Monetary announcement and commodity price dynamics: a portfolio balance model.
Hu, Shih-wen ; Lai, Ching-chong ; Wang, Vey 等
I. Introduction
Over the last two decades, there have appeared a number of studies
concerning the dynamic adjustment of commodity prices from both
theoretical and empirical viewpoints.' Among the literature, Van
Duyne (1979) presents a portfolio balance model, and analyzes how
commodity prices will react as the economy experiences a bad harvest and
a commodity speculation. Frankel (1986) sets up a macroeconomic model,
which can be treated as an application of the Dornbusch (1976) model,
and finds that agricultural product prices will display an overshooting following an unanticipated expansion in money supply. There are however
at least two points ignored in the Frankel (1986) analysis. First, some
empirical studies including Frankel and Hardouvelis (1985) and Barnhart (1989), indicate that the commodity prices will react following the
policy announcement but prior to the policy implementation. Second, the
interaction linking the disequilibrium in the agricultural product
market to the stock of agricultural products, which Van Duyne (1979)
emphasizes, is not modelled.
This paper attempts to construct a portfolio balance model to
capture the linkage between the flow and stock of agricultural products?
We will portray an economy with the following features: market
participants form their expectations with perfect foresight; the economy
produces two kinds of goods: agricultural products and manufactured
products; and the public hold three financial assets: money, bonds, and
agricultural products? based on such a framework, we try to shed light
on how the pre-announcement monetary policy will govern the transitional
adjustment of commodity prices.
The rest of the paper is arranged as follows. The structure of the
model is outlined in section II. The adjustment of commodity prices in
response to announced monetary expansion is examined in section III.
Finally, section IV summarizes the main findings of the paper.
II. The Theoretical Framework
Basically, the framework we shall develop can be treated as a
modified Van Duyne (1979) model, which is a portfolio balance model of
the financial sector. The model is now popular in the macroeconomic
setting, and its origin should be attributed to Tobin (1969).
Specifically, we consider a closed economy in which: (i) two types of
goods, namely agricultural products (or "auction products")
and manufactured products (or "customer products"), are
produced in the economy; (ii) there are three assets held by domestic
residents: money, bonds, and agricultural goods, and these assets are
regarded as gross substitutes; (iii) market agents form their
expectations with perfect foresight.
In accordance with the above description of the economy, the model
can be specified by the following macroeconomic relationships:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (1)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (2)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (3)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (4)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (5)
W = M + B + [P.sub.c],C (6)
where [D.sup.n] = demand for manufactured products; [P.sub.n] =
price of manufactured products; [P.sub.c] = price of agricultural goods;
[X.sup.n] = supply of manufactured products; m = the desired portfolio
share of the residents' financial wealth on money balance; r =
interest rate, k = the difference between the convenience yield and the
storage costs; W = nominal wealth; M = nominal money supply; b = the
desired portfolio share of the residents' financial wealth on
bonds; B = supply of domestic bonds; c = the desired portfolio share of
the residents' financial wealth on agricultural products; C = stock
of agricultural products; [X.sup.c] = supply of agricultural products;
[D.suP.x] = demand for agricultural products. An overdot indicates the
rate of change with respect to time.
Equation (1) is the equilibrium condition for the manufactured good
market. The equilibrium condition for money, bonds, and agricultural
products, which are imperfect substitutes for each other, is given
respectively by equations (2)-(4). As specified in all portfolio balance
models, they require that available stocks of money, bonds, and
agricultural products equal stock demands for three assets. The demands
for these three assets are proportional to the wealth where the shares
add up to unity. Furthermore, the allocation of portfolios among three
assets depends upon the return on holding bonds r and the return on
holding agricultural (auction) goods [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Equation (5) specifies that the stock of agricultural products will
change over time as there is a flow excess supply of agricultural
products. This specification is similar to those in Van Duyne (1979) and
Baland (1993).
Equation (6) defines that the nominal wealth of the domestic
residents is the sum of the nominal value of three assets they hold. It
is clear from equations (2)-(4) and (6) that the relations [M.sub.1] +
[b.sub.1] + [c.sub.1] = 0, [m.sub.2] + [b.sub.2] + [c.sub.2] = 0, and m
+ b + c = 1 should be held at all time.
