Welfare Reform: An Exploration of Devolution.
Pandey, Shanta ; Collier-Tenison, Shannon
Introduction
IN THE EARLY 1990s DEVOLUTION OF POWER TO ADMINISTER SOCIAL
PROGRAMS AND services in the United States occurred from the federal to
state and local governmental units. Devolution -- defined in
Webster's Ninth New Collegiate Dictionary as "the transference
(as of rights, powers, or responsibility) to another; especially, the
surrender of powers to local authorities by a central government"
-- has proved to be a divisive issue in the United States. Supporters of
devolution argue that governmental units that are closer to the people
(whether state or local) are more knowledgeable about and better
positioned to respond to people's needs and challenges with greater
imagination and insight than are federal units (Borut, 1996; Buckley,
1996; Conlan, 1998; Kingsley, 1996). Those who oppose devolution contend
that block granting of welfare programs to states is based on inaccurate
premises and will hurt the poor and the nation at large (Caraley, 1996,
1998; Donahue, 1997a, 1997b; Goldberg, 1996; Kuttner, 1995; Steuerl e
and Mermin, 1997; Weaver, 1996). Still others have mixed views regarding
the merits of devolution of welfare programs to the states (Gold, 1996;
Nathan, 1997). In this article we ask the following questions: How does
the recent decentralization of welfare administration responsibilities
to states and local governments fit within the context of evolution of
welfare programs and services in the United States? Why did state and
local political units support the welfare devolution legislation of
1996? How does this differ from earlier governmental moves to
decentralize power? What is the true function of welfare in the U.S.?
Are certain governmental units better suited to undertake the
responsibility of welfare administration than others? Finally, what are
the limitations of the welfare legislation of 1996?
Background
There has been ongoing debate over the division of responsibilities
between the federal government and the states since the 1700s, when the
first federal grants were issued to states and localities (Brown and
Corbett, 1997; Nathan and Lago, 1990; Rivlin, 1991). Between 1880 and
1910, pensions for Civil War veterans comprised over one-quarter of
federal expenditures, with 90% of surviving Union veterans collecting
pensions by 1910 (Skocpol, 1995). Besides the 28% of men aged 65 or
more, over 300,000 widows, orphans, and other dependents of Union
soldiers received federal benefits during this time. In contrast to the
Civil War Pension Acts (Skocpol, 1995; 1998), local governments and
charities in the U.s. were primarily responsible for providing poor
relief through the time of the Great Depression (Brown, 1940; Nathan,
1997). During the 1930s, states took a more active role as they
attempted to reduce the high rates of unemployment and to boost the
economy through various work relief programs. Although these p rograms
were federally subsidized, only after the passage of the Social Security
Act of 1935 did the federal government begin to directly share the
responsibility of providing relief to the poor through a variety of
social welfare programs. Even today, most of our public assistance
programs stem from this act (Gordon, 1994).
The passage of the Social Security Act reflected the general
political sentiment that the federal government had a role in
alleviating poverty among children, the elderly, and the unemployed
(Brown and Corbett, 1997; Rivlin, 1991). Among the various programs
established by this act were Supplemental Security Income (SSI), or
old-age assistance, unemployment compensation, and Aid to Dependent
Children (later known as Aid to Families with Dependent Children [AFDC]). The 11 public assistance programs established under the Social
Security Act were aimed at different social groups and operated under
different terms (Gordon, 1994). Due to discontent with perceived state
neglect, many services that were previously regarded as a function of
the states became the responsibility, or shared responsibility, of the
federal government, including poverty alleviation programs, income
transfer programs, and federal work training and manpower development
programs (Rivlin, 1991). In short, where state or local governments were
unwilling or unable to act, federal programs established a safety net
for the poor (Caraley, 1996). At the same time, critics of this new
federal welfare system have argued that the differential foci and terms
of the various programs, and AFDC in particular, set up a stratified,
inequitable system along gender, racial, and class lines (Abramovitz,
2000; Gordon, 1994; Piven and Cloward, 1993).
Despite calls to slow the trend of federal expansion as negative
reaction to centralization developed (Brown and Corbett, 1997; E.
Peterson, 1995; G. Peterson, 1995), the evolution of new federal
programs continued. In the 1960s, President Lyndon B. Johnson's War
on Poverty fueled an explosion of new programs. The federal government,
often bypassing state governments, expanded social welfare programs,
insured bank deposits, financed healthcare for indigent populations and
the elderly, and provided education loans for students (Brown and
Corbett, 1997; Rivlin, 1991). Many of these programs assumed the task of
changing individual poverty conditions and empowering communities.
