Economic education, experimental methods and the structure-conduct-performance paradigm.
Ray, Margaret A.
Introduction
The traditional view of student learning in the economic education
literature places the teacher and/or school in the role of producer
while students are seen as inputs to which value is added. Empirical
models of economic education often assume students are passive
receptors, with varying degrees of initial endowments, subject to the
teaching techniques and learning environment supplied by teachers and
schools. Within this framework, teaching effectiveness, and thus student
learning, can be changed by simply altering the teaching technology or
school environment. However, most educators would agree that in most
circumstances the ultimate control over teaching effectiveness lies with
the student, and not with the "teacher/school producer."
Consider an alternative economic model of education that views
students as the producers of learning. Imagine the classroom as a
market, a market in which students produce learning. In this market, the
output is monitored by test scores. The student "produces"
test scores by learning and trades the scores for grades. Instructors
strive to assure that grades are highly correlated with actual learning.
The economic goal of students is to maximize learning (as measured by
grades) subject to a time constraint (the student's available time
and the length of the course) or, alternatively, to minimize study time
subject to a given level of learning (grades).
This alternative view is consistent with research findings of
sociologists studying the motives and goals of college students.
Empirical research has established the "grade point average
perspective" as prevalent among college students:
The student's generalized goal enjoins him to be serious about
college: to recognize it as a serious place where important things
happen and to try to do well in all areas of college life as a sign of
achieved maturity. His perspective on academic work develops as he
interacts with other students in an environment in which, as we shall
see, grades are the chief form of institutionalized value and the
institutional basis of punishment and reward in academic pursuits
(Becker, Geer and Hughes, 1983).
Becker, Geer and Hughes further recognize the "analogy"
grade directed behavior and behavior within a money economy. Students
strive to make grades which are "good enough" to pass their
individual quality standards just as workers strive to earn income to
maintain a desired standard of living. (Obviously the desired standards
and the ability to achieve those standards vary across individuals in
both cases.) Faculty often disagree with the emphasis placed on scores,
grades, and grade point averages but the institutional structure of
universities has a deeply embedded "grade point perspective."
The instructor may be seen as serving three functions in the market.
First, the instructor "buys" learning with grades. (In most
circumstances the instructor is the sole buyer of test scores--a
monopsonist with a degree of control over the "price" of
grades). A second function of the instructor is as an input. Classroom
instruction is combined with readings, homework, study time, student
ability and other inputs to produce learning. A quality instructor
increases learning efficiency and thereby decreases the cost of student
learning, while a poor instructor increases the cost. The last, and
perhaps most important, function of the instructor is to determine the
operational structure of the course. The course structure creates the
market which correlates grades with learning.
This alternative perspective places students in the role of
producers. The student makes decisions that determine if and how much
learning will be produced. Within this framework, students, rather than
teachers, are endowed with the power and responsibility to produce
learning. Teachers have no direct control over student actions, they can
only attempt to induce learning by providing the optimal class structure
and teaching inputs. Adopting this classroom market perspective of the
education process has several benefits. One is the ability to borrow the
"structure-conduct-performance" paradigm from the field of
industrial organization.
In industrial organization, market structure represents the
firm's external environment. When the classroom is viewed as a
market, structure refers to the environment set up by the teacher. Each
student must operate within the confines of the class structure.
Firm behavior concerns the conduct of the firm within the market
structure. Student behavior refers to the choices made by students
within the class structure. The link between structure and performance
is often overlooked or ignored in the "teacher/school
producer" models of learning. Teachers have no direct control over
student behavior or performance. Performance can only be affected via
the teachers ability to influence student behavior using class
structure.
Finally, market performance is evaluated in terms of efficiency,
equity, and progress. In education, academic performance can be
evaluated using testing instruments. Grades, student evaluations, and
scores on standardized exams are all measures of academic performance.
How may the classroom market perspective be useful for research in
education? Importantly, it calls attention to alternative class
structures, student behavior and academic performance within the
structure-conduct-performance paradigm. This framework incorporates the
interrelationships between the class structure teachers create, the
students' behavior choice and academic performance.