III. Dynamic Adjustment
This section examines the evolution of agricultural prices and the
stock of agricultural products when the economy experiences an announced
monetary expansion. One point should be noted at this stage. Due to the
Walras law in the asset markets, one of the market equilibrium
conditions of three assets is redundant; we thus do not explicitly deal
with the equilibrium condition for the stock market of agricultural
goods.
Without loss of generality, we assume that P = [P.sub.n] = 1 and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] initially. In addition, for saving
space, in what follows we only deal with monetary shock. Given dB = 0,
the model can then be manipulated into the following two differential
equations:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (7)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (8)
where
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (7a)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (7b)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (7c)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (8a)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (8b)
We first examine the long-run property of the model. At the
long-run equilibrium, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [P.sub.c]
and C are at their stationary levels, namely [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. By Cramer's rule,
it is a straightforward task from equations (7) and (8) to derive the
following steady-state relationship:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (9)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (10)
Equations (9) and (10) tell us that an expansion in money supply
will generate a positive effect on both agricultural commodity prices
and agricultural commodity stock. This result is familiar from
old-fashioned IS-LM analysis, even though long-run money neutrality is
standard in recent literature. The present result is consistent with the
empirical evidence found by Devadoss and Meyers (1987) and Lapp and
Smith (1992), but runs contrast with the theoretical conclusion proposed
by Frankel (1986).(5)
We now begin to trace out the dynamic behavior of the economy.
Letting [Lambda]be the characteristic root of the dynamic system and
linearing the system around the stationary equilibrium, we then have the
following characteristic equation:
[[Lambda].sup.2] ([[Omega].sub.1] + [[Omega].sub.2]) [Lambda] +
([[Omega].sub.1][[Psi].sub.2] - [[Omega].sub.2][[Psi].sub.1]) = 0 (11)
Since [[Omega].sub.1][[Psi].sub.2] = [[Omega].sub.2][[Psi].sub.1]
[less than] 0, the two characteristic roots of the dynamic system are of
opposite sign, implying the system displays the saddlepoint stability
which is common to perfect foresight models.
The dynamic behavior of the system can be described by means of a
phase diagram like Figure 1. It is clear from equations (7) and (8) that
the slopes of loci [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] are:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (12)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (13)
As indicated by the direction of the arrows in Figure 1, the lines
SS and UU represent the stable and unstable branches, respectively.(6)
As is evident, the convergent saddle path SS is always downward sloping
and must be flatter than the [Mathematical Expression Omitted] locus,
while the divergent branch UU is always upward sloping and must be
steeper than the [Mathematical Expression Omitted] schedule.
We now analyze the dynamic behavior of the economy, in which at
time t = 0 the monetary authorities announce the money supply will
experience a permanent rise from [M.sub.0] to [M.sub.1] at a specific
date t = T in the future. In both Figure 2a and Figure 2b, the initial
equilibrium, where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] intersects
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], is at [Q.sub.0]; the initial
agricultural product prices and initial level of agricultural commodity
stock are [P.sub.c0] and [C.sub.0], respectively. Upon the permanent
monetary shock, both [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] shift upwards to [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
and [Mathematical Expression Omitted], respectively; but [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] shifts by a greater distance than [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] does.(7) The new long-run equilibrium is established
at [Q.sub.*], and the results are both [P.sub.c0] and [C.sub.0] increase
to [P.sub.c*] and [C.sub.*]. In both Figure 2a and Figure 2b, we can
draw a line connecting the old steady state [Q.sub.o] and new steady
state [Q.sub.*]. This line is named the LL schedule, and it is always
upward sloping. As is evident, the relative steepness between the LL
schedule and the divergent branch UU is ambiguous. Figure 2a depicts the
situation where the LL line is steeper than the UU line, while Figure 2b
portrays the situation where the LL line is flatter than the UU line.(8)
Before we proceed to study how the economy will respond in the
presence of an anticipated monetary expansion, three points should be
addressed. First, for expository convenience, in what follows [0.sup.+]
denotes the instant after the announcement made by the monetary
authorities; [T.sup.-] and [T.sup.+] denote the instant before and after
policy implementation, respectively. Second, during the dates between
[0.sup.+] and [T.sup.-], the money supply remains at its initial level
[M.sub.0], and the point [Q.sub.0] should be treated as the reference
point to govern the dynamic adjustment of P and C. Third, since the
public become aware that the money stock will increase from [M.sub.0] to
[M.sub.1] at the moment of [T.sup.+], the economy should move to a point
exactly on the stable arm SS([M.sub.1]) at that instant of time for
ensuring the system to be convergent.
