Critique. Journal of Monetary Economics 16,
283-308.
Cuddington, J. T., 1983. Currency Substitution, Capital Mobility,
and Money Demand. Journal of International Money and Finance 2, 111-333.
Darrat, A. F., 1985a. Are Budget Deficits and Wage Costs Prime
Determinants of Inflation? Another Look at the Evidence from the United
States and the United Kingdom. Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics 7,
177-192.
-----, 1985b. The Impact of Fiscal Policy Under Rational
Expectations. Journal of Macroeconomics 7, 553-565.
-----, 1986. The Economic Impact of Taxes in the US: Some Tests
Based on the St. Louis Model. Journal of Economic Studies 13, 3-13.
-----, 1988. Have Large Budget Deficits Caused Rising Trade
Deficits? Southern Economic Journal 54, 879-887.
-----, and S. W. Barnhart, 1989. Federal Deficits and Money Growth
in the United States: A Vector Autoregressive Analysis. Journal of
Banking and Finance 13, 137-149.
Dornbusch, R., and S. Fischer, 1987. Macroeconomics, Fourth
Edition, McGraw Hill Inc., New York.
Engle, R. F., and C. W. J. Granger, 1987. Co-Integration and Error
Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing. Econometrica 55,
25-276.
Evans, P., 1986. Is the Dollar High Because of Large Budget
Deficits? Journal of Monetary Economics 18, 227-249.
Feldstein, M., 1995. Lower Deficits, Lower Dollar. Wall Street
Journal, May 16.
Glassman, J. E., 1985. The Influence of Exchange Rate Movements on
Inflation in the United States. Working Paper Series No. 46, Federal
Reserve Board of Governors.
Gonzalo, J., 1994. Five Alternative Methods of Estimating Long-Run
Equilibrium Relationships. Journal of Econometrics 60, 203-233.
Granger, C. W. J., 1980. Testing for Causality. Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control 2, 320-352.
-----, 1988. Some Recent Developments in the Concept of Causality.
Journal of Econometrics 54, 199-211.
Hafer, R. W., 1989. Does Dollar Depreciation Cause Inflation?
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review 71, 16-28.
Hakkio, C. S. and J. G. Whittaker, 1985. The U.S. Dollar-Recent
Developments, Outlook, and Policy Options. Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Economic Review, 3-15.
Johansen, D., 1988. Statistical Analysis of Cointegrated Vectors.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12, 231-254.
-----, 1995. Likelihood-Based Inference in Cointegrated Vector
Autoregressive Models. Oxford University Press, New York.
Jones, J. D., and D. Joulfaian, 1991. Federal Government
Expenditures and Revenues in the Early Years of the American Republic:
Evidence from 1792 to 1860. Journal of Macroeconomics 14, 133-155.
Kholdy, S., and A. Sohrabian, 1990. Exchange Rates and Prices:
Evidence from Granger Causality Tests. Journal of Post-Keynesian
Economics 13, 71-78.
Krugman, P., 1995. Why Higher Savings May Hit the Dollar. Financial
Times.
Lupoletti, W. and R. Webb, 1986. Defining and Improving the
Accuracy of Macroeconomic Forecast: Contributions from a VAR Model.
Journal of Business 59, 263-285.
Lutkepohl, H., 1982. Non-Causality Due to Omitted Variables.
Journal of Econometrics 19, 367-378.
Miller, S. M., 1991. Monetary Dynamics: An Application of
Cointegration and Error-Correction Modeling. Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking 23, 139-154.
Mizen, P., and E. J. Pentecost, 1946. The Impact of Intra-European
Trade on Sterling Currency Substitution. Weltwirschafthiches Archiv 132,
160-170.
Modigliani, F., and L. D. Papademos, 1980. The Structure of
Financial Markets and the Monetary Mechanism, in Controlling the
Monetary Aggregates III, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston.
Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff, 1996. Foundations of International
Macroeconomics. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Osterwald-Lenum, M. 1992. A Note with Quantiles of the Asymptotic
Distribution of the ML Cointegration Rank Test Statistics, Oxford
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 54, 461-472.
Phillips, M. M., 1998. Oil-Price Rise Isn't Expected to Damp
Economy. The Wall Street Journal 24, A2.
Runkle, D. E., 1987. Vector Autoregressions and Reality. Journal of
Business and Economic Statistics 28, 177-180.
Schwert, G. W., 1987. Effects of Model Specification on Tests for
Unit Roots in Macroeconomic Data. Journal of Monetary Economics, 73-103.
Sims, C. A., 1980. Macroeconomics and Reality. Econometrica 48,
148.
_____, 1982 Policy Analysis with Econometric Models. Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity 1, 107-52.
Solomon, R., 1985. Effects of the Strong Dollar. Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City, Economic Review, 65-88.
