Examining the impact of the StubHub agreement on price dispersion in Major League Baseball.
Watanabe, Nicholas M. ; Soebbing, Brian P. ; Wicker, Pamela 等
Introduction
The second-hand ticket market has increased in recent years
(Drayer, 2011). While the history of the secondhand ticket market can be
traced back to the first sporting events which tickets were sold for,
the growth in technology has truly evolved this market. Twenty years
ago, consumers participating in the second-hand market would need to
visit a ticket broker or find a scalper in person from which to purchase
tickets. The rapid growth of technology has made purchasing of tickets,
both from the organization as well as from second-hand sources,
convenient and easy. The rise of the internet quickly alleviated the
need for individuals to spend time physically searching for tickets, as
they were able to find tickets being resold through various websites.
Several prominent websites quickly took advantage of the existence of
the second-hand ticket market, including EBay, StubHub, and Craigslist.
The secondary ticket market has been noted for its ability to offer
new opportunities for those groups which are part of a primary market
(Drayer, Stotlar, & Irwin, 2008). For example, Major League Baseball
(MLB) signed a revenue sharing agreement with the ticket sales website
StubHub.com in 2007 (just several months after StubHub was acquired by
Ebay Inc.; Lee & Mohl, 2007). Part of this agreement between StubHub
and MLB provided a platform through which consumers could legitimately
sell tickets (Drayer, 2011), since the secondary market was plagued with
issues regarding counterfeit tickets and fraud (Drayer et al., 2008).
Currently, most professional sport leagues in North America have an
official website for ticket reselling (Drayer, 2011).
The empirical setting for the present research is MLB. Prior to the
agreement in 2007 with StubHub, MLB franchises were concerned about the
rise of the secondary ticket market. For example, the New York Yankees
made the public claim that much of the decline in their ticket sales can
be directly attributed to ticket reselling on StubHub (Sandomir, 2006).
Since the Yankees and other MLB teams have to price their tickets before
the start of the regular season, the price of the ticket on the
secondary market can reflect the current information regarding team and
game quality along with consumer preferences for attending that game.
With the agreement with StubHub, MLB and its member teams were able to
gain important information about the real value of the ticket sales,
which also provided a better understanding of how organizations could
maximize their ticket revenue (Drayer et al., 2008).
The purpose of the present research is to examine how the MLB
agreement with StubHub has changed the ticket price dispersion of MLB
teams. Price dispersion is the distribution of prices for similar or the
same goods (Pan, Ratchford, & Shankar, 2002). The present research
uses ticket prices from the MLB media guides (called the Red and Green
Books) and individual websites to construct a unique dataset of MLB
ticket prices from 1975 until 2010 season (except for the 2009 seasons).
Estimating a fixed effect Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression to
control for team, league, and market factors, we find that the StubHub
agreement increases price dispersion amongst MLB teams. The findings
have implications for the marketing of professional sport franchises.
Teams can be encouraged to use the second-hand ticket market to their
advantage and benefit from the opportunity to receive information to
better price tickets prior to the season.
Theoretical Framework and Literature Review
Pricing in Sport
Pricing is an important component of the marketing mix because
pricing is the element of marketing where managers have expectations of
customers paying their money to the organization (Kopalle et al., 2009).
Compared with other elements of the marketing mix, pricing has the
advantage of a high level of flexibility. The flexibility is due to the
fact that prices tend to change continually (Smith, 2008). This
flexibility can be considered an advantage over other components of the
marketing mix. However, this advantage is less prevalent in some sports
leagues because of regulations, often placed by sport governing bodies,
which contain modulations and restrictions in regards to prices that are
allowed to be set (Smith, 2008).
The opportunity of quick price changes can also have disadvantages,
if they are not chosen deliberately. For example, customers stop
purchasing the product when prices are set too high and they do not come
back when prices are lowered afterwards. Yet, due to the high
involvement and emotional attachment of sports fans to their teams
(Mullin, Hardy, & Sutton, 2007); this effect should be less
pronounced in professional team sports. Taken together, prices can be
easily changed in many cases. However, there are organizations like MLB
which employ rules and regulations that make changing prices difficult
(Smith, 2008). In MLB, teams have to set prices prior to the regular
season. A glance at the literature reveals a considerable number of
papers which examined the effect of pricing from multiple perspectives
(e.g., Coates & Humphreys, 2007; Drayer & Shapiro, 2011; Drayer,
Rascher, & McEvoy, 2012; McDonald, Milne, & Hong, 2002; Rishe
& Mondello, 2004).
