首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月28日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:How event significance, team quality, and school proximity affect secondary market behavior at March Madness.
  • 作者:Rishe, Patrick J. ; Mondello, Michael ; Boyle, Brett
  • 期刊名称:Sport Marketing Quarterly
  • 印刷版ISSN:1061-6934
  • 出版年度:2014
  • 期号:December
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Fitness Information Technology Inc.
  • 摘要:There is considerable research which discuss how sport ticketing professionals engage in inelastic ticket pricing (Fort, 2004; Krueger, 2001), and that such behavior is not in contrast with profit-maximization because it enables organizations to bolster other non-ticket sources of revenue (Coates & Humphreys, 2007; Krautmann & Berri, 2007). Separately, there is long-standing evidence from the marketing literature of a strong correlation between the price of a product and perceptions of product quality (Monroe & Krishnan, 1985; Scitovsky, 1945; Tsao, Pitt & Caruana, 2005).
  • 关键词:Basketball teams;College sports;Pricing;Secondary market;Sports associations;Ticket sales

How event significance, team quality, and school proximity affect secondary market behavior at March Madness.


Rishe, Patrick J. ; Mondello, Michael ; Boyle, Brett 等


Introduction

There is considerable research which discuss how sport ticketing professionals engage in inelastic ticket pricing (Fort, 2004; Krueger, 2001), and that such behavior is not in contrast with profit-maximization because it enables organizations to bolster other non-ticket sources of revenue (Coates & Humphreys, 2007; Krautmann & Berri, 2007). Separately, there is long-standing evidence from the marketing literature of a strong correlation between the price of a product and perceptions of product quality (Monroe & Krishnan, 1985; Scitovsky, 1945; Tsao, Pitt & Caruana, 2005).

The secondary market for sports tickets affords an opportunity to (1) confirm whether organizations systematically engage in inelastic ticket pricing, and (2) explore the relationship between perceptions of quality and secondary price markups over face values. Academic research regarding the secondary ticket market has become more voluminous in recent years but is still relatively underdeveloped. This is particularly the case as it pertains to collegiate sporting events and specifically college basketball, where there has been tremendous growth in secondary market revenues. For example, the estimated dollar volume of total secondary market sales increased from $2.6 billion in 2011 to $4.0 billion in 2013, with increases from $420 million to $676 million over the same span for college sports alone, and increases from $100 million to $160 million for March Madness alone. (1)

Studying secondary market behavioral trends at March Madness (i.e., the Division I Men's College Basketball tournament) presents a unique opportunity to examine whether an organization (in this case, the National Collegiate Athletic Association) is able to price tickets in the inelastic range of consumer demand when dealing with two unique anomalies not typically confronted by sports organizations. First, there are several micro-events (e.g., four Regional Finals and the Final Four) contained within the overall tournament, none of which are held annually in the same city. Second, there is greater consumer uncertainty regarding perceptions of event quality for these micro-events because the event participants (i.e., the qualifying teams) are not known until 5-6 days before the event occurs. Due to the added travel and logistical costs for non-local fans associated with last-minute travel (e.g., airfares), greater event uncertainty could impact event demand, and subsequently, secondary markups associated with tickets for the event.

Therefore, the primary goals of this paper are: 1) examine the secondary price behavior associated with March Madness to determine whether the afore-mentioned anomalies impact the NCAA's ability to set their face prices where demand is inelastic; and 2) determine which factors are the most influential in determining the magnitude of secondary markups. In terms of theoretical contributions, we extend the pricing literature by examining pricing behavior within the unique consumer product class of sports entertainment, focusing on secondary ticket pricing where the "product" being priced (i.e., the ticket) is not the primary revenue driver. Another key contribution is the revelation that the sports organization may not always be able to price tickets in the inelastic range of demand when there is considerable a priori uncertainty and lack of control regarding an event's quality. Lastly, the evidence supports the notion that consumers' perceptions of event significance and team quality, as well as logistical travel considerations which impact fans' total cost of attending an event, directly impacting the magnitude of secondary markups.

Tournament and Ticketing Logistics of March Madness

March Madness admits 68 teams in a single-elimination tournament taking place over three weeks from mid-March through early April. Thirty-two of the 68 teams automatically qualify by winning their end-of-season conference tournament, while the other 36 teams are at-large selections chosen by a Selection Committee mostly comprised of senior-level Division I athletic administrators (e.g., athletic directors, conference executives). Apart from selecting the at-large teams, the Selection Committee is charged with the arduous tasks of (1) dividing the teams into four similarly competitive Regionals, (2) seeding the teams within each Regional, and (3) determining which teams should play where during the first weekend of the tournament. (2)

Achieving these "selection goals" simultaneously in a way that promotes both ticket sales and competitive balance is a challenging endeavor. Consider that The Ohio State University (located in Columbus, OH) was selected as the #2 seed in the West Region for the 2013 tournament. The reason the Buckeyes were placed in the West Region was to add more competitive depth to that region, though doing so made it less likely for Buckeye fans to make a last-minute cross-country trip to Los Angeles for the Regional. However, the Selection Committee placed Ohio State in nearby Dayton, OH for their first two tournament games for the likely reason of boosting ticket sales for early-round games (given the close proximity of Dayton to Columbus). In short, it would appear that the NCAA Selection Committee's primary scheduling goal in the early rounds of the tournament is to maximize ticket sales by ensuring that the better teams within a particular pod are reasonably close to their home city, while the primary goal of the Regional allocation of teams is to minimize the disparity in competitive balance across the Regionals (with proximity being an added bonus if it comes to fruition as was the case with Louisville playing the 2013 Midwest Regional in nearby Indianapolis).

