Sectoral shocks and unemployment rate fluctuations.
Elias, Carlos G.
I - Introduction
One of the basic problems in macroeconomics has been to provide
explanations for aggregate business fluctuations. In the classical model
the level of production is determined by exogenous tastes and
technology. The basic assumption is that the economy is populated by
self-interest agents who leave no opportunity for mutual gain
unexploited. Price and wage flexibility is the outcome of such an
economy. If aggregate demand falls and output falls below the potential
GNP, firms with excess capacity will reduce prices to stimulate sales.
If demand rises and output increases above the potential GNP, prices
will increase thereby reducing sales and consequently output. In this
economy any deviation of output from potential GNP will be temporary.
Furthermore, fiscal and monetary policies are completely unnecessary to
restore the long run equilibrium.
In the Keynesian model, wage and price rigidity could cause the
economy to operate in a suboptimal position. In this case, government
intervention in the economy is necessary to restore long term
equilibrium whenever the economy is trapped in a low output, high
unemployment situation.
The basic line of research for classical economists was to explain
how business fluctuations were possible in a world with flexible prices
and full employment. The rational expectations school assumed as valid
the classical assumption of price-wage flexibility. However, they
assumed also that expectations are formed rationally (i.e., using all
available information). In this case, expected monetary shocks will have
no effect on output but an unexpected shock may cause output to deviate
from the potential GNP. This, of course, could be used to explain
business cycles. One problem remains; given that only unexpected shocks
could cause deviations from potential GNP, and unexpected shocks are
completely random, the deviations should be random with an expected
value equal to zero. Thus no persistent cycles should be observable. In
reality, business cycles do not behave like that. Business cycle
research has found a high degree of persistence in GNP data.(1)
The research also suggests that there is comovement (a tendency to
move together) among different sectors in the economy. Comovement was a
major problem in the original formulation of the classical model. In the
original classical formulation the result of a decline in consumption
was an increase in the total amount of savings in the economy. This
additional savings will reduce interest rates and, keeping everything
else constant, stimulate investment. In this case a recession will be
avoided but no comovement is observed, and consumption and investment
will move in different directions. Keynes suggested that it is
contradictory for firms to increase investment expenditure if they
observe consumption falling. An increase in investment implies
increasing production capacity but consumers are buying less not more;
therefore less capacity is needed.
Real Business Cycle (RBC) models try to explain comovement and
persistence within the classical framework by arguing that business
cycles are mainly caused by technological shocks.(2) Long and Plosser(3)
have shown that even with sector specific technological disturbances it
is possible to have comovement in output.
A major drawback of RBC models is they fail to explain the role of
unemployment fluctuations in the economy. An important assumption in RBC
is intertemporal substitution. That is, how responsive in terms of hours
worked are employees to changes in wages. An adverse technological shock
will decrease demand for labor and reduce both real wages and
employment, but due to wage flexibility labor demand and supply will
equilibrate. Thus the unemployment rate does not have to change in the
presence of sectoral shocks.
Cooper and Haltiwanger (1990) found that sectoral shocks with RBC
assumptions do not lead to comovement among employment in different
sectors. However, if sectoral shocks occur in the presence of imperfect
competition, employments in different sectors will tend to move
together. The data examined by Cooper and Haltiwanger suggests that
there is comovement in employment among sectors. Therefore they imply
that some imperfection or rigidity is present in the labor market.
The main topic of this paper is to analyze the relative importance
of productivity shocks on unemployment rate fluctuations. Sectoral
shocks can cause comovement if there are spillover effects to other
sectors. It is clear that an adverse shock will reduce employment in the
sector where the shock occurs. An adverse technological shock will
reduce the demand for labor. Employment will be reduced in the presence
of the Keynesian assumption of wage rigidity and also in the presence of
the RBC assumption of wage flexibility with a fiat labor supply. The
response of the unemployment rate will be very different. In the
presence of wage rigidity the unemployment rate will increase; while
under the RBC assumption, the unemployment rate will be mostly
unaffected. For this reason, if sectoral shocks are important in the
fluctuations of the unemployment rate, this would give support to the
Cooper and Haltiwanger hypothesis that some type of imperfection is
present in the market.
The reduction in employment will have two effects on the other
sectors: on the one hand it will increase the relative price of the good
in question, increasing the demand for products of other sectors; on the
other hand the consequent reduction in income will tend to reduce
production and employment in other sectors. If the income effect is
sufficiently big we will see comovement of employment in different
sectors. If the substitution effect is bigger than the income effect,
comovement will not be observed.