Price Dispersion
While ticket prices received attention in a variety of sport
disciplines (e.g., Drayer et al., 2012; Fort, 2004; Rascher, McEvoy,
Nagle, & Brown, 2007), few articles have focused on the concept of
price dispersion within sport (Humphreys & Soebbing, 2012). Price
dispersion is "the distribution of prices of an item with the same
measured characteristics across sellers" (Pan et al., 2002, p.
434). The seminal work of Stigler (1961), who observed the phenomenon in
the different prices for cars in the Chicago car market, began the
research in this area.
Price dispersion has received attention in other industries,
whereas the sport literature has largely neglected this topic with a few
exceptions (Humphreys & Soebbing, 2012). Over the past decade, a
considerable amount of research examined this pricing strategy within
traditional, online retailers, and multi-channel (mixture of online and
traditional) businesses (Pan et al., 2002). The present research is
particularly focused on the literature examining the impact of online
merchants on the price dispersion offered by traditional retailers.
Brown and Goolsbee (2002) found that the introduction of online
retailers within the life insurance market led to an initial increase in
price dispersion. As consumers began to increasingly use the web to
search life insurance rates and gather additional information, the
dispersion of prices decreased. Research by Kung, Monore, and Cox (2002)
found that the internet and internet based companies may assist
traditional brick and mortar companies in developing better pricing
strategies.
In the literature, there are reasons for why price dispersion
occurs. Traditionally, it was due to lack of information and uncertainty
for both sellers and consumers (Carlson & McAfee, 1983; Che &
Gale, 2002; Dana Jr., 1999, 2001; Stigler, 1961). Dana Jr.'s (1999)
development of a theoretical model put forth the idea that all firms
face some demand uncertainty. He noted that a good empirical setting to
test price dispersion under demand uncertainty would be to examine MLB
since prices have to be set well in advance of the actual event
occurring. Humphreys and Soebbing (2012) examined the phenomenon in MLB
from 1975 until 2008. They found that uncertainty, measured by the
standard deviation of a team's winning percentage over the last
five seasons, resulted in less dispersion. However, they did not examine
the potential impact that the Stub Hub agreement had on a team's
ticket pricing.
Price Dispersion and the Secondary Ticket Market
The fact that not all tickets are sold well in advance before an
event or that some tickets are sold again presents opportunities for the
secondary ticket market. Within this sophisticated market, brokers and
scalpers have established several ways to acquire tickets for the best
seats and sell them at prices between face and market value (Courty,
2000). Importantly, the level of price dispersion is associated with
differences in consumer preferences (Courty, 2003). Ideally, there are
two types of consumers: early buyers and late deciders. Promoters of
events have to make tickets available early to meet the needs of the
early buyers who value planning and want to secure the event consumption
well ahead of the event. The late deciding consumers, however, prefer
buying tickets close to the event date (typically from brokers). This
leads to potential conflicts between promoters and brokers. Given the
high prices on the secondary market (Shapiro & Drayer, 2012),
promoters are interested in securing the profits made by brokers. Yet,
Courty (2003) showed that the promoter is neither able to prevent the
broker from entering the market nor capture the broker's profits.
Therefore, some event promoters and leagues have put regulations in
place that restrict brokers.
For MLB, a lack of certainty regarding each game's expected
demand has contributed to the growth of the secondary ticket markets. In
2007, MLB and StubHub entered into a five-year revenue sharing agreement
(Stone & Richtel, 2007). As part of this agreement, MLB can directly
capture some of those ticket revenues that previously went to StubHub
and the secondary ticket market sellers. Moreover, the agreement also
calls for sharing of information between the two organizations (Newman,
2007). Thus, it provides an opportunity to better understand consumer
preferences. Within increased information on consumer preferences, MLB
teams can specifically learn about the characteristics of late deciders
who would typically buy their tickets on the secondary market and not
from the team. As a result, more effective pricing strategies can be
developed by individual teams with the goal of increasing revenue
(Drayer et al., 2008). These strategies support the overall conclusion
of Kung et al. (2005).