Regarding ticket allocation for both the Regionals and Final Four, the NCAA allocates tickets to a variety of groups including the Local Organizing Committee, the general public, the participating schools, the National Association of Basketball Coaches (NABC), the NCAA's corporate partners, and a general allocation to member NCAA schools. One key distinction is that the NCAA only sells "All-Session" ticket packages to the Final Four (i.e., a three-game package including both semifinals and the finals). Conversely for the Regionals, the NCAA sells All-Session packages as well as separate tickets for just Session 1 (the Regional semifinals) and Session 2 (the Regional Finals). Regarding face value ticket pricing, the NCAA sets the face value for all March Madness tickets well before the tournament field is set. The only factor known with certainty prior to their price setting is the facility capacity for each venue. For the 2013 Final Four, there were seven separate 'price points' assigned for the "All Session" ticket packages ($5000, $420, $280, $250, $230, $190, $175). For the Regionals, Table 1 below details the various face value prices associated with each ticket type sold at each host venue. (3)

Given that each micro-event within the tournament takes place in different cities and involves different groupings of teams, this conveniently lends itself to an examination of how different "event draws" appeal to consumers, and thus, produce differing secondary market behavior. Based on prior conversations with NCAA representatives, local event organizers and local tourism officials, a "quality draw" of teams is desirable for boosting both ticket sales and general tourism activity. (4) Furthermore, these sources note that a "quality draw" of teams reflects some combination of (1) highly ranked teams from that year's national polls, (2) teams with fan bases who historically travel well, and/or (3) teams that are located within a reasonable driving proximity to the event. (5)

Literature Review

Inelastic Sports Pricing

Though the concept of inelastic sports pricing has garnered considerable attention for decades because of its potential implications regarding whether sports organizations are exhibiting profit-maximizing behavior, several papers noted that complementary revenues stemming from products tied to the sporting event may make up for the lost gate revenues resulting from inelastic pricing. Krueger (2001) observed that face value prices for the 2001 Super Bowl were priced below what consumers were willing to pay on the secondary market, likely because the NFL earned sufficiently high revenues from media revenues. Fort (2004) used gate and media revenue data from Major League Baseball to show that inelastic pricing was consistent with profit maximization if local television revenues compared favorably to the average marginal television revenue across the rest of the league. Extending the scope of research to include both professional baseball and basketball, Coates and Humphreys (2007) argued that inelastic ticket pricing is consistent with profit maximizing behavior due to the inter-related pricing decisions on tickets, concessions, and other related goods sold at these sporting contests. Examining the four major team sports leagues in North America, Krautmann and Berri (2007) argued that concession revenues allow professional sport teams to discount their ticket prices significantly.

Correlation Between Perceptions of Product Quality and Willingness to Pay

Scitovsky (1945) first suggested price serves as a cue for product quality. Consumers were particularly dependent on this cue when other more salient attributes of the product are absent (Tsao, et al. 2005). Much of the conceptual foundation of the current study draws from Monroe and Krishnan's (1985) price-perceived quality model, which defines price as having an influence on both perceived quality as well as perceived sacrifice. In turn, perceived value is the net of these two factors, the former having a positive effect on perceived value, the latter a negative effect. Subsequently, one's willingness to buy is seen as directly affected by perceived value. (6) Their work is particularly germane to the present study. Tournament seeding serves as an initial proxy of product (team) quality while allowing the most talented teams the best chance to advance to later rounds by pairing them with easier early-round opponents. This creates the potential for maximizing the perceived overall quality of later-round tournament games, given the advancing of top teams.

However, history has shown that tournament game results rarely--if ever--follow true-to-form with regard to seeding. Consider the 2014 tournament, where the #3 seed in the Midwest (Duke) lost in the first round to #14 seed Mercer. Hence, the perceived value of the 2014 Midwest Regional--which initially was high because of the potential matchups involving a blueblood Duke program as well as 2013's national runner-up Michigan--diminished rapidly when the better teams failed to advance through the tournament. In short, perceived value (via perceived quality) is highly dynamic within the context of the March Madness Tournament. Though we do not directly introduce game results into our analysis, nevertheless the intrigue of March Madness as a sporting event rests heavily on the unpredictability of the Tournament, thus providing a rich environment to study secondary price elasticities.

Intuitively, the quality of the March Madness product would also include the location of the seats purchased in the game venue. A study by Leslie and Sorensen (2014) using secondary ticket sales data to 56 major rock concerts found the best seats were approximately four times more likely to be resold than low-to-mid quality tickets. Similarly, Salaga and Winfree (2013) examined the secondary ticket market for the NFL and specifically for personal seat licenses (PSL) and season ticket rights (STR). High-quality seating locations were a strong predictor of price, and higher face value ticket prices were also associated with lower secondary market PSL and STR transaction prices.

Perceived sacrifice is also a unique aspect of consumption of the March Madness product. Unlike single-site sporting events such as the Super Bowl, fans of different Tournament teams are required to travel different distances, paying correspondingly varied prices to reach their team's game. Such travel costs no doubt play a role in a fan's calculus of the value of a secondary market ticket. We therefore additionally incorporate travel distance (along with proxies for perceived quality) in assessing consumers' willingness to pay above face value on the secondary market.

Secondary Pricing Behavior, Dynamic Pricing, and Revenue Management

Because inelastic ticket pricing in the primary market drives secondary market pricing decisions, a review of the secondary price literature is warranted. Using data from online bidding transactions from the secondary ticket market for NFL playoff games, Drayer and Shapiro (2009) found that secondary prices were significantly related to the total number of online ticket transactions per game, the home team's city per capita income, and the home team's city population. In a separate study for NFL regular season games, Drayer, Rascher, and McEvoy (2012) found the point spread, percent of capacity sold, the presence of a new stadium, a team's comparative quality, the face value of tickets, and current and lagged win percentages each had a statistically significant impact on the value of secondary ticket prices.