In this paper, a vector autoregressive model (VAR) for unemployment
in different sectors and for the unemployment rate is estimated. From
the assumptions made, it will be possible to identify the shocks and
measure the importance of sectoral shocks using variance decomposition.
In Section II a simple theoretical model will be developed, In Section
III the model will be estimated to measure the relative importance of
sectoral shocks on the unemployment rate. Section IV summarizes major
findings and conclusions.
II - The Model
A major recent feature of employment in industrialized nations has
been the secular shift from manufacturing to services. Although
employment is growing over time, on average, in all sectors, the share
of employment in manufacturing has been declining over time. In general
this shift in employment is due to the fact that productivity grows
faster in the manufacturing sector while the demand for services is
growing faster that the demand for manufactured goods.(4) Abraham and
Katz (1986) show that employment in the manufacturing sector responds
more to the business cycle than does employment in the services sector.
In this model there will be a sectoral shock and a labor supply shock
affecting the manufacturing sector. It will be assumed that service
sector employment will not be subject to a sectoral shock.
The first assumption that will be made is that sectoral shocks will
have a permanent effect of the level of employment in a given sector.
Aggregate monetary shocks will have a temporary effect on the level of
employment. None of the shocks will have a permanent effect on the
unemployment rate.(5) This assumption, together with the trend explained
in the previous paragraph, will be enough to identify the shocks.
The economy will be divided into two sectors, manufacturing (m) and
services (s). The long run level of employment in manufacturing will be
determined by sector specific technological shocks, labor supply and
product demand. The long run level of employment in the manufacturing
sector evolves according to the following equation:(6)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (1)
Where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is the long rum level of
employment in manufacturing, [[Phi].sup.m](L) is an infinite lag
polynomial(7) and [[Epsilon].sup.m] is the productivity shock in the
manufacturing sector. It is expected that an adverse productivity shock
will depress the employment in the manufacturing sector.
The long run evolution of the labor supply will be determined by
the following equation:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (2)
A positive labor supply shock is expected to increase the labor
supply.
In the short run the level of employment in each sector can deviate
from the long run level (equation 1) because of the transitory adjustment of productivity shocks and aggregate monetary shocks.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (4)
Taking first differences of equation (4) and using (1) will
produce:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (5)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (6)
For the services sector:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (7)
Taking first differences of equation (7) and using (1), (2) and (4)
we find:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (8)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (9)
It will be assumed that the unemployment rate will be affected by
three types of shocks: A monetary aggregate demand shock ([[Mu].sub.t]),
a productivity shock from manufacturing [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] and a labor supply shock [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
None of the shocks have permanent effects on the unemployment rate.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (10)
The system will consist of the following equations:
[Y.sub.t] = [summation of] A([Tau])[e.sub.t-[Tau]] where [Tau] = 0
to [infinity] (11)
Where:(8)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression
Omitted]
or:
[Y.sub.t] = A(L)[e.sub.t] (12)
A(L) is a matrix that is derived from the lag polynomials
[[Phi].sup.m](L), [[Phi].sup.l](L). Following Shapiro and Watson (1988),
I will identify the shocks by using the long run multipliers matrix
A(1). It is clear from equations (6), (9) and (10) that A(1) will be a
lower triangular.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
III-Estimation Procedure and Results
One of the main assumptions of this paper is that variables follow
a random walk. It is then necessary to test the hypothesis of unit root
to the variables.[9] We test the hypothesis that [Gamma] = 0 in equation
(13) below.
[Delta][X.sub.t] = [Alpha] + [Beta]t + [Gamma][X.sub.t-1] +
[summation of] [[Delta].sub.i][Delta][X.sub.t-i] where i = 1 to p +
[u.sub.t] (13)
Where t is a trend and [u.sub.t] is white noise.
The results of the estimation of the equation (13) are shown in
Tables 1-3. This is done for the employment series in the manufacturing
and services sectors and for the seasonally adjusted unemployment rate.
The null hypothesis is that [Gamma] = 0; the alternative is that [Gamma]
[less than] 0.(10)
The t statistic in Tables 1-3 can be used to test [H.sub.0]:[Gamma]
= 0 vs. [H.sub.1]: [Gamma] [less than] 0.(11) The critical value of t at
the 5% confidence level is -2.87. (See Fuller (1979) pp. 373.) Using
this test, we can accept the null hypothesis of unit root.