John Davis, Vice President for Ticket Sales for the Cincinnati
Reds, articulated how StubHub assists MLB teams in their pricing
strategy in the primary market. He stated, "'Teams are
provided a clear picture as to nuances of the secondary buyer by pricing
categories, proximity to the ballpark, and timing in regards to time of
purchase and the actual game [...] All these factors are extremely
helpful in understanding our fan base, how best to message to them, and
how to properly price our tickets'" (Associated Press, 2012,
n.p.).
In summary, MLB teams are able to offer more prices that are
specifically targeted at the preferences of their various consumer
groups. MLB benefits from this agreement since it can learn about
consumer preferences, provide a ticket price that may more accurately
reflect demand for games, and capture revenue that would previously be
gained by secondary ticket market sellers. Thus, we hypothesize that:
H1: An increase in information available to MLB teams prior to
setting regular season ticket prices with its agreement with StubHub is
associated with increasing price dispersion.
Method
Data Collection
In order to examine the effect that the agreement between StubHub
and MLB has on the ticket price dispersion of MLB teams, the present
research examines the ticket prices set by MLB teams prior to the start
of the season from 1975 to 2011. The ticket pricing data were gathered
from two main sources. The first source was the media guides published
by both the American and National Leagues. These publications contain
information for all the member teams as well as the league. The media
guides were purchased from 1975 until 2008. Starting in 2009, MLB moved
to electronic publication requiring an MLB granted password for viewing.
Repeated attempts by the authors for a password were denied by MLB. As a
result, ticket pricing levels were gathered from each of the individual
team's websites prior to the start of the 2010 seasons. The authors
are still unable to find the ticket prices for the 2009 season. Thus,
the complete sample period is from 1975 to 2008 and the 2010 seasons.
The sample size used in the present research was also decreased for
two additional reasons. The first was the elimination of the
observations for teams in Canadian markets. In the media guides, there
are inconsistencies with the reporting of the ticket prices. Second,
there were some instances where ticket prices were not published in the
media guides. Ticket prices were not published for the Baltimore Orioles
in 1979 and the Washington Nationals in 2005. Eliminating these two
team-season observations and all observations from Canadian teams
results in 899 team-season observations in the sample period.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Measures and Variables
Previous literature measured price dispersion in many different
ways (Ancarani & Shankar, 2004). In the present research, there are
two different dependent variables (DVs) that measure price dispersion.
The first is the number of price levels (PLN) a team offers in the
observed season. The number of price levels indicates a basic level of
dispersion, similar to using a range of prices. The second DV is the
Gini Coefficient (Gini) of those ticket price levels. The Gini
Coefficient is a widely used distribution measure in many disciplines
(Powell, 2003). Figures 1 and 2 examine the dependent variables over the
sample period. Notice in both figures that both the number of price
levels and ticket price inequality is increasing over the sample period.
This increase has been pronounced since the 1990s.