Additionally, several studies have addressed why dynamic pricing is critically important for revenue maximization in today's sports environment. Drayer, Shapiro, & Lee (2012) noted sport organizations needed to evolve and develop ticketing strategies capitalizing on the secondary market since other revenue sources like stadium naming rights and sponsorship inventories are limited. Rascher et al. (2007) concluded a general variable ticket pricing policy for the San Francisco Giants could have increased the team's revenue by roughly 7%. Separately, using data from the San Francisco Giants in comparing the team's dynamic pricing policy to prices arising on the secondary market, Shapiro and Drayer (2012) found prices from the previous year, the current year's season ticket prices, the Giants winning percentage as well as that of opposing teams, and how far back the Giants were from first place all impacted the optimal dynamic price for a given game. Zhu (2014) tested MLB primary and secondary ticket data for one franchise to gauge how the team could increase revenue with dynamic ticketing, and found that the franchise could increase revenue by 6.93% when dealing with uninformed consumers but only by 3.67% when dealing with customers more savvy with the intricacies of the secondary market.

Secondary Market Behavior in Collegiate Sports and March Madness

Though there has been little research regarding the dynamics of the secondary market for collegiate sporting events, Rishe (2014a) analyzed a sample of 285 online transactions involving 750 tickets sold to the 2013 Final Four. He found that (1) the NCAA under-prices tickets to the Final Four, (2) the magnitude of the secondary price markups differed across 'Session Type' (e.g., Session 1 tickets had significantly higher markups than All Session packages or Session 2 tickets), (3) markups per ticket decreased as consumers bought more tickets within a single transaction, (4) tickets in the upper-bowl experienced lower markups than all other tickets, and (5) centrally-located tickets experienced greater markups than all other tickets. However, by only analyzing secondary price trends at the Final Four, this analysis failed to consider how secondary market behavior might differ across micro-events (Regional Finals, Final Four) that differ in terms of team-specific factors (e.g., quality, proximity) and local factors (incidence of locals buying tickets, facility capacity).

Theoretical Model and Data

The primary investigative task is to examine whether secondary market behavior significantly differs across the micro-events of March Madness which differ in terms of both event significance and the attractiveness of an event's draw. The model specifications to follow are founded on the following hypotheses. First, there is a direct correlation between perceived product quality and willingness to pay. Second, there is an inverse correlation between the ancillary costs of attending a sporting event (such as distance to travel) and willingness to pay. Third, there is a direct correlation between seat quality and willingness to pay. Fourth, secondary markups will differ across "session type" and the volume of tickets purchased within a transaction as found in Rishe (2014a).

Hence, the initial model specification employed to examine March Madness secondary market behavior is: MU = a + b(ALL) + c(CHAMP) + d(LOW) + e(HIGH) + f(CENT) + g(QTY) + h(QTY2) + i(STATE) + j(TIME) + k(LOCAL) + l(EAST) + m(MIDWEST) + n(SOUTH) + o(wEST),

(Model 1)

where

* MU = the size of the markup (i.e., difference between secondary and face value price) as a percentage of the face value price. (7)

* ALL = 1 if an All Session ticket, 0 if a Session 1 (i.e., Semifinals) ticket.

* CHAMP = 1 if a Session 2 (i.e., Finals) ticket, 0 if a Session 1 ticket.

* LOW = 1 for tickets in the lower bowl (100 level sections) of a facility, 0 for tickets in the middle bowl (200-level sections).

* HIGH = 1 for tickets in the upper bowl (300 level sections), 0 for tickets in the middle bowl (200-level sections).

* CENT = 1 for centrally located seats located in sections between either baseline, 0 otherwise.

* QTY = the number of tickets in a given online transaction.

* QTY2 = QTY squared.

* STATE = 1 if the zip code associated with the online buyer was from one of the four states represented in a particular regional or Final Four, and 0 otherwise. (8)

* TIME = the difference (in days) between when the online purchase was made and the tip-off of the event.

* EAST, MIDWEST, SOUTH, and WEST are dummy variables representing each Regional, and have a value of one for tickets to that Regional, and zero otherwise. Hence, tickets purchased for the Final Four is the control group.

* LOCAL = 1 if the consumer has a zip code which is local to the host city of the event in question, and zero otherwise.

Given that the micro-events analyzed herein differ in terms of event significance (the Final Four is the crescendo of the overall tournament), the aggregate quality of participating teams, the collective proximity of participating schools from each event's host city, and event attendance as a percentage of capacity, an alternative model which potentially offers greater specificity regarding the source of fluctuations in secondary markup differentials is:

MU = a + b(ALL) + c(CHAMP) + d(LOW) + e(HIGH) + f(CENT) + g(QTY) + h(QTY2) + i(STATE) + j(TIME) + k(LOCAL) + l(RPI) + m(PROX) + n(ATTCAP) + o(FF).

(Model 2)

In Model 2, the Regional dummy variables are replaced by RPI, PROX, ATTCAP, and FF. RPI stands for Ratings Percentage Index, and is measured as the median RPI of the four participating schools at a particular micro-event. The expected sign is negative because larger RPIs imply a less attractive draw of teams which should lower markups. (9) PROX is the median distance in miles between the participating schools and the host city of the micro-event in question. The expected sign is negative based on the hypothesis that teams playing further away from home will be less likely to boost event demand as their fans will be less likely to make the trip due to the added costs associated with farther distances to travel. ATTCAP is attendance as a percentage of capacity, and the expected sign on this coefficient is positive based on the hypothesis that greater attendance as a percentage of capacity implies greater scarcity of tickets, which should increase secondary prices and corresponding markups. Lastly, FF is a dummy variable with a value of one for tickets to the Final Four and zero for tickets to any of the Regionals. The expected sign on this coefficient is positive given that the Final Four represents the crescendo of the tournament.

Regarding the data employed, TicketCity.com (TC) provided data for 831 secondary market transactions which resulted in 2,160 tickets sold during the 2013 tournament. (10) Of the 831 total secondary market transactions, 117 transactions were for the East Regionals, 102 were for the Midwest Regionals, 231 were for the South Regionals, 96 were for the West Regionals, and 285 were for the Final Four. Table 2 below breaks down the number of consumer transactions for each micro-event by session.