TABLE 1
Estimated equation (13) for employment in manufacturing
Estimated equation with
dependent variable [Delta]Manuf
Variable
or
Statistic (1) (2)
Constant .148 .096
(1.9) (1.65)
Manuf(-1) -.02 -.010
(-1.9) (-1.64)
[Delta]Manuf(-1) .397 .490
(8.66) (0)
[Delta]Manuf(-2) .209
(4.58)
[R.sup.-2] .27 .24
DW 2.03 2.19
The t statistics are shown in parentheses.
TABLE 2
Estimated equation (13) for employment in services
Estimated equation with
dependent variable [Delta]Serv
Variable
or
Statistic (1) (2)
Constant -.005 -.005
(-.93) (-1.19)
Serv(-1) .001 .0006
(1.40) (1.75)
[Delta]Serv(-1) .186 .222
(4.11) (4.98)
[Delta]Serv(-2) .164
(3.63)
[R.sup.-2] .079 .055
DW 2.07 2.07
TABLE 3
Estimated equation (13) for unemployment
Estimated equation with
dependent variable [Delta]Unemplsa
Variable
or
Statistic (1) (2)
Constant .048 .036
(2.42) (2.24)
Un(-1) -.028 -.021
(-2.42) (-2.23)
[Delta]Un(-1) .060 .062
(1.28) (1.33)
[Delta]Un(-2) .147
(3.13)
[R.sup.-2] .027 .009
DW 2.01 2.02
Given our assumptions, equation can be rewritten:
[B.sub.p](L)[Y.sub.t] = [e.sub.t] (14)
Where [B.sub.p](L) is a finite lag polynomial of order p and A(L) =
[[[B.sub.p](L)].sup.-1].
The objective will be to estimate the VAR coefficients of (14) and
then estimate the contribution of the different shocks to the
unemployment rate.(12) One problem mentioned by Blanchard and Quah is
that the unemployment rate is not stationary. The answer to this problem
is not trivial. If the unemployment rate is subject to hysteresis, an
aggregate monetary shock can have permanent effects.(13) Because this
does not seem to be very important to U.S. data, a trend variable is
included in the VAR estimation to account for it. However, the results
are similar with or without the trend.
The data used to estimate the model is employment in the
manufacturing(14) and services(15) sectors, monthly and seasonally
adjusted. The sample period is from January 1948 to December 1987.(16)
(The level of employment is measured in number of workers. This is the
appropriate measure if we want to analyze the effects of sectoral shocks
on unemployment rate fluctuations.)
Figures 1-2 show the impulse response function of shocks in
manufacturing, and on the unemployment rate.(17) Figure 1 shows the
effect of sectoral manufacturing shock on the three endogenous variables in equation (10) (employment in manufacturing, employment in services
and unemployment rate). Figure 2 shows the effect of a monetary shock on
the same three endogenous variables. I am going to concentrate on the
effect on the aggregate unemployment rate (UNEMPLSA).
In Figure 1 it is observed that a sectoral manufacturing shock will
have a perceptible impact on the unemployment rate. This effect is small
initially but increases steadily until the ninth month. After the ninth
month the effect of the sectoral manufacturing shock decreases and is
almost completely eliminated by the thirty-fifth month. This result
suggests that sectoral shocks are important on aggregate unemployment.
The impact tends to completely disappear three years after the initial
shock.
Figure 2 shows the effect of the aggregate monetary shock.(18) The
effect of this shock on unemployment is large initially but decreases
steadily over the sample and is almost completely eliminated by the
thirtieth month. This suggests that a monetary shock has an important
effect on the unemployment rate in the first months, but it loses
importance until it is completely eliminated two and a half years after
the initial shock.
TABLE 4
Estimation results
Dependent variable
Manuf1 Serv1 Unemplsa
Ind. Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient
Variable (t stat.) (t stat.) (t stat.)