We first discuss the situation where the LL schedule is steeper
than the unstable arm UU. Under such a situation, two patterns of
adjustment possibly occur depending on the length of lead time between
policy announcement and implementation T. In Figure 2a, if T is
relatively large, at the instant of [0.sup.+], agricultural product
prices will at once increase from [P.sub.c0] to [[P.sub.c0].sup.+],
while the stock of agricultural products remains at its initial level
[C.sub.0] because it is a stock variable. In consequence, the economy
will jump from the point [Q.sub.0] to [Q.sub.0+] on impact. Since the
point [Q.sub.0+] lies vertically above the point [Q.sub.0], from
[0.sup.+] to [T.sup.-], as arrows indicate, both P and C continue to
rise, and the economy will move from [Q.sub.0+] to [Q.sub.T]. At time
[T.sup.+], as a monetary expansion is enacted, the economy exactly
reaches the point [Q.sub.T] on the convergent saddle path SS([M.sub.1]).
Subsequently, from [T.sup.+] onwards, [P.sub.c] continues to rise and C
becomes less as the domestic economy moves along the SS([M.sub.1]) locus
towards its new long-run equilibrium represented by point [Q.sub.*].
Given that the time lag between policy announcement and implementation
is relatively long, two interesting conclusions can be drawn in Figure
2a. First, in response to a pre-announced rise in money supply, the
agricultural prices will display an undershooting phenomenon. Second,
rising agricultural prices accompany an accumulation of agricultural
products during the dates prior to the monetary expansion, while rising
agricultural prices are matched by a decrease in agricultural products
after policy implementation.
However, if T is relatively short, at the instant of [0.sup.+],
agricultural product prices will immediately rise from [P.sub.c0] to
[P[prime].sub.c[0.sup.+]], while the stock of agricultural products is
fixed at [C.sub.0] because it is a stock variable. Consequently, the
economy will jump discretely from [Q.sub.0] to [Q[prime].sub.[0.sup.+]]
on impact. Since the point [Q[prime].sub.[0.sup.+]] lies vertically
above the point [Q.sub.0], from [0.sub.+]+ to [T.sup.-], as arrows
indicate, both [P.sub.c] and C continue to rise, and the economy will
move from [Q[prime].sub.[0.sup.+]] to [Q[prime].sub.T]. At time
[T.sup.+], as a monetary expansion is implemented, the economy exactly
reaches the point [Q[prime].sub.T]. on the convergent saddle path
SS([M.sub.1]). Subsequently, from [T.sub.+] onwards, P begins to fall
and C continues to accumulate as the domestic economy moves from
[Q[prime].sub.T] towards its new long-run equilibrium [Q.sub.*] along
the SS([M.sub.1]) locus. As a result, we obtain two interesting findings
under the situation where the time lag between policy announcement and
implementation is relatively short. First, in response to a preannounced
rise in money supply, the agricultural prices will overshoot their
long-run value.(9) Second, rising agricultural prices accompany an
accumulation of agricultural products during the period of time between
the announcement and realization of the monetary expansion, while
falling agricultural prices are matched by an accumulation of
agricultural products after policy implementation.
We now turn to illustrate another situation where the LL schedule
is flatter than the unstable arm UU. In Figure 2b two distinct patterns
of adjustment should be recognized corresponding to the length of the
transition period T. One possibility is that T is substantially large.