Results

Descriptive Summary Statistics

Table 3 below summarizes the teams that competed in each Regional as well as the Final Four. Focusing on comparisons of the median RPI ranking of the teams in each Regional and the median distance teams traveled to reach the host city where their Regional was held, the evidence suggests Indianapolis had the most attractive draw (e.g., the lowest median RPI and lowest median distance to travel), Los Angeles had the least attractive draw (e.g., the highest median RPI and highest median distance to travel), and the East Regional had a better quality draw than the South Regional. Not surprisingly (as shown in Table 4 below), the Regionals with the better draws (East, Midwest) had higher attendances as a percentage of capacity than the Regionals with less attractive draws (South, West).

Table 5 presents descriptive statistics for mean and median secondary prices, face value prices, and markups (both in dollars and percentage terms) for each Regional and the Final Four, broken down by Session Type. Consistent with Rishe (2014a), it would appear that markup percentages are consistently higher for Session 1 compared to All-Session or Session 2. However, in a significant contrast to the Final Four findings, average and median markups are negative for each Regional irrespective of Session Type (i.e., the central trend in secondary prices is below the face value at the Regionals). Furthermore, the degree to which secondary prices fell below face value prices was less severe for the East and Midwest Regionals compared to the South and West Regionals. Additionally, Table 6 shows that secondary markups were far more common for Final Four purchases than Regional purchases, and that the incidence of Regional markups was more common for the East and Midwest Regionals.

In short, the descriptive statistics suggest that (1) consumers place a significant value premium on the Final Four compared to the Regionals, and (2) Regional markups significantly differ from each other. The next step is to use regression analysis to further examine the root

of these Regional markup discrepancies. (11)

Regression Results

Table 7 below present regression results for Model 1 using ordinary least squares (OLS) estimation corrected for heteroskedasticity (H/S) using White's heteroskedastic-consistent standard errors (HCSE). (12,13) The overall adjusted R-squared is 0.467, suggesting that 46.7% of the variation in secondary markups can be explained by the joint variation of the variables in Model 1. Focusing on the Regional coefficients, ceteris paribus, the Final Four secondary markup percentages were approximately 54 percentage points higher than for the East Regional, 60 percentage points higher than the Midwest Regional, 104 percentage points higher than the South Regional, and 92 percentage points higher than the West Regional. (14)

Furthermore, all the coefficients had their expected signs while only two variables (TIME, STATE) were statistically insignificant. Ceteris paribus, secondary markups were: (1) 11.9 percentage points lower for local consumers compared to non-locals, (2) 12.8 percentage points higher for lower-tier seats and 34.8 percentage points lower for upper-bowl seats compared to middle-tier seats, (3) 39.4 percentage points higher for centrally-located seats, and (4) 20.0 percentage points lower for All Session tickets and 42.0 percentage points lower for Session 2 tickets compared to Session 1 tickets. Lastly, the signs on QTY and QTY-squared suggest there is a non-linear inverse relationship between the number of tickets purchased and the size of the secondary markup per ticket.

For greater specificity regarding what may be driving differences in secondary markups across micro-events, Table 8 below presents regression results for Model 2 (also estimated using OLS with White's HCSE). The overall adjusted R-squared for Model 2 (0.475) is significantly greater than for Model 1. Furthermore, each of the newly introduced event-specific variables has their expected sign and is statistically significant. The coefficient on RPI suggests secondary markups increased by 1.1 percentage points as the median RPI of the teams within a pod fell (i.e., as the median quality of the teams improved) by one ranking point. The coefficient on PROX suggests secondary markup percentages increased by 1.01 percentage points for each 100 miles closer the median proximity of the schools competing in a pod were to the event's host city. A one percentage point increase in ATTCAP increased secondary markups by 4.7 percentage points. Lastly, secondary markups for the Final Four were 77.3 percentage points higher than for the Regionals collectively. All other model coefficients had their expected signs, while only two variables (TIME, STATE) were statistically insignificant.

Separately, the data was partitioned and a Chow test was conducted to determine if the regression coefficients are statistically different when comparing secondary market behavior between the Final Four and the Regionals. These results are presented in Table 9 below. Note that some variables had to be dropped from the earlier specifications to ensure the model is of full rank. The null hypothesis of the Chow test is that the regression coefficients obtained from running separate regressions are identical, implying that the Final Four and Regionals data can be pooled. However, the F-statistic associated with the Chow falls well into the rejection region, suggesting the underlying secondary markup behavior is structurally different when comparing the Final Four to the Regionals. Though not presented for space reasons, similar conclusions (i.e., the appropriateness of disaggregating the data) are drawn when running separate regressions for each Regional. Collectively, these results imply the secondary market behavior of each micro-event within March Madness has its own unique dynamic which is partially driven by differences in event significance and the quality of each event's draw.

Other variables were considered but ultimately excluded for a variety of reasons. For example, population and income--two variables commonly included to proxy local demand factors--were excluded because their inclusion introduced a significant degree of multicollinearity which impacted the statistical significance of RPI and PROX, and neither variable was statistically significant on its own. Practically speaking, the size and affluence of the city hosting these micro-events may be less impactful upon secondary prices if an overwhelming majority of event attendees are not from the host city's MSA. (15)

Separately, alternate proxies for team quality--such as national rankings and tournament seeding--were considered. However, national rankings are an inferior proxy of quality compared to RPI because such rankings are determined subjectively through human voting by media members and coaches (depending on the poll used), whereas RPI is formulaic based on the win percentages of the team in question, its opponents, and its opponents' opponents. Also, national polls only rank the Top 25 teams, whereas every team in Division I college basketball has an RPI rank. Regarding a team's tournament seed, this too is subjectively determined by the Selection Committee, and the values of the variable itself are more constrained (1 through 16) than is true for RPI. (16)

Another factor considered when assessing the appeal of a particular draw was the brand appeal of the participating schools at an event. This is subtly different from current team quality because brand appeal is largely built upon past success. Schools with greater brand appeal should attract greater interest, and thereby, drive up secondary prices and markups. One objective proxy for brand appeal is the revenue a school's college basketball program generates, since present levels of ticket sales and alumni donations are positively correlated with past on-court success. (17) However, when "brand appeal" was incorporated into Model 2 (either in place of or with RPI), it was not statistically significantly nor did the adjusted R-square improve.