An additional benefit of this alternative approach derives from the
ability to use experimental methods to study market organization. The
ability to create markets and study them using experiments gives
researchers an additional method of investigation (Taylor, 1988). Since
the classroom is viewed as a market, this approach suggests that
educational issues can be investigated using experimental methods
similar to those used in the field of industrial organization. For
example, it is possible to investigate how alternative class structures
affect student performance using this method. Questions of how many
tests should be given, should homework be assigned, do quizzes increase
learning and so forth can be addressed using experimental methods.
Experimental Methods in Education: An Example
Experimental methods are now used by economists in several fields.
Economic experiments often use university students as the economic
agents operating in a market designed by the experimenter. Analyzing
student behavior in these strategic situations gives insight into the
behavior of economic agents in the type of market under investigation.
At the same time, these experiments give insight into student behavior.
For experiments using students to shed light on firm behavior, it must
be assumed that students in the experiment behave as firms behave in a
market. But for experiments to shed light on student behavior, it must
only be assumed that students behave as students.
In the university classroom, students face interdependence. The
outcome of a student's decision often depends on other students.
For example, the pace of the class may be determined by the top
students, the slower students, or the median student; the grade scale
may be set based on the highest score or the mean score; and teacher
expectations, which determine the "terms of trade" between
scores and grades, may be affected by the abilities of class members as
a whole. Experimental methods have been used to study firm behavior in
interdependent markets. These same methods can be applied to study
student behavior in the classroom. Specifically, experiments can be
designed to determine what factors affect student conduct and
performance when they are placed in a "strategic" classroom
situation.
The market in which students operate in a classroom experiment is a
familiar market with which they have much experience. Below is one
example of how experimental methods similar to those used to investigate
questions in industrial organization can be applied to economic
education.
The Experiment
The experiment was conducted at Texas Christian University (TCU).
Participants were students enrolled in Macroeconomic Principles during
the Fall 1989 semester. In this experiment, students chose whether to
take an optional weekly quiz. If the choice were between taking a quiz
with some probability of earning bonus points at zero cost and not
taking a quiz to earn no bonus points there is no real economic choice.
Therefore, in this experiment, a student could earn bonus points either
by taking the quiz or by not taking the quiz. Students are placed in a
strategic situation where the return to their decision depends on the
decision of other students in the class. Student instructions and
payoffs are included as Appendix 1. If a student chose to take the quiz
she would receive either her score (if the class chose not to take the
quiz) or the class average (if the class chose to take the quiz). If she
chose not to take the quiz she would receive either a 0 (if the class
chose not to take the quiz) or 100% (if the class chose to take the
quiz). (As reported in the Appendix, the "class decision" to
take the quiz required an 80% participation rate.) The payoffs are
similar to the payoff in a "prisoner's dilemma" game for
those choosing not to take the quiz. Institutional constraints, however,
mandated that students receive some credit if they chose to take the
quiz.
Quizzes were administered during each Friday class over the course of
the 15 week semester. Students were first given a choice sheet to mark
their choice (to take the quiz or not to take the quiz). Their response
was concealed and collected. After collecting all responses, quizzes
were distributed.
Each Monday students were given the results of the Friday quiz. The
results included both the student's individual and class choices,
individual quiz score (when applicable), individual points earned for
the current round and total points earned. Also reported were the class
quiz average and the exact percent of the class that chose to take the
quiz. At the end of the semester, bonus quiz points were added to final
class grades at a rate of 15 points = 1%. That is, a student earning
perfect scores on quizzes (150 total points) would earn a 10% bonus.
The Model
This experiment may help instructors understand student behavior by
observing students in a situation similar to that faced by
interdependent firms in a collusive agreement. Students chose whether to
take the optional quiz. They could either study and earn points by
taking the optional quiz or they could try to earn points, with zero
study costs, by choosing not to take the quiz (thus
"free-ride" on the class decision). Note from the payoffs
outlined in Appendix 1 that the return to the student's individual
decision depends on the decision of the class as a whole. The adopted
80% decision rule for the class required approximately 40 students to
take the quiz (assuming perfect class attendance). Eighty percent was
chosen for the decision rule to create a reasonable probability that
students could indeed earn points by choosing not to take the quiz. The
choice was somewhat arbitrary, relying on the instructors ability to
approximate the students' perceptions of probabilities. Changing
this percentage would alter the student's perceived probabilities
and therefore would be expected to alter the results.