If this is the case, upon receiving the new information (t = [0.sup.+]),
agricultural product prices will immediately rise from [P.sub.c0] to
[P.sub.c0+], and the economy will jump upward from [Q.sub.0] to
[Q.sub.[0.sup.+] on impact. During the dates between [0.sup.+] and
[T.sup.-], the economy will move along the unstable branch
[Q.sub.0+][Q.sub.T]. At the instant [T.sup.+], when the monetary
expansion comes into force, the economy reaches the point [Q.sub.T] on
the saddle path SS([M.sub.1]). Thereafter, P keeps falling and C keeps
rising as the economy moves along the SS([M.sub.1]) locus from QT
towards its new stationary equilibrium [Q.sub.*]. The other possibility
is that T is substantially small. In this case, at the instant
[0.sup.+], agricultural product prices will at once rise from [P.sub.c0]
to [P[prime].sub.c]0.sup.+], while the stock of agricultural products
remains at its initial level [C.sub.0] because it is a stock variable.
In association with the discrete adjustment in [P.sub.c], the economy
will jump from the point [Q.sub.0] to [Q[prime].sub.[0.sup.+]. During
the time interval [0.sup.+] and [T.sup.-], as the arrows indicate, both
[P.sub.c] and C continue to increase, and the economy moves from
[Q[prime].sub.[0.sup.+] to [Q[prime].sub.T]. At the instant [T.sup.+],
as the monetary expansion is implemented, the economy should move to the
point [Q[prime].sub.T] which is exactly on the convergent saddle path
SS([M.sub.1]). From [T.sup.+] onwards, P continues to fall and C
continues to rise as the economy moves along the SS([M.sub.1]) schedule
from [Q[prime].sub.T] towards its new steady state [Q.sub.*]. The
results in Figure 2b reveal a fact running counter to those in Figure
2a. That is, the length of the transition date T plays a critical role
in determining whether agricultural prices will overshoot or undershoot their long-run value, but plays no role in determining the dynamic
pattern of both P and C during the post-implementation period.(10)
IV. Concluding Remarks
This paper first sets up a simple portfolio balance model, and then
investigates how commodity prices will behave as the monetary
authorities conduct a pre-announced monetary policy. Two major
conclusions emerge from the analysis. First, agricultural product prices
will rise discretely on impact but may either overshoot or undershoot
its long-run level at the instant of policy announcement. The crucial
factor for determining whether the initial jump in agricultural prices
overshoots or undershoots its long-run magnitude is the time lag between
policy announcement and implementation. Second, during the period
following the announcement but prior to the monetary expansion, rising
agricultural prices are matched by an accumulation in the stock of
agricultural products. When the monetary expansion actually takes place,
two possible patterns of adjustment may happen: rising agricultural
prices are matched by a decrease in the stock of agricultural products
and falling agricultural prices are coupled with an accumulation in the
stock of agricultural products.
Appendix
This appendix will provide a detailed mathematical derivation regarding the adjustment of commodity prices when the economy
experiences an anticipated shock. Given that [P.sub.c] = [P.sub.n] = 1
and [Mathematical Expression Omitted] initially and that B does not
change over time (i.e., dB = 0), substituting equation (6) into (1),
(2), (3), and (5) and totally differentiating the resulting equations
yield:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A1)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A2)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A3)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A5)
Putting (A2) and (A3) together to delete dr and reminding that m +
b + c = 1 and [m.sub.1] + [b.sub.1] + [c.sub.1] = 0, we have:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A6)
On the other hand. from equation (A1) we obtain:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A7)
Substituting equation (A7) into (A5) and rearranging the terms, we
have:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A8)
Equations (A6) and (A8) can be expressed by the following reduced
forms:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A9)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A10)
where
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Equations (A9) and (A10) are identical to equations (7) and (8) in
the text.
We then examine the long-ran property of the model. At the long-run
equilibrium, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [P.sub.c] and C are
at their stationary levels, namely [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. It follows from equations (A9) and
(A10) with m+b+c = 1 and [m.sub.1] + [b.sub.1] + [c.sub.1] = 0 that:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A11)
Cramer's rule generates
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A12)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A13)
Equations (A12) and (A13) repeat the results in equations (9) and
(10) in the text. For expository convenience, the above relationships
can be expressed by the following reduced forms:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A14)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A15)
For notational simplicity, define
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A16)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A17)
We now turn to discuss the dynamic nature of the system. Letting
[Lambda] be the characteristic root of the dynamic system, from
equations (A9) and (A10) we have the following characteristic equation:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A18)
Since [[Omega].sub.1][[Psi].sub.2] - [[Omega].sub.2][[Psi].sub.1]
[less than] 0, the two characteristic roots of the dynamic system,
namely [[Lambda].sub.1] and [[Lambda].sub.2], are of opposite sign,
implying the system displays the saddlepoint stability which is common
to perfect foresight models. For ease of exposition, in what follows let
[[Lambda].sub.1] be the negative root and [[Lambda].sub.2] be the
positive root (i.e., [[Lambda].sub.1] [less than] 0 less than]
[[Lambda].sub.2]).