Discussion

This paper marks the first time that real-time secondary price data is employed to examine secondary market behavior across multiple stages of the largest collegiate sporting event (March Madness). The empirical results reveal distinctively higher secondary markups for Final Four tickets relative to tickets for any of the Regionals. Additionally, secondary market behavior across the Regionals is sensitive to the perceived quality of an event's draw, which itself is impacted in part by the quality of the teams at the event and the proximity of those schools to the event's host site. In short, the results suggest an organization's ability to engage in inelastic ticket pricing may be compromised when setting prices for several micro-events whose drawing power is not known with certainty until just days before the event.

It is not altogether surprising that "locals" pay lower markups than "non-local" secondary ticket consumers for two reasons. First, local consumers have the luxury of making last-minute decisions to attend an event, and thus, can exhibit greater patience (i.e., price sensitivity) to see if secondary prices eventually fall to their reservation price. Second, local fans may not exhibit particularly strong allegiances to watch any of the participating schools since it is uncommon that a Regional or Final Four participant is playing in its home city. Hence, this too would make local fans more price-sensitive compared to non-local fans that are traveling to the host site with a strong rooting interest for one of the participating teams.

In terms of application, these results have the potential to provide strategic justification for the NCAA to employ a dynamic pricing model for future March Madness tournaments. Though evidence of sizable secondary markups over face values at the Final Four suggests the NCAA prices those tickets in the inelastic region of the demand curve, contrasting evidence of mostly secondary price "markdowns" at the Regionals suggests the NCAA may be systematically overpricing the face values for the Regionals. Given that the attractiveness of a particular Regional's draw is partially dependent upon the collective quality of the teams at the Regional as well as their proximity to the host site, any future algorithm used to dynamically price such tickets would be warranted to account for these factors. Ultimately, however, the NCAA's motivation to more dynamically price tickets for the purpose of boosting ticket revenue might be relatively weak given the massive media and advertising revenues generated from March Madness. (18)

Similar to Rishe (2014a), one limitation of this analysis is the lack of supply-side data regarding the number of tickets available on the secondary market for each of these micro-events. TicketCity was not able to provide information about the number of tickets available for resale at the time of each consumer's online transaction. Though capacity of facilities (imbedded in the ATTCAP variable) partially captures the supply side of the primary pricing market, the number of tickets available for resale on the secondary market would add further illumination to supply-side considerations. Future research should strive to obtain more supply-side ticket data in order to better account for potential simultaneity issues.

Another issue to examine in future research is whether conclusions regarding secondary market behavior for a particular event are consistent across different ticket resellers. Though the present research is based strictly on secondary sales data from TicketCity due to data availability, one of the authors is currently engaged in a secondary price analysis of the 2014 Rose Bowl and the 2014 BCS National Championship Game (also contested at the Rose Bowl) using data from two ticket resellers (TicketCity and SeatGeek). The preliminary results suggest that secondary price markups are not significantly different across these resellers. Though not always possible to obtain proprietary secondary sales data from ticket resellers, future studies should strive to obtain data from at least two different ticket resellers to enhance the robustness of conclusions drawn.

One part of the tournament not examined herein was secondary market behavior at the early rounds of the tournament. Given that the Selection Committee tries to boost early round ticket sales by placing the top Regional seeds at sites which minimize the distance traveled by fans, this could yield higher secondary demand for these games compared to the Regionals. Daily hotel metrics provided by Smith Travel Research show that Orlando and St Louis--which both hosted early-round tournament games in March 2014--experienced a net MSA hotel occupancy rate increase of approximately 14% relatively to historical norms. (19) Conversely, a recent study of twenty-four separate Regional Finals between 2008 and 2013 found that the median net increase in occupancy rates was less than 2% higher than historical norms (Rishe, 2014c). Thus, it would be illuminating to see if the secondary market behavior mirrors the differences in net occupancy spikes observed when comparing early-round pods to Regional Finals.

References

Chapman, J. (1987). The impact of discounts on subjective product evaluations. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Marketing Department, Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, Blacksburg, VA.

Chapman, J., & Wahlers, R. (1999). A revision and empirical test of the extended price-perceived quality model. Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice, 7(3), 53-64.

Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. (2007). Ticket prices, concessions, and attendance at professional sporting events. International Journal of Sport Finance, 2, 161-170.

Crupi, A. (2013, March 6). Show me the moneyball: March Madness generates $1 billion in ad sales. Ad Week. Retrieved from http://www.adweek.com/news/television/show-me-moneyball-marchmadness-generates-1-billion-ad-sales-147732

Dodd, W., & Monroe, K. (1985). The effect of brand and price information on subjective product information. In E. Hirschman & M. Holbrook (Eds.), Advances in consumer research (Vol. 12, pp. 85-90). Provo UT: Association of Consumer Research.

Drayer, J., Rascher, D., & McEvoy, C. (2012). An examination of underlying consumer demand and sport pricing using secondary market data. Sport Management Review, 15, 448-460.

Drayer, J., & Shapiro, S. (2009). Value determination in the secondary ticket market: A quantitative analysis of the NFL playoffs. Sport Marketing Quarterly, 18, 5-13.

Dwyer, B., Drayer, J., & Shapiro, S. L. (2013). Proceed to checkout? The impact of time in advanced ticket purchase decisions. Sport Marketing Quarterly, 22, 166-180.

Fort, R. (2004). Inelastic sports pricing. Managerial and Decision Economics, 25, 87-94.

Gujarati, D. (2011). Econometrics by example. Hampshire, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.

Krautmann, A., & Berri, D. (2007). Can we find it at the concessions? Understanding price elasticity in professional sports. Journal of Sports Economics, 8, 183-191.