Spencer, D. E., 1989. Does Money Matter? The Robustness of Evidence
from Vector Autoregressions. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 21,
442-454.
Thornton, D. L., and D. S. Batten; 1985. LagLength Selection and
Tests of Granger-Causality Between Money and Income. Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking 17, 164-178.
Todd, R. M., 1990. Vector Autoregression Evidence on Monetarism:
Another Look at the Robustness Debate. Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, Quarterly Review 14, 19-37.
Whitt, J. A., P. D. Koch, and J. A. Rosensweig, 1986. The Dollar
and Prices: An Empirical Analysis. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta,
Economic Review 71, 4-18.
Woo, W. T., 1984. Exchange Rates and the Prices of Nonfood, Nonfuel
Products. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity No 2, 511-530.
Yarbrough, B. V., and R. M. Yarbrough, 1997. The World Economy,
Trade and Finance. Fourth Edidon. The Dryden Press, Fort Worth Texas.
TABLE 1
Cointegration result from the Johansen approach
[lambda]-
Trace
Null Alternative Test
Hypothesis Hypothesis Statistic
r=0 r[greater than or equal to]1 115.17 (*)
r[less than or equal to]1 r[greater than or equal to]2 63.50
r[less than or equal to]2 r[greater than or equal to]3 33.49
r[less than or equal to]3 r[greater than or equal to]4 13.67
r[less than or equal to]4 r[greater than or equal to]5 2.92
r[less than or equal to]5 r=6 0.02
[lambda]- [lambda]-
Trace Max
Null Alternative Test
Hypothesis C.V.(95%) Hypothesis Statistic
r=0 94.15 r=1 51.67 (*)
r[less than or equal to]1 68.52 r=2 30.01
r[less than or equal to]2 47.21 r=3 19.82
r[less than or equal to]3 29.68 r=4 10.75
r[less than or equal to]4 15.41 r=5 2.91
r[less than or equal to]5 3.76 r=6 0.02
[lambda]-
Max
Null
Hypothesis C.V.(95%)
r=0 39.37
r[less than or equal to]1 33.46
r[less than or equal to]2 27.07
r[less than or equal to]3 20.97
r[less than or equal to]4 14.07
r[less than or equal to]5 5.76
Note: Maximum lag in the Johansen test is 12, and the appropriate
AIC-based lag is lag is 7. The critical values come from Osterwald-Lenum
(1992, Table 1). The deterministic components are chosen by the Pantula
Principal which dictated the exclusion of the linear trend from both the
cointegrating relationship and the short-run model with an intercept
only in the short-run model. Nevertheless, the results are robust with
different lags and deterministic components. An (*)indicates rejection
of the null hypothesis (in favor of the corresponding alternative) at
the 5 percent significance level.
TABLE 2
Log-likelihood ration test statistics of implied Granger-causality
hypotheses (Derived from the off-diagonal elements of the VECM
maintained model)
LR Test Degrees of
Null Hypothesis Statistics Freedom
DI Equation
(1) [[beta].sub.12](L) = 0 8.88 (**) 2
(2) [[beta].sub.14](L) = 0 9.59 (**) 4
(3) [[beta].sub.16](L) = 0 13.83 (**) 3
(4) [[lambda].sub.1] = 0 9.33 (**) 1
DE Equation
(5) [[beta].sub.23](L) = 0 6.55 4
(6) [[beta].sub.24](L) = 0 13.95 (**) 5
(7) [[lambda].sub.2]2 = 0 0.32 1
DR Equation
(8) [[beta].sub.31](L) = 0 30.46 (**) 6
(9) [[beta].sub.32](L) = 0 3.04 (*) 1
(10) [[beta].sub.34](L) = 0 10.18 (**) 3
(11) [[beta].sub.35](L) = 0 3.15 (*) 1
(12) [[beta].sub.36](L) = 0 52.77 (**) 13
(13) [[lambda].sub.3] =0 6.22 (**) 1
DB Equation
(14) [[beta].sub.43](L) = 0 23.56 (**) 3
(15) [[lambda].sub.4] =0 0.03 1
DE Equation
(16) [[beta].sub.52](L) = 0 8.55 (**) 3
(17) [[beta].sub.54](L) 0 2.58 1
(18) [[beta].sub.56](L) = 0 17.01 (**) 8
(19) [[lambda].sub.5] =0 23.38 (**) 1
DX Equation
(20) [[beta].sub.61](L) = 0 2.63 1
(21) [[beta].sub.63](L) = 0 22.77 (**) 5
(22) [[beta].sub.65](L) = 0 22.82 (**) 7
(23) [lambda] = 0 9.34 (**) 1
Notes: See notes to Table 1. The superscripts in the log polynomials
(equal to the degrees of freedom) are omitted for clarity. An
(*) indicates rejection of the null hypothesis of noncausality at the
five percent level of significance, while (**) indicates rejection at
the one percent level.