Contrary to the beliefs of many conservatives, programs of the Great
Society did not represent a usurpation of power by the federal
government (Brown and Corbett, 1997; Caraley, 1996; Corbett, 1997). In
fact, under federal regulations, local officials administered most
federally funded programs for the poor (Caraley, 1996).
Between the mid-1960s and the mid-1970s, a new philosophy of
poverty alleviation evolved as the federal government began to calculate
and distribute benefits based upon an income threshold (Corbett, 1997).
Cash income-support programs such as AFDC and in-kind programs such as
Food Stamps, Medicaid, and Housing Assistance became federal entitlement
programs aimed at populations deemed most deserving of help, while local
governments maintained responsibility for general assistance programs
designated for single or ablebodied adults (Brown and Corbett, 1997;
Corbett, 1997). To reach Black voters, the federal government
circumvented local governments to expand Great Society programs into the
inner cities (Piven and Cloward, 1993). Minorities and women also began
to claim welfare as a strategy to move out of poverty in conjunction
with the women's movement and increased labor force participation.
Unfortunately, these tactics resulted in a strong conservative backlash
and a move by Democrats to appeal to conservat ive voters, so that the
benefits of centralization began to be questioned again (Gordon, 1994;
Piven and Cloward, 1993).
In the 1970s, a movement to give states and local governments
unrestricted federal funds and maximum discretion over spending
characterized a new federalism (Videka-Sherman and Viggiani, 1996;
Wright, 1998). In 1972, President Richard Nixon enacted general revenue
sharing for the first time, bringing "no strings" direct
federal monies ($6.1 billion annually) to many states and local
governmental units (Conlan, 1998). General revenue sharing combined
"the advantages of raising revenues at the national level with the
advantages of local discretion over spending" (Ibid.: 65). State
and local governments had flexibility in the use of federal funds
received through general revenue sharing, while federal regulations,
paperwork, and choice over the allocation of these funds were minimized.
At the same time, the Nixon administration launched three block grant
initiatives with increased local discretion on spending in an attempt to
curb mismanagement and waste at the federal level (The National Journal,
1995). This b lock grant policy continued through the Ford and Carter
administrations. President Gerald Ford signed community development
block grant legislation in 1974 and consolidated social services funds
to welfare recipients into a block grant in 1975. Although not much
change occurred with regard to devolution of welfare spending during the
Carter administration, federal funding to state and local governments
peaked in 1978 (Conlan, 1998).
In the 1980s, the focus of the federal policy changed course,
diminishing the notion of a social safety net as a federally funded
entitlement. In the interest of reducing federal government activity and
freeing state and local governments to take a more active role, the
Reagan administration called for a new federalism by moving to a system
of block grants with reduced federal funding. Seventy-seven categorical programs were consolidated into nine block grants with reduced funding,
and 62 additional programs were terminated (Conlan, 1998). Through block
granting, the Reagan administration cut federal taxes and deregulated
federal-state relations (Brown and Corbett, 1997; Conlan, 1998; Jost,
1996; E. Peterson, 1995; G. Peterson; 1995; Rivlin, 1991). General
revenue sharing, a large program fiscally, was phased out for states in
1980 and for local governments in 1986, thus offsetting the gains made
by advocates of devolution in obtaining special block grants (Conlan,
1998). At the same time, the federal govern ment continued to exercise
major authority in the regulation of social program standards.
The Bush administration continued the fiscal policies as outlined
during the Reagan years. With bipartisan support from state governors,
the Family Support Act of 1988 established new federal requirements for
welfare while providing more local flexibility (Brown and Corbett, 1997;
Katz, 1995; Rivlin, 1991). States were encouraged to experiment with
changes in the welfare system by taking advantage of waiver options
offered by the Department of Health and Human Services, which allowed
deviation in specific ways from federal program guidelines (Lurie,
1997). Whereas only 10 states successfully obtained waivers allowing
experimentation with welfare programs between 1988 and 1990, that number
doubled to include 20 states by 1993 (Brown and Corbett, 1997).
Although welfare reform originated as a conservative issue,
liberals and even welfare clients joined the calls for reform of an
ineffective system in the early 1990s (Gordon, 1994). The Clinton
administration, as part of an earlier strategy for economic recovery,
continued to promote a redistribution of wealth upward, limited federal
government, and a shrinking of social welfare programs (Abramovitz,
1994). This administration further strengthened the role of states with
an easier waiver process, resulting in greatly increased numbers and
complexity of statebased welfare demonstrations by the mid-1990s (Brown
and Corbett, 1997). By 1996, about 90% of the states had successfully
obtained at least one waiver to accommodate their own preferences for
welfare policy goals and innovative program strategies (Ibid.; Corbett,
1997). This resulted in a wide range of social programs, both in program
type and in level of success. Although program results varied, each
waiver offered greater flexibility to local governmen ts in designing
programs to meet the needs of state and local government populations
(Nathan, 1997; Pandey et al., 1999a; E. Peterson, 1995; G. Peterson,
1995).