Krueger, A. (2001, Feb 1). Seven lessons about Super Bowl ticket prices. New York Times. Retrieved from http://www.nytimes.com/2001/02/01/business/economic-scene-sevenlessons-about-super-bowl-ticket-prices.html

Monroe, K., & Krishnan, R. (1985). The effect of price on subjective product evaluations. In J. Jacoby & J. Olson (Eds.), Perceived quality: How consumers view stores and merchandise (pp. 209-232). Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath.

Morganteen, J. (2014, January 27). The economics of Super Bowl tickets: TiqIQ CEO. CNBC. Retrieved from http://www.cnbc.com/id/101366720

O'Toole, T. (2010, April 22). NCAA reaches 14-year deal with CBS/Turner for men's basketball tournament. USA Today. Retrieved from http://content.usatoday.com/communities/campusrivalry/post/2010/04/ncaa-reaches-14-year-deal-with-cbsturner/1#.UmWCDhCzLMo

Rascher, D., McEvoy, C., Nagel, M., & Brown, M. (2007). Variable ticket pricing in Major League Baseball. Journal of Sport Management, 21, 407437.

Rao, A., & Monroe, K. (1988). The moderating effect of prior knowledge on cue utilization in product evaluation. Journal of Consumer Research, 15, 253-264.

Rishe, P. (2014a). Pricing insanity at March Madness: Exploring the causes of secondary price markups at the 2013 Final Four. International Journal of Sport and Society, 4, 67-78.

Rishe, P. (2014b, January 6). Distance, stadium capacity explain cheaper secondary prices for 2014 BCS National Championship Game. Forbes. Retrieved from http://www.forbes.com/sites/prishe/2014/01/06/distance-stadium-capacity-explain-cheaper-secondary-prices-for-2014-bcs-national-championship/

Rishe, P. (2014c, October). Do mobile sporting events produce net increases in tourism, local hotel revenues, and overall economic impact? Evidence using STR data. Mustang Journal of Business and Ethics.

Rishe, P. (2012, January 6). Dynamic pricing: The future of ticket pricing in sports. Forbes. Retrieved from http://www.forbes.com/sites/prishe/2012/01/06/dynamic-pridng-thefuture-of-ticket-pricing-in-sports/

Rovell, D. (2014, January 6). BCS title tickets selling on the cheap. ESPN.com. Retrieved from http://espn.go.com/collegefootball/bowls13/story/_/id/10250044/2014-vizio-bcs-national-champi-onship-tickets-cheapest-14-year-history

Salaga, S., & Winfree, J. A. (2013). Determinants of secondary market sales prices for National Football League personal seat licenses and season ticket rights. Journal of Sports Economics.

Scitovsky, T. (1945). Some consequences of the habit of judging quality by price. The Review of Economic Studies, 12, 100-105.

Shapiro, S., & Drayer, J. (2013). An examination of dynamic ticket pricing and secondary market price determinants in Major League Baseball. Sport Management Review, 17, 145-159.

Tsao, H., Pitt, L., & Caruana, A. (2005). The formation of 'high price-high quality' inferential belief: A study among young buyers of mobile phones and notebooks. Asia Pacific Journal of Marketing and Logistics. 17, 50-60.

Zeithaml, V. (1988, July). Consumer perceptions of price, quality, and value: A means-end model and synthesis of evidence. Journal of Marketing, 52, 2-22.

Zhu, J. D. (2014). Effect of resale on optimal ticket pricing: Evidence from Major League Baseball tickets. Working paper. Texas A&M University.

Endnotes

(1) These dollar value estimates for various segments of the secondary market were obtained through an email communication between one of the authors and an executive from a national ticket resale firm. The executive asked for anonymity.

(2) Input regarding the Selection Committee's duties, responsibilities, and challenges was obtained from prior informal conversations with Doug Elgin and Greg Shaheen. Mr. Elgin is the long-standing Commissioner of the Missouri Valley Conference and has five years of experience on the Selection Committee. Mr. Shaheen is a former Senior Vice President at the NCAA who for a decade oversaw the operational logistics of March Madness.

(3) Information on ticket allocation and pricing was provided to one of the authors via a May 2013 email communication with an NCAA executive working within the NCAA's Championships and Alliances team.

(4) One of the authors is the director of a consulting firm that has conducted economic impact studies at multiple Final Fours and Regionals since 2000. As such, he has cultivated business relationships with numerous civic leaders, collegiate sports executives, and NCAA officials who have shared informal in-person feedback regarding the operational logistics of both bidding upon and hosting Regional Finals and Final Fours.

(5) Rovell (2014) and Rishe (2014b) cite evidence that the secondary prices for the 2014 BCS National Championship game between Florida State and Auburn at the Rose Bowl in Pasadena CA were among the lowest in over a decade in part because of the distance the team's fans had to travel. Also, Morganteen (2014) quotes TiqlQ CEO Jesse Lawrence as saying that distance was a factor in why secondary prices for 2014's Super Bowl XLVIII between the Denver Broncos and Seattle Seahawks at MetLife Stadium near New York City were among the lowest for a Super Bowl in the last decade.

(6) Monroe and Krishnan's model has been validated and extended in a number of subsequent studies (e.g., Dodd and Monroe 1985; Zeithaml, 1988; Chapman, 1987; Rao and Monroe, 1988; Chapman and Wahlers, 1999).

(7) Markup percentage was chosen as the dependent variable in order to focus on the issue of how much fans were willing to spend over face in comparative terms across observations. "Markups in dollars" was deemed a weaker proxy since the same dollar markup (say $25) could represent a different 'percentage markup' across different face values (e.g., a $25 markup over a face of $175 is a larger percentage markup than if the face price was $225). Secondary sales prices did not include transaction fees.

(8) Alternatively, "miles" was considered as an independent variable, and was measured as the distance between the event site and the consumer's zip code. However, whether used in place of "State" or with "State" in either Model 1 or Model 2, the coefficient on "miles" was strongly insignificant and did not improve the adjusted R-squared.

(9) A team's RPI is weighted as 25% on the team's winning percentage, 50% on the team's opponents' winning percentage, and 25% on the opponents' opponents' winning percentage. For more, visit http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Ratings_Percentage_Index#Basketball_Formula.