The present research measures the inequality amongst those ticket
price levels. Two regression models are run to examine the potential
impact that the StubHub agreement with MLB has on ticket pricing
behavior of MLB teams to test the two hypotheses of this research. Model
1 uses the Gini Coefficient of the ticket price (Gini) as the DV. In
Model 2, the number of price levels a team offers in one season (PLN) is
used as the DV. Both models are estimated in the following general form
using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS):
(1) [Ticket.sub.it] = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.1] [StubHub.sub.t] +
[[beta].sub.2] [MLBAM.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.3] [Perf.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.4] [NewStad.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.5] [Classic.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.6] [StadCap.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.7] [Trend.sub.t] +
[[epsilon.sub.it]
In Equation 1, i indexes teams, t indexes seasons, [alpha] is an
MSA fixed effect controlling for metropolitan statistical area specific
coefficients, and e is the equation error term reflecting unobserved
variation. StubHub is a variable equal to 1 for each team in the seasons
following the agreement between MLB and StubHub, 0 otherwise. MLBAM is
equal to 1 for each team in the seasons following the creation of Major
League Baseball Advanced Media (MLBAM). MLBAM was created in 2000 and
serves as the platform to direct consumers to StubHub (Stone &
Richtel, 2007). MLBAM also serves as the platform to other broadcasts
such as the NCAA March Madness (Warzel, 2012). Overall, MLBAM has been a
revenue producer for the league, which shares these revenues equally
amongst all 30 teams. This additional revenue from MLBAM may provide
additional information for teams regarding consumer preferences for MLB
games. PERF is the standard deviation of a team's winning
percentage over the past five seasons. This variable controls for the
variance in team performance as outlined in Dana Jr. (2001) and
empirically examined in Humphreys and Soebbing (2012). Dana Jr. (2001)
did not predict how team performance would affect price dispersion,
while Humphreys and Soebbing (2012) found that an increase in the
standard deviation of team performance led to a decrease in the standard
deviations of ticket price levels.
Three stadium variables are included in the model. NewStad is equal
to 1 in the seasons where the stadium is less than or equal to 10 years
old. This reflects the novelty effect of a new stadium, which previous
research defined as a short-term increase in attendance attributed to
the newness of the facility (Coates & Humphreys, 2005). Due to this
increase, teams may increase the dispersion of their ticket prices in
order to capture additional revenue from fans. Previous research has
also indicated that older stadiums see an increase in attendance
(McEvoy, Nagel, DeSchriver, & Brown, 2005). Thus, Classic is equal
to 1 for a team-season observation if its stadium is greater than 47
years old, corresponding to the result of McEvoy et al. (2005). Stadium
ages were calculated from the Ballparks.com website. StadCap is the
stadium capacity in season t. Capacity information was obtained from the
Red and Green books when available and then from ESPN.com for the
seasons after 2008. Finally, a linear time trend variable is included
(Trend) equal to 1 for the year 1975, 2 for 1976, etc. The linear time
trend controls for both the increase in the number of ticket prices and
for the increase in the Gini coefficient over the sample period as
illustrated by Figures 1 and 2. Controlling for the general increase
over time will further isolate the impact that the StubHub agreement has
on a team's ticket pricing policy.
Table 1 presents the summary statistics and correlation
coefficients for all the variables included in Equation 1. The final
sample of observations is 889 due to the elimination of the first two
seasons for each expansion team during the time period since there is no
opportunity to calculate a standard deviation of winning percentage
prior to year 3. During the sample period, MLB teams offered around six
or seven price levels on average per season. Notice that there is a wide
range of ticket prices. Some teams offered only two price levels in one
season, while other teams offered as many as 23 different price levels.
The average Gini Coefficient is 0.237 during the sample period with a
range of 0.100 (more equality) and 0.582 (less equality). Six percent of
team-season observations occur after the agreement between StubHub and
MLB. Twenty-three percent of the observations play in a stadium that is
10 years old or less. Eighteen percent of team-season observations play
in a stadium that is considered a classic stadium. Average stadium
capacity during the sample period is approximately 50,000.
Estimation Issues
Two potential estimation issues of the model should be discussed.
The first issue is multicollinearity. The presence of multicollinearity
is assessed using both the correlation coefficients and the variance
inflations factors. Notice in Table 1, all the correlation coefficients
are under the suggested threshold of 0.9 (Tabachnick & Fidell,
2007). Examining the variance inflation factors (vif), all are less than
or equal to 4 and thus under the acceptable threshold of 6 (Keith,
2007). As a result, multicollinearity should not be an issue with
Equation 1.
The second issue is the standard error correction. There are
certain facility effects that are unobserved due to the nature of
different, seats, viewing angles, etc. Thus, the standard errors are
clustered corrected by facility. Equation 1 was also estimated with
population and per capita income as independent variables. This
information was collected from the Bureau of Economic Analysis website
that is through the U.S. Department of Commerce. Including these two
independent variables does not change the results. They are excluded
from the present model because the vif for many independent variables
are greater than 6. Finally, there is concern that since Pln is a count
variable, estimating an OLS regression model without transforming the
dependent variable could present estimation issues. Thus, the
logarithmic transformation of the Pln (logPln) is presented along with
Pln.