It follows from equations (A9) and (A10) that the general solution
for [P.sub.c] and C can be written as: [see Gandolfo (1980, pp. 263-65)
and Turnovsky (1995, pp. 138-39)]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A19)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A20)
where [A.sub.1] and [A.sub.2] are unknown parameters.
In Figure 1, the stable branch SS is associated with the value
[A.sub.2] = 0 in equations (A19) and (A20), i.e., the positive
(unstable) root is excluded in the trajectory. Hence, the stable branch
satisfies the following relation:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A21)
It is clear from equation (A21) that the slope of the saddle path
SS is:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A22)
On the other hand, the unstable branch UU is associated with the
value A1 = 0 in equations (A19) and (A20), i.e., the negative (stable)
root is excluded in the trajectory. Accordingly, the unstable branch
satisfies
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A23)
The slope of the unstable branch UU thus is:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A24)
It follows from equation (A18) that the two characteristic roots
have the following relationship:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A25)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A26)
Then from equations (A25) and (A26) we have:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
The above equation can be alternatively expressed as:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A27)
Given that (1 - [[Psi].sub.2]/[[Lambda].sub.2]) [greater than] 0
and [[intersection].sub.2][[Psi].sub.1]/[[Lambda].sub.2] [greater than]
0, the requirement to satisfy equation (A27) is:
[[Lambda].sub.2] - [[Omega].sub.1] [greater than] 0 (A28)
Equations (A24) and (A28) lead us to infer:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A29)
Based on equations (A19) and (A20), we now can deal with the
evolutionary behavior of relevant variables in the presence of an
anticipated monetary expansion. The experiment we conduct is that, at
time t = 0, the monetary authorities announce that money supply will
permanently rise from MO to [M.sub.1] at a future specific date t = T.
Equipped with equations (A19) and (A20), we can use the following
equations to describe the process of such a monetary policy switch:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A30)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A31)
where [0.sup.-] and [0.sup.+] denote the instant before and after
the announcement made by the monetary authorities, [T.sup.-] and
[T.sup.+] denote the instant before and after money expansion, and
[A.sub.1], [A.sub.2], [A.sup.*], and [A.sup.*].sub.2] are undetermined
coefficients. There are some supplementary explanation for the
specification of equations (530) and (531). First, the initial money
stock is Mo and the system is assumed to be in its stationary
equilibrium initially, so that, at the instant t = [0.sup.-], [P.sub.c]
and C are equal to [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical
Expression Omitted]. Second, from [0.sup.+] to [T.sup.-], the money
stock is not yet increased, the stationary values of [P.sub.c] and C
during this time interval are associated with [M.sub.0]. Third, from
[T.sup.+] onwards, money stock has increased, the stationary values of P
and C during this period correspond to [M.sub.1].
To understand the exact time paths of [P.sub.c] and C from
[0.sup.+] to [T.sup.-] and [T.sup.+] onwards, we must determine
appropriate values for the arbitrary parameters [A.sub.1], [A.sub.2],
[[A.sup.*].sub.1], and [[A.sup.*].sup.2]. These unknown parameters can
be determined by the following conditions:
[C.sub.0] = [[C.sub.0[.sup.+] (A32)
[[C.sub.T].sup.-] = [[C.sub.T].sup.+] (A33)
[P.sub.c], [T.sup.-] = [P.sub.c], [T.sup.+] (A34)
[[A.sup.*].sub.2] = 0 (A35)
Equations (A32) and (A33) restrict the stock of agricultural
products to move continuously because C is a stock variable. Equation
(A34) is the continuity condition of the forward-looking variable P.
Equation (A35) is the transversality (stabilIty) condition; it states
that the economy should move along the saddle path after a monetary
expansion is enacted.