Manuf1(-1) .31 .07 -1.54
(6.15) (3.9) (-3.27)
Manuf1(-2) .10 .04 -1.28
(1.88) (2.4) (-2.7)
Manuf1(-3) .02 .01 -.51
(.30) (.4) (-1.1)
Manuf1(-4) .07 .002 -.30
(1.34) (.2) (-.7)
Serv1(-1) .08 -.01 -1.24
(.61) (-.15) (-1.0)
Serv1 (-2) .12 .003 -2.13
(.89) (-.06) (-1.7)
Serv1(-3) .10 .115 1.09
(.72) (.237) (.9)
Serv1(-4) .10 .10 -3.08
(.73) (2.14) (-2.4)
Unemplsa(-1) -.01 -.001 .88
(-1.72) (-.46) (18.5)
Unemplsa(-2) -.002 -.001 -.06
(-.35) (-.47) (1.02)
Unemplsa(-3) .01 .001 -.08
(1.65) (.25) (-1.36)
Unemplsa(-4) .003 .001 .08
(.72) (.70) (1.8)
Trend 0 0 0
Constant -.005 .002 .09
(-2.4) (2.21) (5.03)
[R.sup.-2] .29 .19 .97
DW 2.00 1.99 2.02
F 16.0 9.9 1154.2
Table 5 and Figure 3 show the variance decomposition of a shock to
the unemployment rate. The aggregate shock will drop from 93% in the
first month to 43% a year later to stabilize at 34% after five years.
The sectoral manufacturing shock on the other hand will increase from 7%
in the first month to 52% after a year to stabilize at 59% after five
years.
The impulse function suggests that both sectoral shocks and
aggregate monetary shocks play an important role in the fluctuations of
the unemployment rate. The aggregate monetary shock is especially
important in the first year and its importance diminishes over time. The
sectoral manufacturing shock increases over time until the ninth month
after the initial shock and its importance diminishes thereafter.
TABLE 5
Decomposition of Variance
Fraction of unemployment rate explained by shock to:
Month MANUF1 SERV1 UNEMPLSA S.E.
1 6.5 .56 92.9 .05
2 12.0 .95 87.0 .07
3 19.8 1.77 78.5 .09
4 26.5 1.80 71.7 .10
12 51.9 5.65 42.5 .20
24 58.5 6.87 34.7 .24
36 58.7 6.95 34.3 .24
48 58.8 6.95 34.3 .24
60 58.8 6.95 34.3 .24
The analysis of variance suggests most of the variance on the
unemployment rate is explained by aggregate shock. The manufacturing
sectoral shock initially explains less than 7% of the variance of the
unemployment rate in the first months but this effect increases over
time to explain almost 60% five years after the shock.
In order for a sectoral shock to affect the unemployment rate it
needs to propagate to other sectors. This explains the delay of the
shock on manufacturing in our analysis of variance.
IV - Conclusion
In this paper a simple vector autoregression model is estimated to
measure the importance of sectoral shocks on the unemployment rate for
the U.S. for the period 1948-1987. The main finding of the variance
decomposition suggests that shocks to the manufacturing sector are an
important source of fluctuations to the unemployment rate. This does not
imply that aggregate shocks are not important. Five years after the
shock, the aggregate shock contributes to approximately 34% of the
variance in the unemployment rate, while the manufacturing shock
contributes 59%. This last shock increases its contribution over time.
That is consistent with the theory of spillover effects.
I would like to express my appreciation for the helpful comments
ana suggestions by Mitch Charkiewicz, the faculty of Manhattan College,
and an anonymous referee. Any opinion expressed is my own and does not
necessarily reflect the opinion of the Business Market Division at
AT&T.
Notes
1. Persistence is a situation where the next period GNP is not very
different from this period value. If a variable follows a first order
autoregressive process, [y.sub.t] = [Alpha][y.sub.t-1], the coefficient
[Alpha] will serve as the persistence coefficient. An [Alpha] close to
one implies high persistence, an [Alpha] close to zero implies very low
persistence.
2. Technological shocks are shocks to the production function. An
adverse technological shock would shift down the production function
causing a reduction in the marginal productivity of labor (MPL). A basic
criticism to RBC models asks how such productivity shocks might arise in
real life. (Technological "declines" are empirically
unimportant.) Oil shocks are an obvious example, but probably not enough
to explain business cycles. The consensus among RBC theoreticians is
that small changes in the price of raw materials could generate
productivity shocks consistent with RBC assumptions. Changes in the
price of raw materials may induce firms to retire capital earlier with
the subsequent reduction in MPL.
3. See for example Long and Plosser (1983) and Long and Plosser
(1987).
4. See for example Rowthorn and Wells (1987) p. 15.
5. These are standard assumptions; see for example Shapiro and
Watson (1988) and Blanchard and Quah (1989).