Results
Table 2 presents the results of the fixed effect equation with
facility clustered standard errors. The three models explain between 64
and 74 percent of the observed variation in the dependent variables
(Gini, Pln, and logPln). In all three models, the StubHub variable is
positive and significant, providing support for H1. The effect of
StubHub on Gini indicates that the agreement with StubHub increased the
dispersion in ticket prices that MLB teams offered prior to the start of
the season.
Due to the additional information that MLB teams receive from the
agreement with StubHub, they are able to increase their price dispersion
to account for that information. By increasing price dispersion, teams
may be able to capture additional consumer surplus consistent with the
previous literature on the sources of price dispersion. Furthermore, the
agreement with StubHub significantly (p<.001) increased the number of
price levels (Pln and logPln), again supporting H1.
The introduction of MLBAM also increases both the inequality of
ticket price levels that a team offers and the number of price levels
offered for the season. The performance variable presents some
interesting and conflicting results. Recall that performance is measured
by the standard deviation of winning percentage for a team over the past
five seasons. Table 2 shows that performance has a negative effect on
ticket price inequality, a result that is similar to Humphreys and
Soebbing (2012). This means that the higher the variation in team
performance, the lower the price dispersion. However, variation in team
performance does not statistically impact the number of price levels a
team offers. Thus, price levels are not impacted by team performance
rather the price difference within those levels.
The three stadium variables provide relatively consistent results
across models. In all three models, playing in a new stadium increases
both the number of price levels and ticket price inequality. A classic
stadium also increases the inequality of prices; however, there are
mixed results when examining the number of price levels. It does
increase the number of price levels when not transforming Pln to logPln.
Overall, these two results indicate that teams are attempting to take
advantage of both the novelty effect of new stadiums and the nostalgia
effect of old stadiums by increasing the number of price levels and the
inequality within those price levels. The stadium capacity variable does
not have any effect on the levels and the prices of MLB tickets, a
finding that is consistent with previous research (Humphreys &
Soebbing, 2012). Finally, the time trend reflects both the increasing
inequality of ticket prices and the number of price levels of the sample
period.
Discussion
The present research looked at the effect of the StubHub agreement
on price dispersion in MLB. The major findings of this research (Table
3) have implications for marketing practice. As presented in Table 2,
the results showed that the StubHub agreement had a significant and
positive impact on price dispersion. Therefore, it can be recommended
that sport leagues enter official agreements with second-hand ticket
sellers to also generate the revenues from this market. Increased price
dispersion can help increase these revenues, as previous research has
shown that variable ticket pricing was associated with higher revenues
for sport franchises (Rascher et al., 2011). Thus, the use of
second-hand ticket market websites like StubHub seems to be beneficial,
although some teams complain about these partnerships (Sandomir, 2006).
From a policy perspective, the findings of this research indicate sport
leagues and organizations which sell tickets to events should consider
similar partnerships in the future, to better capture the second-hand
ticket market. Moreover, policy makers should work on the legit imacy
issues that second-hand ticket markets experience (Drayer & Martin,
2010).
This study provided evidence that teams have offered significantly
more price levels and that the inequality amongst ticket price levels
has significantly increased since the StubHub agreement. As there are
still some teams that only offer few price levels, they can be
encouraged to augment their number of price levels. Teams should use the
second-hand online ticket market to their advantage and increase their
variation in ticket prices. Given the positive relationship between
variable ticket prices and revenues (Rascher et al., 2011), teams should
benefit from the pricing flexibilities the second-hand ticket market
provides (or gives back) to them, despite existing ticket price
regulations set by the MLB. Taken together, it seems that the
second-hand ticket market has increased the complexity of pricing
behavior of teams in MLB.