By the 1990s, a conservative movement to reform welfare was well
underway, despite opposition from welfare rights organizations, female
academics and professionals, and some feminist groups (Abramovitz,
2000). Five of the many factors instrumental in shifting welfare policy
goals are: the changing demography and size of the welfare population;
the changing demography of the American labor force; the growth in
federal social welfare spending and rising concern that federal
government is inefficient; the debate over negative effects of public
assistance on recipients; and a supportive political environment.
1. Changing demography and size of the welfare population: The
earliest welfare recipients were mostly white women with children, whose
husbands were victims of war -- recipients viewed as "worthy"
of minimum public assistance. Over time, as the number of welfare
caseloads and costs rose dramatically, the demography of welfare
recipients also changed. In 1940, the average monthly number of welfare
recipients was about one million. This number increased to two million
in 1950, 3.1 million in 1960, 7.4 million in 1970, 10.6 million in 1980,
11.4 million in 1990, and 14.2 million in 1994 (Committee on Ways and
Means, 1996). In 1976, 20.8% of all single women receiving welfare were
never married, but by 1992 over half (52.3%) of all single women
receiving welfare were never married (GAO, 1994a). Furthermore, in 1992
approximately 42% of all single women receiving welfare gave birth as
teenagers, and over half (52.8%) had incomes below 50% of the poverty
line (GAO, 1994b). Although marital and birth patterns of w elfare
mothers reflect societal trends (GAO, 1994a), these mothers face many
barriers to exiting poverty through employment due to the lack of needed
services (including childcare, healthcare, and transportation), gender
and racial discrimination (Hagen, 1995), and a lack of education,
employment skills, and work experience (GAO, 1994a; 1994b).
2. Changing demography of the American labor force: The dramatic
rise in the participation of American mothers in the labor force in the
last two decades resulted in a change in public attitudes toward working
mothers (Orthner and Kirk, 1995; Szanton, 1991). In 1960, only 30.4% of
all women with children participated in the labor force, whereas by 1987
their labor force participation rate had increased to 64.7% (Reischauer,
1989). Feminist emphasis on an expansion of women's workplace
rights furthered the assumption that women ought to work outside the
home, possibly confusing middle-class women's right to work with
poor women's obligation to do so (Mink, 1998a). While middle-class
mothers can choose to make childrearing a full-time job, poor mothers do
not have this choice. Indeed, as Mink (Ibid.: 150) notes, "except
among welfare rights activists and a handful of feminists, no one has
defended the right of poor mothers to raise their children, and no one
has questioned the proposition that poor single moth ers should have
to.. .work outside the home." As a result, most welfare mothers are
now perceived as undeserving of long-term public benefits and thus are
required to work in return for welfare (Kaus, 1992; Mead, 1986; 1992).
3. Growth in federal spending on social welfare programs for the
poor: When the federal outlay was compared to perceived outcomes, the
federal government appeared to be bureaucratic, inefficient, and distant
in providing for the welfare needs of its people (Caraley, 1996, 1998;
Donahue, 1997a; Goldberg, 1996; Kuttner, 1995; Steuerle and Mermin,
1997; Weaver, 1996). The general perception of many conservative leaders
was that "Washington was trying to do too much with too little
success and with too much micromanagement" (Weaver, 1996: 52).
Proponents of welfare reform argued that federal welfare policy had
failed, that local governments were better positioned to respond to
local preferences and circumstances, and that federal budget restraints
would be better served by block rather than open-ended grants (Bailey
and Koney, 1996; Borut, 1996; Brown and Corbett, 1997; Casse, 1997;
Corbett, 1997; Goldberg, 1996; Kingsley, 1996; E. Peterson, 1995; G.
Peterson, 1995; Watson and Gold, 1997). As federal policymaker s
despaired of national solutions to the problems of welfare, block grants
to the states that transferred control of welfare policy appeared to be
a viable solution.
4. Sensational debate over the outcomes of public assistance
programs: As AFDC caseloads continued to rise, conservative politicians
began to express concern over the negative consequences of welfare and
long-term dependency upon public support, as well as growing doubts
about who among the poor deserve help (Videka-Sherman and Viggiani,
1996). Some researchers (including Murray, 1984) contended that public
assistance actually caused many of society's ills, including
poverty. It was argued that individuals and even communities were
altering behavior to take advantage of federal entitlement programs
(Ibid.), proof that federal programs were not having the desired effect
on poverty and welfare use. In contrast, many state welfare reform
initiatives linked welfare benefits to personal responsibility or
changes in personal behavior, a sort of "social engineering"
(Corbett, 1997:4). Without a strong feminist counterargument, poor women
found themselves and their private behavior at the center of a very
public dis cussion about the worth of continuing public assistance
programs as an entitlement (Mink, 1998a).
