Contractual governance in trucking: a comment.
Mixon, Franklin G., Jr. ; Upadhyaya, Kamal P.
In an innovative and cogent article, Smith (1993) analyzes the
structure of post-deregulation contracting in the trucking industry,
utilizing the transactions-cost framework developed by Williamson (1979)
and by Klein, Crawford, and Alchian (1978). In examining the
relationship between trucking firms and final product suppliers, Smith
employs Williamson's characterization of transactions based upon
the level of uncertainty, the frequency of recurrence, and the level of
specific investment associated with such transactions. Williamson's
arguments do add much to the theoretical developments of Coase (1937),
Alchian and Demsetz (1972), and Klein et al. (1978) by discussing the
market (uncertainty and ex-post small numbers) and human characteristics
(bounded rationality and opportunism) that affect many contractual
arrangements (both vertical and horizontal) within industries.
Smith makes several valid points in his analysis. First, the degree
of transaction-specific investment is a prime determinant of contractual
governance structures. However, physical capital is not
transaction-specific in the trucking industry (Smith, p. 58). The lack
of specific capital does not rule out the possibility of the presence of
specific investment, where Williamson emphasizes the importance of
specific investment in human capital. As a source of specific
investment, Smith points out that by allowing motor carriers to enter
into "reduced-rate" agreements with individual shippers, the
costs of negotiating the contracts is positive and creates an investment
in negotiations that is transaction-specific (Smith, p. 58).
Smith's second major point is that uncertainty will increase the
benefits of unified governance (vertical integration) or bilateral governance when some degree of specific investment is present (long-term
contracting). Without such specific investment, Williamson's
analysis points out that short-term contractual governance will be an
option under uncertainty. Two sources of uncertainty among shippers and
trucking firms is fuel prices and the possibility of bankruptcy of
carrier firms (Smith, p. 58).
Third, Smith correctly points out that ex-post small numbers may lead
to "opportunism" with contractual governance. Opportunism can
be expected to arise in situations where recurrent transactions and
mixed investment can create quasi-rents which facilitate the use of
long-term, relational contracting (Smith, p. 60). Smith's analysis
of the relationship between shippers and carriers lacks a cross-section
of data, and he supports his observations with illustrative examples of
these relationships.
The purpose of this comment is to provide support for Smith's
analysis from current research. Using the ideas of Williamson (1971 and
1979), modified by the additions of other researchers such as Ekelund
and Higgins (1982), our research suggests that vertical relationships
within the motor carrier industry since the Motor Carrier Act of 1980
exhibit the theoretical construct developed by Smith (see Upadhyaya and
Mixon, 1993; Mixon and Upadhyaya, 1993). Using a cross-section of
carrier companies collected from trucks which were inspected by the
Tennessee Public Service Commission, we are able to proxy many of the
ideas developed by Smith. The firms we examine are similar in that they
are all for-profit companies with I.C.C. authority to engage in
interstate transportation for non-exempt cargo between 1982-1986 (n =
60). Our research examines the relationship between trucking companies
and truck producing companies that lease and/or sell trucks and
equipment to motor carriers. The relationships developed by Williamson
and detailed by Smith are all valid. The decision to lease/contract or
purchase capital equipment by motor carriers is subject to the degree of
uncertainty of the demand for carriers' services, because it is
derived from the demand for final goods and services.
The dependent variable in our analysis is the percent of total annual
expenses in leasing transport equipment (versus ownership) in 1986, and
we use various techniques to control for the problem caused by firm size
in statistical analysis. Our measure of demand or market uncertainty is
the absolute value of earnings deviations for each company between 1982
and 1986 (at 1986 prices). Because the demand for carriers'
services is a function of the demand for final products, there is much
uncertainty in motor carrier markets and will be captured by large
variations in earnings over time. In all of our models, earnings
deviation is positive and significant at the 99 percent level of
confidence, which supports the ideas developed by Smith. Short-term
leasing, in the absence of ex-post small numbers, is beneficial in the
face of demand uncertainties. Our model did not consider the possibility
of carrier bankruptcy, which would also favor short-term contracting
over bilateral or unified governance in the leasing decision. Because
our analysis examines an alternate vertical structure, our theoretical
explanation of the role played by the possibility of firm bankruptcy
offers a different conclusion regarding contractual governance, although
the principles developed by Williamson and Smith are still adhered to.
Our results generally support the developments of Smith in his
earlier study. Other avenues developed in our analysis examine the role
of maintenance costs as specific human capital investment, which leads
to greater leasing expenditures in this vertical arrangement between
motor carriers and equipment suppliers. Here, trucking firms opt for
full service leases (either short-term or bilateral) over unified
governance. While we originally thought that our use of
Williamson's theoretical constructs to explain vertical
relationships in the motor carrier industry to be new and unique, our
results specifically support the work of Smith regarding contractual
governance in this industry. Hopefully, future researchers will
recognize the useful contributions made by Smith as a theoretical
background involving empirical analysis.
References
Alchian, A. and H. Demsetz. "Production, Information Costs, and
Economic Organization." Journal of Law and Economics, 62 (1972),
777-795.
Coase, R. H. "The Nature of the Firm." Economica, 4 (1937),
386-405.
Ekelund, R. B. and R. S. Higgins. "Capital Fixity, Innovations
and Long-Term Contracting: An Intertemporal Economic Theory of
Regulation." American Economic Review, 72 (1982), 32-46.
Klein, B., R. Crawford, and A. Alchian. "Vertical Integration,
Appropriate Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process."
Journal of Law and Economics, 21 (1978), 297-326.
Mixon, F. G., Jr. and K. P. Upadhyaya. "Economic Regulation,
Firm Size, and Vertical Integration in the Motor Carrier Industry."
Unpublished Manuscript, (1993).
Smith, B. R., II. "Contractual Governance in Trucking: Maislin
v. Primary Steel and the Undercharge Crisis." The American
Economist, 37 (1993), 56-63.
Upadhyaya, K. P. and F. G. Mixon, Jr. "The Transactions Cost
Theory of Vertical Integration: Leasing in the Motor Carrier
Industry." International Journal of Transport Economics, 20(1993),
295-304.
Williamson, O. E. "Transactions Cost Economics: the Governance
of Contractual Relations." Journal of Law and Economics, 22 (1979),
233-261.
Williamson, O. E. "The Vertical Integration of Production:
Market Failure Considerations." American Economic Review, 61
(1971), 112-123.