6. This follows the paper by Shapiro and Watson (1988).
7. In this paper it will be assumed that the lag polynomial has
roots outside the unit circle.
8. Time subscript will be eliminated whenever possible.
9. See for example Evans (1989).
10. Tables 1-3 report the result of equation (13) using: (1) p = 2
and (2) p = 1. These equations were estimated with and without a trend;
however, only the results without a trend are reported because the trend
coefficient was insignificantly small.
11. See for example Fuller (1976) and Dickey and Fuller (1979).
12. It can be argued that the VAR estimate is not efficient because
of possible correlation between the shocks. I estimated the system using
Seemingly Unrelated Regression, but the results were not different.
13. See Blanchard and Summer (1987).
14. Manufacturing will include durable and non durable goods. The
construction employment is added to manufacturing. Only the mining
sector is left out but the level of employment in that sector is very
small.
15. The services sector will include transportation, wholesale and
retail trade, finance insurance and Real estate, and other services as
defined by the U.S. Department of Labor.
16. The sources for data for this paper are: Employment, Hours and
Earnings (Bureau of Labor Statistics), for employment in different
sectors and Labor Force Statistics Derived from the Current Population
Survey 1948-87, for unemployment rate.
17. MANUF1 is the first difference of employment in manufacturing,
SERV1 is the first difference of employment in services and UNEMPLSA is
the seasonally adjusted unemployment rate.
18. The shock to the unemployment rate equation.
References
Abraham, Katherine G. and Lawrence F. Katz, "Cyclical
Unemployment: Sectoral Shifts or Aggregate Disturbances." Journal
of Political Economy, Vol. 94., #3, p. 507-522, (1986).
Barro, Robert J., Comment on "Do Equilibrium Business Cycle
Theories Explain Postwar U.S. Business Cycles?," NBER Macroeconomics Annual, (1986).
Blanchard, Oliver J. and Lawrence H. Summers, "Hysteresis and
the European Unemployment Problem," NBER Macroeconomics Annual,
(1986).
Blanchard, Oliver J. and Lawrence H. Summers, "Hysteresis in
Unemployment," European Economic Review, Vol. 31, p. 288-295,
(1987).
Blanchard, Oliver Jean and Danny Quah, "The Dynamic Effects of
Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Disturbances," American
Economic Review, Vol. 79, #4, p. 655-673, (September 1989).
Cooper, Russel and John Haltiwanger, "Inventories and the
Propagation of Sectoral Shocks," American Economic Review, Vol. 8,
#1, p. 170-190, (March 1990).
Dickey, David A. and Wayne A. Fuller, "Distribution of the
Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series With a Unit Root,"
Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 74, #366, (June
1979).
Eicbenbaum, Martin and Kenneth J. Singleton, "Do Equilibrium
Business Cycle Theories Explain Postwar U.S. Business Cycles?,"
NBER Macroeconomics Annual, (1986).
Evans, George W., "Output and Unemployment Dynamics in the
United States: 1950-1985," Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 4,
p. 213-237, (1989).
Fuller, Wayne A., Introduction to Statistical Time Series, Wiley,
New York, 1976.
Lilien, David, "Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical
Unemployment," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90, #4, p.
777-793, (1982).
Long, John B. and Charles I. Plosser, "Real Business
Cycles," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91, #1, p. 39-69,
(1983).
-----, "Sectoral vs. Aggregate Shocks in the Business
Cycle," American Economic Review, Vol. 77, #2, p. 333-336, (May
1987).
Mankiw, N. Gregory, "Real Business Cycles: A New Keynesian
Perspective," The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 3, #3, p.
79-90, (Summer 1989).
Nickell, Stephen, "Unemployment: A Survey," The Economic
Journal, Vol. 100 #401, p. 440-463, (June 1990).
Plosser, Charles I., "Understanding Real Business
Cycles," The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 3 #3, p. 51-78,
(Summer 1989).
Prescott, Edward C., "Theory Ahead of Business Cycle
Measurement," Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, (Fall 1986).
Prescott, Edward C. "Response to a Skeptic," Quarterly
Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, (Fall 1986).
Rowthorn, R.E. and J.R. Wells, De-industrialization and Foreign
Trade, Cambridge University Press, (1987).
Shapiro, Matthew D. and Mark W. Watson, "Sources of Business
Cycle Fluctuations," NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1988.
Summers, Lawrence H., "Some Skeptical Observations on Real
Business Cycle Theory," Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, (Fall 1986).