The present research is not without limitations. It only looks at
price inequality and the number of different price levels, but does not
consider the actual prices and revenues that are associated with the
different price levels. Another limitation is that this research only
examines one sport league in one country. There may be other regulations
in other leagues and countries which lead to different structures in
pricing and effects on the secondary ticket market. Moreover, this study
takes--like most of the current price dispersion literature--a seasonal
approach to pricing of tickets to events. Thus, the current research
does not examine the use of variable ticket pricing for sporting events
from a game-to-game perspective.
The limitations of this study represent avenues for future
research. Further studies should examine the impact on the prices in the
secondary ticket markets to see if additional consumer surplus is indeed
being captured by teams with their pricing prior to the start of the
regular season. There is also a need to consider the importance of the
StubHub deal as the newest deal between MLB since the company had three
franchises (Chicago Cubs, New York Yankees, Los Angeles Dodgers) opt out
of participating in future years (Matthews, 2012). The three franchises
supposedly decided to remove themselves from the new five-year deal
because they felt that StubHub was decreasing the value of their
tickets. Results in this research hint that this may not be true, and
there will be need for future research in this area.
Another avenue for future research is to look at price dispersion
and the effects of the second-hand ticket market in other leagues and
countries. A further investigation of the effects of price dispersion on
consumption of tickets to sporting events for other professional and
collegiate sport leagues would be beneficial to see if additional
empirical evidence supports the findings of this study and previous
research. Additionally in future research, a game-to-game approach
should be used that considers variations in ticket prices during the
season.
References
Ancarani, F., & Shankar, V. (2004). Price levels and price
dispersion within and across multiple retailer types: Further evidence
and extension. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 32, 176-187.
Associated Press (2012, November 21). Teams looking closer at
secondary ticket market. ESPN Online. Retrieved from
http://sports.espn.go.com/espn/wire?section=mlb&id=8659108
Brown, J. R., & Goolsbee, A. (2002). Does the internet make
markets more competitive? Evidence from the life insurance industry.
Journal of Political Economy, 110, 481-507.
Carlson, J., & McAfee, P. (1983). Discrete equilibrium price
dispersion. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 480-493.
Che, Y., & Gale, I. (2000). The optimal mechanism for selling
to budget constrained buyer. Journal of Economic Theory, 92, 198-233.
Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2005). Novelty effects of new
facilities on attendance at professional sporting events. Contemporary
Economic Policy, 23, 436-455.
Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2007). Ticket prices,
concessions and attendance at professional sporting events.
International Journal of Sport Finance, 2, 161-170.
Courty, P. (2000). An economic guide to ticket pricing in the
entertainment industry. Recherche Economiques de Louvain--Louvain
Economic Review, 66, 167-192.
Courty, P. (2003). Some economics of ticket resale. Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 18, 85-97.
Dana Jr., J. D. (1999). Equilibrium price dispersion under demand
uncertainty: The roles of costly capacity and market structure. RAND
Journal of Economics, 30, 632-660.
Dana Jr., J. D. (2001). Monopoly price dispersion under demand
uncertainty. International Economic Review, 42, 649-670.
Drayer, J. (2011). Making a case for the integration of the primary
and secondary ticket markets for professional team sports in the United
States. International Journal of Sport Marketing and Sponsorship, 12,
199-208.
Drayer, J., & Martin, N. T. (2010). Establishing legitimacy in
the secondary ticket market: A case study of an NFL market. Sport
Management Review, 13, 39-49.
Drayer, J., & Shapiro, S. L. (2011). An examination into the
factors that influence consumers' perception of value. Sport
Management Review, 14, 389-398.
Drayer, J., Stotlar, D. K., & Irwin, R. L. (2008). Tradition
vs. trend: A case study of team response to the secondary ticket market.
Sport Marketing Quarterly, 17, 235-240.
Drayer, J., Rascher, D. A., & McEvoy, C. D. (2012). An
examination of underlying consumer demand and sport pricing using
secondary market data. Sport Management Review, 15, 448-460.
Fort, R. (2004). Inelastic sports pricing. Managerial and Decision
Economics, 25, 87-94.
Humphreys, B. R., & Soebbing, B. P. (2012). A test of monopoly
price dispersion under demand uncertainty. Economics Letters, 114,
304-307.
Keith, T. Z. (2006). Multiple regression and beyond. Boston, MA:
Pearson.
