TEACHING INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE USING COMPUTER SPREADSHEETS.
Gregorowicz, Philip ; Hegji, Charles E.
Philip Gregorowicz [*]
Charles E. Hegji [*]
The possibility of the use of computer spreadsheet models as an aid
to teaching economics is clearly established. The work of Smith and
Smith (1988), Smith and Ellis (1990), Clark and Hegji (1997) and others
clearly demonstrates that computer spreadsheets can be used to model
standard micro economic concepts such as marginal revenue, marginal
cost, and value of marginal product. Hegji (1998) has shown that
managerial economics topics such as determining the firm's optimal
level of advertising can be readily modeled with computer spreadsheets.
The present paper builds on this approach by developing examples in
which computer spreadsheets can be used to enhance the teaching of
international economics and finance.
The importance of using computer spreadsheets to teach
international economics comes from two sources. First, there has been a
growing interest in international economics by the teaching profession.
This is suggested by the increased international coverage in most
principles of economics texts written since 1990. Second, the authors
believe that topics covered in international trade and finance are
difficult for most students. The idea of modeling international
economics topics with computer spreadsheets is that this approach allows
students to learn through experimentation. We are convinced that a
hands-on approach is an effective way to teach such material.
With this in mind, the present paper develops several examples of
how computer spreadsheets can be used as an aid in teaching
international economics. The choice has been made based on the
authors' experiences.
Using Supply and Demand Curves to Determine Exports and Imports in
a Two Country Model
The following example was adapted from Managerial Economics:
Theory, Applications, and Cases by Edwin Mansfield. A two-country model
is assumed, with supply and demand curves for a single product specified
for each country. The object of the exercise is to determine imports and
exports for both countries.
Suppose that the supply (s) and demand (d) curves for a product
manufactured and purchased in both the United States (u) and Germany (g)
are given by
[[Q.sup.u].sub.s] = 5 + 2.6[P.sub.u],
[[Q.sup.u].sub.d] = 100 - 2[P.sub.u],
[[Q.sup.g].sub.s] = 2 + 2[P.sub.g],
[[Q.sup.g].sub.d] = 120 - 4[P.sub.g]. (1)
Prices in the United States are measured in $, while prices in
Germany are in DDM.
Solution to above problem requires an exogenous exchange rate.
Given this exchange rate, prices can be converted to a single currency.
Given this conversion, the "law of one price" is invoked by
equating worldwide supply and demand, and solving for the worldwide
equilibrium price and quantity. Substituting this price into (1) obtains
the quantities supplied and demanded in the two countries. These
quantities can, in turn, be used to determine if a country is a net
exporter or importer of the good.
Suppose that the exchange rate is e = 1.6 DM/$. This implies that
[P.sub.g] = l.6[P.sub.u]. Substituting into (1), and letting
[[Q.sup.u].sub.s] + [[Q.sup.g].sub.s] = [[Q.sup.u].sub.d] +
[[Q.sup.g].sub.d], (2)
results in an equilibrium price [P.sub.u], = $15 = 24 DM =
[P.sub.g]. With these prices, the US demands 70 units of the above good
and supplies 44 units. Germany demands 24 units and supplies 50 units.
Therefore, the US imports 26 units and Germany exports 26 units.
An important concept for students to grasp is how these net export
and import positions change with the exchange rate. The spreadsheet in
Example 1 is set up to do this.
The exchange rate in DM/$ is entered into one cell in Column A of
the spreadsheet. This exchange rate is used in the formulas in the
remainder of the spreadsheet. The $ price of the good is entered in Col
B, with US demand and supply expressed as a function of this price in
Cols C and D. Demand equation (1) is used for this computation. The DM
equivalent of this price is computed in Col B, using the exchange rate
in A. German demand and supply for the good are computed using this
price. World demand is computed as the sum of US demand and German
demand, while world supply is computed as the sum of the two
countries' supplies. Excess supply in the world market is computed
in Col J, while US and German exports are computed in Cols K and L as
the difference between supply and demand in the two countries
respectively.
For a given exchange rate, equilibrium in the world market is
approximated by the smallest absolute value of world excess supply. This
is 1.5 in Example 1. Reading across this row obtains supply and demand
in the two countries, the equilibrium prices in the two currencies, and
US and German net exports of the good.
The spreadsheet can be used to aid the teaching of international
economics in several ways. Three of these are:
* To demonstrate to the student how exports, imports, and prices
are impacted by the exchange rate
* To demonstrate how tariffs and quotas alter the relationship
between exchange rates, prices, and exports and imports
* To demonstrate how changes in costs and the resulting shifts in
supplies in the two countries change exports, imports, and equilibrium
prices, holding the exchange rate constant
Lectures, in-class exercises, and homework could be designed using
Spreadsheet 1 to examine the above three points.