(10) TicketCity is an Austin, TX based ticket broker founded in 1990. They have formal relationships with professional teams (San Francisco 49ers of the NFL), college athletic programs (including numerous schools from the Pac-12 Conference), and numerous college bowl games (including the Beef O'Brady's Bowl and BBVA Compass Bowl).

(11) The sample data from Table 5 indicates that fans were much more likely to buy Session 1 tickets than either All Session or Session 2 tickets for the Regionals. For the Final Four, the most commonly transacted ticket was the All Session pass. These results likely reflect the method of ticket allocation mentioned earlier (i.e., the NCAA only sells All-Session tickets for the Final Four, but sells each different type of Session for the Regionals ... and Session 1 appears to be the most popular among the 3 Sessions given its consistently higher markups).

(12) When H/S is present, OLS coefficient estimates are still unbiased but the OLS assumption of having an error term with constant variance is violated, thereby causing the standard errors and thus t-tests of individual variable significance to be unreliable.

(13) Given the presence of H/S, various remedial approaches were attempted following Gujarati's textbook prescriptions (Gujarati, 2011). The log transformation of the dependent variable did remove H/S but led to the sample size falling considerably given that many markup percentages were negative. Weighted least squares (WLS) using the predicted value of the dependent variable as the weight did not remove H/S. Conversely, White's corrected standard errors did remove H/S.

(14) To illustrate the importance of accounting for differences across micro-events, note that the adjusted R-squared was only 0.230 when Model 1 was run without the Regional dummies.

(15) Based on both first-hand consulting research that one of the authors has conducted for 3 Final Fours and 2 Regional Finals, coupled with informal conversations with tournament organizers who have collected data on the origin of event attendees at these events, approximately 80-95% of fans who typically attend these events come from outside the host site's MSA.

(16) Despite the noted limitations of "seeding" as a proxy for quality, it was tested. When used in place of RPI, the coefficient on "seeding" was negative and significant, but the adjusted R-squared fell by over one percentage point compared to the results reported in Table 9. Lastly, RPI and "seeding" could not be used in the same specification due to multicollinearity issues.

(17) Data for 2012-13 basketball revenues for the sixteen schools under consideration was obtained from the U.S. Department of Education's Office of Postsecondary Education (http://ope.ed.gov/athletics/).

(18) The NCAA has a 14-year, $10.8 billion media rights deal with CBS and Turner Sports, assuring the NCAA roughly $771 million annual in rights fees alone (O'Toole, 2010). And according to research by Kantar Media, CBS and Turner jointly netted over $1 billion in tournament ad sales revenue during March Madness in 2012, more than the respective playoffs and championship series for the National Football League, National Basketball Association, Major League Baseball and National Hockey League (Crupi, 2013).

(19) This information was provided by Smith Travel Research at the behest of one of the authors who sought hotel occupancy data during two separate presentations in April 2014 to civic groups in Orlando and St Louis, respectively, regarding the ability of early-round "pods" to increase net tourism activity.

Patrick J Rishe, PhD, is a professor of business and economics in the Business Department at Webster University. His research interests include ticket pricing and economic impact.

Michael Mondello, PhD, is an associate professor in the Department of Management at the University of South Florida. His research interests include stadium financing, contingent valuation method (CVM), employee compensation, analytics, and ticket pricing.

Brett Boyle, PhD, is an associate professor in the Department of Marketing at Saint Louis University. His research interests include sports consumer issues, sports sponsorship, and economic impact.
Table 1

Face Value Prices for 2013 Regionals

EAST
Price Points    All-Session   Session 1   Session 2

1                  $600         $340        $320
2                  $240         $130        $125
3                  $200         $110        $105
4                  $175          $98         $93

MIDWEST
Price Points    All-Session   Session 1   Session 2

1                  $600         $340        $320
2                  $160          $90         $85
3                  $130          $75         $70
4                   $90          $55         $50

SOUTH
Price Points    All-Session   Session 1   Session 2

1                  $600         $340        $320
2                  $200         $110        $105
3                  $150          $85         $80
4                  $100          $60         $55
5                   $70          $45         $40

WEST
Price Points    All-Session   Session 1   Session 2

1                  $600         $340        $320
2                  $250         $135        $130
3                  $200         $110        $105
4                  $180          $90         $85

Table 2
TicketCity Transactions by Event and Session

Regional     All-Session    Session 1   Session 2   Total

East              20           57          40        117
Midwest           0            53          49        102
South             43           130         58        231
West              15           49          32        96
Final Four       107           90          88        285

Total            185           379         267       831

Table 3
Regional and Final Four Participants at 2013 March Madness

RPI                     Distance

East Regional (Verizon Center, Washington DC)

Syracuse                   14        376
Marquette                  12        788
Indiana                     8        639
Miami                       4        1050
Sum                        38        2853
Median                     10       713.5

Midwest Regional (Lucas Oil Stadium, Indianapolis)

Louisville                  3        115
Oregon                     47        2280
Duke                        1        606
Michigan State              9        255
Sum                        60        3256
Median                      6       430.5

South Regional (AT&T Stadium, Arlington TX)

Kansas                      5        526
Michigan                             1200
Florida                     7        1000
Florida Gulf Coast         93        1250
Sum                        105       3976
Median                      7        1100

West Regional (Staples Center, Los Angeles)

Wichita State              37        1380
Ohio State                 10        2250
LaSalle                    46        2710
Arizona                    15        373
Sum                        108       6713
Median                     26        1815

Final Four (Georgia Dome, Atlanta)

Syracuse                   14        967
Michigan                   21        709
Louisville                  3        421
Wichita State              37        960
Sum                        75        3057
Median                    17.5      834.5

Table 4
Facility Capacity and Attendance at Regionals and Final Four

Regional      Capacity   Session 1   AttCap1%

East           20,308     19,731      97.2%
Midwest        36,000     35,520      98.7%
South          42,614     40,639      95.4%
West           18,997     18,232      96.0%
Final Four     80,000     75,350      94.2%