Kopalle, P., Biswas, D., Chintagunta, P. K., Fan, J., Pauwels, K.,
Ratchford, B. T., et al. (2009). Retailer pricing and competitive
effects. Journal of Retailing, 85, 56-70.
Kung, M., Monore, K. B., & Cox, J. L. (2002), Pricing on the
internet. Journal of Product & Brand Management, 11, 274-288.
Lee, S. Y., & Mohl, B. (2007, August 2). MLB, StubHub ink
resale deal. Retrieved from http://www.boston.com/business/globe/arti
cles/2007/08/02/mlb_stubhub_ink_resale_deal
Matthews, W. (2012, December 10). Yankees out of StubHub deal. ESPN
Online. Retrieved from http://espn.go.com/new
york/mlb/story/_/id/8733177/new-york-yankees-opt- stubhub-deal
announce-alliance-ticketmaster
McDonald, M. A., Milne, G. R., & Hong, J. (2002). Motivational
factors for evaluating sport spectator and participant markets. Sport
Marketing Quarterly, 11, 100-113.
McEvoy, C. D., Nagel, M. S., DeSchriver, T. D., & Brown, M. T.
(2005). Facility age and attendance in Major League Baseball. Sport
Management Review, 8, 19-41.
Mullin, B. J., Hardy, S., & Sutton, W. A. (2007). Sport
marketing. (3rd Ed.). Champaign, IL: Human Kinetics.
Newman, M. (2007, August 2). MLB.com partners with StubHub.
MLB.com. Retrieved from
http://mlb.mlb.com/news/article.jsp?ymd=20070802&content_id=2125
070&vkey=news_mlb&fext=.jsp&c_id=mlb (n.p.).
Pan, X., Ratchford, B. T., & Shankar, V. (2002). Can price
dispersion in online markets be explained in differences in e-tailer
service quality. Academy of Marketing Science, 30, 433-445.
Powell, T. C. (2003). Varieties of competitive parity. Strategic
Management Journal, 24, 61-86.
Rascher, D. A., McEvoy, C. D., Nagel, M., & Brown, M. T.
(2007). Variable ticket pricing in Major League Baseball. Journal of
Sport Management, 21, 407-437.
Rishe, P., & Mondello, M. (2004). Ticket price determination in
professional sports: An empirical analysis of the NBA, NFL, NHL, and
Major League Baseball. Sport Marketing Quarterly, 13, 104-112.
Sandomir, R. (2006, September 24). That season ticket on eBay? It
could cost seller the seat. New York Times. Retrieved from
http://www.nytimes.com/2006/09/24/sports/baseball/24tickets.html?_r=1
Shapiro, S. L., & Drayer, J. (2012). A new age of demand-based
pricing: An examination of dynamic ticket pricing and secondary market
prices in Major League Baseball. Journal of Sport Management, 26,
532-546.
Smith, A. C. T. (2008). Introduction to sport marketing. Oxford,
UK: Butterworth-Heinmann.
Stigler, J. (1961). The economics of information. Journal of
Political Economy, 69, 213-225.
Stone, B., & Richtel, M. (2007, August 2). Baseball gets into
resale of tickets. New York Times. Retrieved from
http://www.nytimes.com/2007/08/02/business/02tickets.html
Tabachnick, B. G., & Fidell, L. S. (2007). Using multivariate
statistics. Boston, MA: Allyn & Bacon.
Warzel, C. (2012, May 17). MLB Advanced Media planning major game
initiative: This summer CEO Bowman explains why platforms matter during
IAB sitdown. Adweek. Retrieved from
http://www.adweek.com/internet-week-blog/mlb-advanced-media
planning-major-game-initiative-summer-140611
Nicholas M. Watanabe, PhD, is an assistant professor of sport
management in the Department of Parks, Recreation, and Tourism at the
University of Missouri. His research interests include the demand for
sport, pricing, competitive, policy, develop, and communications in
sport.
Brian P. Soebbing, PhD, is an assistant professor of sport
management in the School of Kinesiology at Louisiana State University.
His research interests include the strategic behaviour of sports leagues
and teams, as well as the social and economic impacts of gambling.