Determining Domestic and Foreign Production and Prices at the Firm
Level
A topic not covered in standard treatments of international trade
is how the firm determines output and prices in domestic and foreign
markets. A related topic is how foreign production impacts the firm. The
following example develops spreadsheets to study these topics.
Begin by assuming a firm produces a product at constant unit costs
of $40. The firm is assumed to face two demand curves, one in the
domestic (D) market, and one in the foreign (F) market. Domestic prices
are measured in $, while foreign prices are denominated in foreign
currency units #. The demand curves are, respectively,
[P.sub.D] = $200 - 2[Q.sub.D]
[P.sub.F] = #600 - 8[Q.sub.F] (2)
Assume that the exchange rate is denominated in dollars per foreign
currency unit, e = $/#. The problem is to see how changes in e impact
the firm's decisions. This can be answered by using the theory of
price discrimination (pricing in two markets) assuming the firm
maximizes total $ profits.
Theory suggests that a single product should be priced in two
markets so that the marginal revenue from each market is the same.
Expressing total domestic revenue as [TR.sub.D] = [P.sub.D][Q.sub.D] and
total $ foreign revenue as [TR.sub.F] = [eP.sub.F][Q.sub.F], and
substituting from (2) results in the marginal revenues
[MR.sub.D] = 200 - 4[Q.sub.D]
[MR.sub.F] = e(600 - 16[Q.sub.F]) (3)
Equating the marginal revenues in (3) obtains
[Q.sub.F] = 125(3 - 1/e) + [Q.sub.D]/4e. (4)
Equation (4) expresses foreign sales as a function of domestic
sales and the exchange rate for the demand curves in (2). This
relationship is used in spreadsheet Example 2.
Spreadsheet 2 starts by entering the exchange rate in $/# into one
cell in Column A. This exchange rate is used in the formulas in the
remainder of the spreadsheet. Domestic sales in units are entered into
Column B, while the domestic price based on the demand curve in (2) is
in entered into Column C. Column D of the spreadsheet contains foreign
sales based on Column B and equation (4). The corresponding foreign
prices are computed in Column E. Revenue from domestic sales is
calculated from B and C, while dollar revenue from foreign sale is
computed from D, E and the exchange rate. Total costs are computed in F
by multiplying the assumed $40 unit cost by the sum of domestic and
foreign output. Profits are displayed in Column G, and computed by
subtracting total costs from the sum of domestic revenue and foreign
revenue expressed in $.
For a given exchange rate the optimal policy is determined by
maximum total profits. Example 2 shows that for the exchange rate of e =
.7$/#, profits will be maximized at $9646. Reading across the row
obtains domestic and foreign unit sales, domestic and foreign prices,
domestic and foreign revenues, and total costs.
In Example 2 production is done entirely domestically at a cost of
$40 per unit. A simple extension would be to assume that the good must
be produced both in the US and in the foreign country. For instance, we
could assume that $20 per unit value added comes from domestic
operations and #40 per unit costs comes from foreign operations. Under
these assumptions, unit costs in dollars would be AC = $20 + e#40. This
unit cost would be used in calculating total costs in Column F of
Example 2.
Spreadsheet 2 was constructed to help managerial economics students
understand the impact that the recent devaluation of Southeast Asian
currencies had on American firms with Asian exposure. The types of
questions that can be investigated with the aid of these spreadsheets
are:
* What is the impact on firm profits when the currency of a country
in which a firm has revenue exposure is devalued?
* How are profits modified when some of the production of a product
occurs in the country with the devalued currency?
Lectures, in-class exercises, and homework can be designed using
Spreadsheet 2 to examine the above points.
Concluding Remarks
The authors believe that the use of computer spreadsheets is a good
way of stimulating class participation and getting students to inquire into issues on their own, particularly in the difficult areas of
international economics and finance. We have had some success with
Examples 1 and 2 and plan on doing more work along these lines. We
encourage others to follow.
(*.) Professors of Economics, Auburn University at Montgomery,
Montgomery, AL 36117-3596.
References
Hegji, Charles E. (1998) A spreadsheet application of Dorfman and
Steiner's rule for optimal advertising, Managerial and Decision
Economics.
Kotler, P. (1983). Marketing decision making: a model-building
approach, New York: Harper and Row Publishers.
Lilien, G. L., & P. Kotler (1988). Marketing management:
analysis, planning, implementation, and control, sixth edition,
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc.
Lilien, G. L., P. Kotler, & K. S. Moorthy (1992). Marketing
models, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc.
Mankiw, N. Gregory (1997). Principles of economics, New York: The
Dryden Press.
Mansfield, E. (1999). Managerial economics: theory. applications,
and cases, fourth edition, New York: W. W. Norton and Company.
Smith, L. M. & L. C. Smith, (1988). Teaching microeconomics with microcomputer spreadsheets, Journal of Economic Education, 19,
363-382.
Smith, L. M., L. C. Smith, & S. Ellis, (1990). Some
applications of microcomputer software in teaching economic theory: a
new math. Unpublished manuscript.