Compare the students situation to the situation of the firm. The firm
may avoid excessive competition and maximize joint profits by colluding.
The class may avoid competition and maximize joint bonus points by
taking the quiz. In effect, the class group may be viewed as entering a
collusive agreement in which each student studies and takes the quiz.
But in each case, the possibility of free-riding exists. A firm may
cheat on the agreement in hope of earning high profits. A student can
violate the implied agreement by choosing not to take the quiz, in hope
of earning a score of 100%. In either case, the action would be
successful only if other firms/students do not also decide to free-ride.
Putting students in this strategic situation, makes it is possible to
observe behavior when choices are interdependent, and to determine what
variables influence a students decision to study.
The Results
The percent of the class which chose to take the optional quiz during
each time period varied. In only four of fourteen periods (weeks) did
80% or more students choose to take the quiz. The highest percent
choosing to take the quiz during the semester was 83%. It is also
interesting to note that each student attempted, at least once, to earn
the full 10 points by not taking the quiz. This indicates that the
variation in the percentage of the class taking the quiz represents
decisions by all students, not just a small segment of the class. The
average quiz score ranged from 3 to 7 points, perhaps indicating the
"bonus" nature of the quizzes.(1)
In making the decision each week, students can consider information
gained from the results of all previous periods. In addition, students
know their own grades (including midterm exams, homework), how much they
have studied, and how well they understand the material. Using this
information, students can decide which choice yields the highest
expected return. The expected return derives from the student's
perception of the probabilities of the outcomes and the perceived return
from each outcome
The factors affecting the decision of the class to study for the quiz
give insight into student conduct. To investigate which information
significantly affected student decisions, the following relationship was
tested using a simple regression framework:
Percent = A0 + B1 Average + B2 Score + B3 Midterm + B4 Attendance + e
Where;
Percent = % of class in attendance choosing to take weekly quiz
A0 = OLS regression constant
Average = Cumulative class average the day of each quiz
Score = Class average on previous week's quiz
Midterm = 0 before midterm exam; = 1 after midterm exam
Attendance = Class attendance on day of weekly quiz
e = Random error term
The cumulative class Average represents the average student grade at
the time of the quiz (including homework and midterm grades). A low
class average may encourage students to take the quiz in order to earn
much needed points or may cause students to choose not to take the quiz
if they feel "free-riding" behavior is their only hope.
The Score variable measures the class average on the previous quiz.
Class success in taking the last quiz may influence student decisions if
it changes student expectations for success on the current quiz. Success
on the last quiz will lead to more students taking the current quiz if
the expected return to taking the current quiz increases.
The midterm grade is included to measure changes in student behavior
that occur after the midterm exam. The class average for the midterm
exam was 76%. High midterm exam grades will affect student decisions if
expected returns are changed. For example, sufficiently high midterm
grades may cause students to become satisfied with current grades so
that additional studying is not deemed necessary.
The percent attending class determines the number of students that
may earn points by not taking the quiz. The Attendance variable may
affect student perceptions of the probability of receiving points by not
taking the quiz.
Not included in this equation are factors that are outside of the
instructor's control and are not easily measured. For example, a
party the night before the quiz or an exam given in another class can
also be expected to enter into a student's decision.
The results of the estimation are included in Table 1. These results
indicate short run success (represented by the Score coefficient)
significantly increased the percent of the class which takes the quiz.
However, in the long run student success (as measured by the Average
coefficient) significantly decreased the percent of students taking the
quiz. This result implies that students may increase or decrease
studying as a result of success on recent assignments. However, reaching
a high or low cumulative class average will discourage or encourage
studying respectively. It appears that students will work to obtain the
desired final grade, but short-run decisions are affected by recent
success on assignments and exams.
The Midterm coefficient is statistically significant and conforms
with the hypothesis that student success in the long-run (i.e.,
achieving the desired grade) may decrease the percentage of students
choosing to take quizzes.