Substituting equations (A30), (A31), and (A35) into (A32), (A33),
and (A34) yields:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A36)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A37)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A38)
From equations (A12),(A13),(A16), and (A17) we know that:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A39)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A40)
Substituting equation (A39) into (A38) and (A40) into (A37),
equations (A36), (A37), (A38) can be rewritten as:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A41)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A42)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A43)
Applying Cramer's rule, the solutions to [A.sub.1], [A.sub.2],
and [[A.sup.*].sub.2] are:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A44)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A45)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A46)
where
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Finally, substituting the values of [A.sub.1], [A.sub.2],
[[A.sup.*].sub.1] and [[A.sup.*].sub.2] (= 0) into equations (A30) and
(A31), we can obtain the complete solutions for [P.sub.c] and C.
It is obvious from equation (A30) that, at the instant of news
arrival, [P.sub.c] will instantaneously respond by:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A47)
Substituting (A44) and (A45) into (A47) yields:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A48)
It is obvious from equation (A48) that the initial jump of
agricultural product prices depends on the length of lead time between
policy announcement and implementation T. With the limiting case T = 0,
from equations (A39) and (A48) we have:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A49)
It implies that an unanticipated rise in money supply will lead to
an overshooting in agricultural product prices.
It also can be derived from equation (A48) that:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A50)
where [T.sup.*] is the critical value of lead time. Equation (A50)
indicates that whether the initial jump of agricultural product prices
overshoots or undershoots its long-run magnitude depends on whether the
length of the transition date T is less or greater than [T.sup.*]. This
result confirms what we state in Section III.
Finally, we intend to address how the relative steepness between
both LL and UU schedules governs the dynamic behavior of C after money
expansion is realized. According to the long-run properties reported in
equations (A12), (A13), (A16), and (A17), the slope of the LL locus in
Figure 2a and Figure 2b is:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A51)
Comparing (A51) with (A29) gives
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A52)
It follows from equations (A30) and (A31) with [[A.sup.*].sub.2] =
0 that, for the period t [greater than or equal to] [T.sup.+], the
adjustment of [P.sub.c] and C is:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A53)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A54)
Due to the facts that [[Lambda].sub.1] [less than] 0,
[[Lambda].sub.1] - [[Omega].sub.1] / [[Omega].sub.2] [less than] 0, AND
[[E.suP.[Lambda][1.sup.T] [greater than] 0, it is a straightforward task
to obtain that:
For t [greater than or equal to] [t.sup.+]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A55)
Equation (A55) indicates that, when the monetary expansion actually
takes place, the adjustment patterns of C and P solely depend upon the
sign of [[A.sup.*].sub.1]. Then, it is immediately inferred from
equations (A46) and (A52) that:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A56)
Given that A [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
and [M.sub.1] - [M.sub.0] [greater than] 0, we can infer from
equations (A55) and (A56) that:
For t [greater than or equal to] [T.sup.+]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A57)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (A58)
Equation (A57) confirms the results revealed in Figure 2b. That is,
under the situation where the LL schedule is flatter than the unstable
arm UU, falling agricultural product prices are definitely coupled with
an accumulation in the stock of agricultural products during the
post-implementation period. On the other hand, equation (A58)
establishes the results depicted in Figure 2a. That is, under the
situation where the LL schedule is steeper than the unstable arm UU, two
possible patterns of adjustment may prevail during the
post-implementation period. That is, rising agricultural prices are
matched by a decrease in the stock of agricultural products and falling
agricultural prices are coupled with an accumulation in the stock of
agricultural products.
Notes
1. The related literature on this topic includes Van Duyne (1979),
Bordo (1980), Frankel and Hardouvelis (1985), Frankel (1986), Barnhart
(1989), and Moutos and Vines (1992), among many others.
2. Chambers (1984) sets out a portfolio balance model portraying
the interdependence between agricultural and financial markets. However,
Chambers (1984) confines itself to short-run analysis, and does not link
the relationship between the flow and stock of agricultural commodities.
3. Frankel (1984, p. 560) argues that "The [agricultural]
commodities are relatively homogeneous, storable, and transportable and
are traded on competitive markets." Thus, in accordance with Van
Duyne (1979), in this paper the domestic residents treat the
agricultural stock as a financial asset.