Regional      Session 2   AttCap2%

East           19,801       97.5%
Midwest        34,657       96.3%
South          36,585       85.9%
West           17,998       94.7%
Final Four     74,326       92.9%

Table 5
Average and Median Secondary Prices, Face Prices, and Markups

Means           Metric    East        MW

All Sessions     MU%     -12.6%      n/a
                  FV      $191       n/a
                  SP      $173       n/a
                  MU      -$18       n/a
Session 1        MU%      -6.7%     -8.1%
                  FV      $113       $70
                  SP      $110       $66
                  MU       -$3       -$5
Session 2        MU%     -16.5%     -35.8%
                  FV      $110       $71
                  SP       $95       $46
                  MU      -$15       -$25

Medians         Metric    East        MW

All Sessions     MU%     -32.3%      n/a

                  FV      $175       n/a
                  SP      $120       n/a
                  MU      -$57       n/a
Session 1        MU%     -24.5%     -23.6%
                  FV      $110       $75
                  SP       $87       $57
                  MU      -$27       -$14
Session 2        MU%     -40.6%     -44.0%
                  FV      $105       $85
                  SP       $66       $40
                  MU      -$43       -$30

Means           South     West    Final Four

All Sessions    -27.6%   -40.4%     47.0%
                 $160     $213       $226
                 $118     $129       $384
                 -$42     -$84       $158
Session 1       -25.1%   -43.8%     79.3%
                 $78      $127       $120
                 $58      $74        $226
                 -$20     -$53       $106
Session 2       -59.1%   -44.7%     36.6%
                 $89      $123       $124
                 $34      $68        $192
                 -$55     -$55       $67

Medians         South     West    Final Four

All Sessions    -36.0%   -50.0%     12.4%

                 $150     $200       $230
                 $106     $106       $223
                 -$52    -$106       $29
Session 1       -31.4%   -49.4%     58.5%
                 $85      $135       $125
                 $50      $63        $174
                 -$25     -$58       $62
Session 2       -65.0%   -57.9%     12.6%
                 $105     $130       $120
                 $33      $55        $136
                 -$64     -$69       $16

Table 6
Percentage of Transactions Resulting in Positive Markups

Regional      All-Session   Session 1   Session 2   Average

East             30.0%        29.8%       20.0%      26.6%
Midwest           n/a         32.1%       10.2%      21.2%
South            20.9%        16.9%       6.9%       14.9%
West             6.7%         12.2%       9.4%       9.4%

Final Four       57.9%        72.2%       56.8%      62.3%

Table 7

Model 1 Estimation with OLS Corrected Using White's HCSE

Variable         Coeff    t-value   p-value   Beta Coeff

Intercept        1.681     13.8     <.0001      0.000
Low              0.128      2.2     0.0253      0.072
High             -0.348    -7.5     <.0001      -0.201
Central          0.394      6.4     <.0001      0.225
East             -0.541    -9.6     <.0001      -0.220
Midwest          -0.596    -8.8     <.0001      -0.229
South            -1.035    -12.5    <.0001      -0.542
West             -0.918    -15.7    <.0001      -0.343
Qty              -0.466    -7.4     <.0001      -0.702
Qty2             0.028      3.7     0.0003      0.377
Time             0.001      1.3     0.2021      0.031
State            0.003      0.1     0.9588      0.002
Local            -0.119    -2.9     0.0038      -0.070
All Sess         -0.200    -3.1     0.0022      -0.097
Session 2        -0.420    -8.7     <.0001      -0.229

F-value          52.830
Pr > F           0.0001
Adjt R-squared   0.467    n = 831

Table 8
Model 2 Modified with Team/Event Specific Variables

Variable            Coeff       t-value     p-value   Beta Coeff

Intercept          -3.350        -4.34      <.0001
All Sess           -0.112        -1.68       0.097      -0.055
Session 2          -0.354        -4.87      <.0001      -0.193
Low                 0.147        2.52       0.0119      0.083
High               -0.329        -7.19      <.0001      -0.190
Central             0.396        6.18       <.0001      0.226
Qty                -0.468        -7.35      <.0001      -0.705
Qty2                0.028        3.63       0.0003      0.377
Time                0.001        1.32        0.188      0.033
State              -0.004        -0.05       0.956      0.002
Local              -0.132        -3.24       0.001      -0.077
AttCap              0.047         5.6       <.0001      0.165
RPI                -0.011        -2.25       0.025      -0.086
Prox              -0.000110      -2.43       0.015      -0.051
FF                  0.773        12.16      <.0001      0.429

F-value             37.54
Pr > F             0.0001
Adjt R-squared      0.475       n = 831

Table 9
Testing the Equality of Coefficients:
Final Four vs Regional Data

                      FULL               REGIONALS

Variable          Coeff    p-value   Coeff    p-value

Intercept         0.999    <.0001    0.811    <.0001
All Sessions      0.093    0.258     -0.148   0.001
Session 2         -0.283   <.0001    -0.218   <.0001
Low               0.217    0.004     0.065    0.161
High              -0.222   <.0001    -0.083   0.025
Central           0.178    0.002     0.035    0.268
Qty               -0.522   <.0001    -0.572   <.0001
Qty2              0.034    <.0001    0.051    <.0001
Time              0.001    0.208     0.003    <.0001
State             0.275    <.0001    0.151    0.0004

n                 831                546
Adjusted R-sqr    0.230              0.417
SSE               462.9              67.4
Chow Stat         63.62
Chow p-value      0.001

                    FINAL FOUR

Variable          Coeff    p-value

Intercept         2.192    <.0001
All Sessions      -0.269   0.021
Session 2         -0.705   <.0001
Low               0.292    0.022
High              -0.718   <.0001
Central           0.932    <.0001
Qty               -0.667   <.0001
Qty2              0.037    0.0001
Time              -0.003   0.055
State             0.102    0.328

n                 285
Adjusted R-sqr    0.454
SSE               192
Chow Stat
Chow p-value
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有