These results are consistent with the findings of Becker, Geer and
Hughes.
TABLE 1
REGRESSION RESULTS
(Dependent Variable = Percent)
Variable Coefficient t-Ratio
Constant 357.32 3.30(***)
Average -5.37 2.89(**)
Score 0.20 1.92(*)
Midterm -21.47 1.96(*)
Attendance -0.02 0.06
F = 8.45 |R.sup.2~ = 0.57 |R.sup.2~ = 0.56 N = 15
*** Significant at the .01 level, two tailed test
** Significant at the .05 level, two-tailed test
* Significant at the .10 level, two-tailed test
A certain minimum is essential because of the way the valuable
|grade~ is institutionalized. But beyond the minimum, which represents
the level necessary in order to have the privilege of choosing where to
put one's remaining time and effort, choice becomes possible and
the person finds that he must balance the various rewards available
against one another in making that choice. (Becker, Geer and Everett,
1983).
The idea, of course, is that as students reach the minimum desired
grade, the opportunity cost of studying becomes very high.
Conclusions
Educators are aware of the futility of trying to teach students who
are not interested in learning. Regardless of the amount of time, talent
and energy an instructor expends, the student has ultimate control over
success in the classroom. Viewing the classroom as a market, where
students combine educational inputs to produce grades allows us to study
the education process using the structure-conduct-performance paradigm.
This paradigm is useful for educators and researchers interested in
determining appropriate class structures, establishing particular
student conduct, or improving academic performance.
Experimental methods have been applied to areas throughout the
economics discipline. They have been especially useful for studying
topics in industrial organization. In addition to providing a framework
for investigating the production of learning, use of the
Structure-conduct-performance paradigm invites the use of experimental
methods for the study of education. The experiment detailed here is
merely an example of the type of research that can be undertaken if
classroom behavior is treated as a market. The importance of this paper
lies in the ideas and research that may result from the adoption of this
alternative perspective and experimental methodology to analyze student
learning.
References
Becker, Howard, Blanche Geer and Everett Hughes, "Making the
Grade" in Howard Robby and Candace Clark, eds. Social Interaction.
New York: St. Martins Press, 1983.
Taylor, Herb, "Experimental Economics: Putting Markets under the
Microscope." Philadelphia Federal Reserve Business revue,
March/April, 1988.
Notes
1. The percentage of the class that choose to take the quiz and the
mean quiz score for each week were as follows:
Week 1 (41%, 3), Week 2 (82%, 7), Week 3 (41%, 5), Week 4 (62%, 5),
Week 6 (83%, 3), Week 7 (70%, 4), Week 8 (62%, 5), Week 9 (66%, 6), Week
10 (64%, 3), Week 11 (80%, 4), Week 12 (80%, 4), Week 13 (76%, 6), Week
14 (72%, 5)
Appendix 1
Economics 2103 10:00 MWF
Bonus Quiz--Instructions
You have the opportunity to participate in an experiment involving
the allocation of your scarce economic resources. You may choose not to
participate if you wish, however the results can not adversely affect
your grade while they may increase it. To participate you will need to
purchase scantron answer forms from the bookstore.
The Experiment
You will have the chance to practice with two quizzes prior to
beginning the experiment. There will be 15 rounds (quizzes) during the
semester. To participate, you must choose whether or not to take the
quiz being given. You may earn quiz points either by choosing to take
the quiz or by choosing not to take the quiz. If you choose not to
participate or are not in class when the quiz is given, you will not
earn quiz points.
The Payoff
The figure below shows the quiz points earned in each possible
situation, given your choice. Your return depends on whether or not
"the class" has chosen to take the quiz. "The class"
is considered as having taken the quiz if 80% or more of those present
choose to take the quiz. Each quiz is worth 10 points.
The results (your score, your quiz points, the % taking the quiz, the
class average) will be reported for each quiz prior to the next round.
Margaret A. Ray is an Assistant Professor of Economics, Texas
Christian University, Fort Worth. The author wishes to thank Paul W.
Grimes, Joe K. Law and Paul S. Nelson for their comments and
suggestions. Any remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the
author.