4. For a detailed explanation of the yield for holding agricultural
(auction) products, see Frankel (1986) and Moutos and Vines (1992).
5. The long-run money neutrality means that both long-run
agricultural and manufactured prices increase equiproportionately with
the monetary expansion. Frankel (1984) and Obstfeld (1986) provide a
more detailed discussion on the neutrality of money.
6. A detailed derivation of the slopes of both lines SS and UU is
provided in the Appendix.
7. It follows from equations (7) and (8) that:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Using the relations [m.sub.1] + [b.sub.1] + [c.sub.1] = 0, m + b +
c = 1, mW = M, bW = B, and cW = C (since [P.sub.c] = 1 initially), we
then have:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
8. See equations (A29), (A51), and (A52) in the Appendix for a more
detailed discussion.
9. With the limiting case T = 0, the economy will jump from
[Q.sub.0] to [Q[double prime].sub.[0.sup.+]], and an unanticipated
expansion in money supply will lead to an overshooting in agricultural
product prices.
10. Details of mathematical derivations are provided in the
Appendix.
We are grateful to an anonymous referee of this journal for
excellent guidance in revising the paper. Needless to say, any remaining
deficiencies are the authors' responsibility.
References
Agenor, P. R. and Montiel, P. J. Development Macroeconomics. New
Jersey, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996.
Baland, J. M. "Foodgrain Stocks and Macrodynamic Adjustment
Mechanisms in a Dual Semi-Industrialized Economy: A Note," Journal
of Development Economics 40 (February 1993) 171-85.
Barnhart, S. W. "The Effects of Macroeconomic Announcement on
Commodity Prices," American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71
(May 1989) 389-403.
Bordo, M. "The Effects of Monetary Change on Relative
Commodity Prices and the Role of Long-Term Contract," Journal of
Political Economy 88 (December 1980) 1088-109.
Chambers, R. G. "Agricultural and Financial Market
Interdependence in the Short Run," American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 66 (February 1984) 12-24.
Devadoss, S. and Meyers, W. H. "Relative Prices and Money:
Further Results for the United States," American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 69 (November 1987) 838-42.
Dornbusch, R. "Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics,"
Journal of Political Economy 84 (December 1976) 1161-76.
Frankel, J. A. "Commodity Prices and Money: Lessons from
International Finance," American Journal of Agricultural Economics
66 (December 1984) 560-66.
Frankel, J. A. "Expectations and Commodity Price Dynamics: The
Overshooting Model," American Journal of Agricultural Economics 68
(May 1986) 344-48.
Frankel, J. A. and Hardouvelis, G. A. "Commodity Prices, Money
Surprises, and Fed Credibility," Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking 17 (November 1985) 425-37.
Gandolfo, G. Economic Dynamics: Methods and Models. Amsterdam:
North-Holland, 1980.
Lapp, J. S. and Smith, V. H. "Aggregate Sources of Relative
Price Variability among Agricultural Commodities," American Journal
of Agricultural Economics 74 (February 1992) 1-9.
Moutos, T. and Vines, D. "Output, Inflation and Commodity
Prices," Oxford Economic Papers 44 (July 1992) 355-72.
Obstfeld, M. "Overshooting Agricultural Commodity Markets and
Public Policy," American Journal of Agricultural Economics 68 (May
1986) 420-21.
Tobin, J. "A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary
Policy," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 1 (February 1969)
15-29.
Turnovsky, S. J. Methods of Macroeconomic Dynamics. Massachusetts,
Cambridge: The MIT Press, 1995.
Van Duyne, C. "The Macroeconomic Effects of Commodity Market
Disruptions in Open Economies," Journal of International Economics
9 (November 1979) 559-82.
Shih-wen Hu, Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Feng
Chia University, Talchung, Taiwan.
Ching-chong Lai, Research Fellow, Sun Yat-Sen Institute for Social
Sciences and Philosophy, Academia Sinica, Taipei, and the Dean of the
College of Business, Feng Chia University, Taichung, Taiwan.
Vey Wang, Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Feng Shia
University, Taichung, Taiwan.