Pamela Wicker, PhD, is a senior lecturer at the Department of Sport
Economics and Sport Management at the German Sport University Cologne.
Her research interests include sport finance, economics of sport
consumer behavior, and development of non-profit sport clubs.
Authors' Note
To the knowledge of the authors, there is no university library
that holds collections of the Red and Green Books. Daniel Rascher made
the initial purchase of media guides, and Brad Humphreys made a second
purchase of the media guides several years ago. We thank Dan and Brad
for allowing us access to the media guides to develop this unique
dataset.
Table 1
Summary Statistics and Correlation Coefficients
Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min Max 1
# Name
1 Pln 6.570 3.100 2 23 1
2 Gini 0.237 0.083 0.100 0.582 0.70
3 StubHub 0.098 0.297 0 1 0.53
4 MLBAM 0.319 0.467 0 1 0.71
5 Perf 0.051 0.020 0.008 0.153 -0.01
6 NewStad 0.227 0.419 0 1 0.32
7 Classic 0.181 0.385 0 1 -0.15
8 StadCap ('000) 49.807 8.590 33.679 78.000 -0.31
9 Trend 19 10 1 36 0.72
Variable 2 3 4 5
# Name
1 Pln
2 Gini 1
3 StubHub 0.42 1
4 MLBAM 0.64 0.48 1
5 Perf -0.03 -0.03 0.00 1
6 NewStad 0.29 0.10 0.28 0.00
7 Classic -0.08 -0.07 -0.13 -0.05
8 StadCap ('000) -0.21 -0.21 -0.34 0.03
9 Trend 0.57 0.50 0.79 0.08
Variable 6 7 8 9
# Name
1 Pln
2 Gini
3 StubHub
4 MLBAM
5 Perf
6 NewStad 1
7 Classic -0.26 1
8 StadCap ('000) -0.20 -0.10 1
9 Trend 0.21 -0.14 -0.28 1
n = 889
Table 2
Summary of Regression Results
DV Gini Pln logPln
coeff. p coeff. P coeff. P
StubHub 0.036 0.019 2.476 <0.001 0.182 <0.001
(0.015) (0.506) (0.045)
MLBAM 0.066 <0.001 1.713 <0.001 0.205 <0.001
(0.010) (0.277) (0.040)
Perf -0.248 0.027 -5.683 0.086 -0.735 0.102
(0.110) (3.237) (0.441)
NewStad 0.032 0.001 0.922 <0.001 0.092 0.009
(0.009) (0.233) (0.033)
Classic 0.042 0.020 1.047 0.035 0.129 0.072
(0.017) (0.483) (0.070)
StadCap 0.000 0.599 -0.025 0.191 -0.004 0.135
(0.001) (0.019) (0.003)
Trend 0.001 0.035 0.109 <0.001 0.019 <0.001
(0.000) (0.013) (0.002)
[R.sup.2] 0.644 0.732 0.739
Fixed MSA MSA MSA
Effects
SE Facility Facility Facility
Cluster
Note Displayed are the unstandardized coefficients, standard errors
in brackets. Dependent variable is the Gini Coefficient of a team.
Table 3
Summary of Major Findings and Implications
Major Point Resulting Major Implication for Practice
From Research Inquiry and/or Further Research
1. StubHub agreement has It can be recommended that sport leagues
significant and positive (and teams) enter official agreements
impact on price with second-hand ticket sellers to
dispersion generate the revenues from the
second-hand market. This can be
beneficial since variable ticket pricing
was associated with higher revenues in
previous research.
2. Teams in MLB have Teams with fewer price levels can be
offered significantly encouraged to increase their number of
more price levels since price levels.
the StubHub agreement.
3. The inequality amongst It can be recommended that teams use the
ticket price levels has second-hand online ticket market to
significantly increased their advantage and increase their
since the StubHub variation in ticket prices. Future
agreement. research could examine the impact on the
prices in the secondary ticket markets
to see if additional consumer surplus is
being captured by teams.
4. Second-hand ticket Further research should look at the
market has increased effects of the second-hand ticket market
the complexity of in other leagues and countries.
pricing behavior of
MLB teams.