Through devolution, states felt that they could end entitlement
programs that were viewed negatively by government officials and
citizens of the state (Corbett, 1997; Governors' Bulletin, 1997).
Moreover, along with shifting control of many public welfare programs,
the state waiver experiments (and later the welfare legislation of 1996)
allowed states to set welfare supports and sanctions so that desired
behaviors such as work, marriage, education, and reduced fertility were
emphasized (Corbett, 1997; Videka-Sherman and Viggiani, 1996).
5. Supportive political environment: In response to popular
ambivalence and a political climate supporting welfare devolution, Bill
Clinton, in his first presidential campaign, promised that he would
"end welfare as we know it." On August 22, 1996, President
Clinton kept his promise by signing the Personal Responsibility and Work
Opportunity Reconciliation Act (PRWORA), which limited federal authority
over program standards, reduced and block-granted federal funds, and
eliminated entitlement status (U.S. Congress, 1996). This law reflected
public sentiment that the able-bodied poor who are of working age should
change their reproductive and parenting behavior and engage in
productive employment. Moreover, passage of the PRWORA helped to fulfill
other political agendas. Socially conservative politicians used welfare
reform to promote their own views of family values, while liberal
politicians established conservative credentials through their support
of PRWORA (Abramovitz, 2000). Congressional feminists also voted in
favor of the new welfare law to show support for increased work
opportunities for women and increased responsibility from absent fathers
(Mink, 1998a).
Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act
PRWORA) of 1996
The PRWORA revamped 60 years of welfare tradition and decentralized the authority for welfare administration to state and local governmental
units. Major changes under PRWORA include the end of welfare as an
entitlement to individuals, the creation of time limits, and the
addition of a work requirement. States and local governments now have
much wider discretion over the block grants they receive (U.S. Congress,
1996; Powers, 1999). According to this law, adults can receive cash
assistance for a maximum of five cumulative years in their lifetimes (or
less at state option) and must begin working after two years of
receiving assistance. State and local governments may require community
service as early as two months after public assistance begins. The law
also requires that by fiscal year 2002, states put 50% of single parents
receiving cash assistance in work programs for at least 30 hours per
week.
Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF) block grants, unlike
the open-ended federal matching grants under AFDC, consolidate grants
from AFDC, the Job Opportunities and Basic Skills (JOBS) program, and
some Emergency Assistance funds to create a fixed-amount grant (U.S.
Congress, 1996). The cost of income maintenance and service programs is
no longer shared proportionately between federal and local governing
bodies, as the federal role is substantially reduced (Brown and Corbett,
1997). Moreover, PRWORA has shifted the emphasis of welfare to altering
the personal behaviors of recipients. Under this law, poor single
mothers became the only people in America required by law to participate
in the labor market and to identify the biological fathers of their
children (Mink, 1998b).
Tribes and Local Governments
Another dimension of the PRWORA is its Section 412, which bestowed
power to American Indian tribal governments to administer their own
public assistance programs (U.S. Congress, 1996). This legislation
authorizes the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (DHHS) to
provide direct funding to tribes that wish to design and operate their
own TANF services (Pandey et al., 1999a; 1999b). Tribes that take this
option must be prepared to forge new relationships with the federal
government and the states to access this funding as new service systems
compete for limited resources.
As the federal government shifted the authority to administer
social welfare policies and programs to states and tribes, the latter in
turn will pass the administration authority on to counties and tribal
political subunits (Nathan, 1997; The Economist, January 3, 1998). Some
states (e.g., California, Colorado, Minnesota, New York, Ohio, and
Wisconsin) are already giving their counties authority to design and
administer their own welfare services (Gallagher et al., 1998; GAO,
1998). Tribal governments must also decide if their local governing
units have adequate resources to administer and support welfare
programs. These decisions probably will be made at the local level as
more authority is given to tribal political subunits; that was the case
with the "Local Governance Act," which was recently passed by
The Navajo Nation. This act provides broader recognition of local
governments, for it allows tribal chapters to make decisions over local
matters, including the administration of welfare programs and servic es
(Office and Commission on Navajo Government Development, 1998).
A review of the evolution of welfare policies in the U.S. indicates
that federal and state governments have periodically expanded or shrunk their welfare responsibilities. Thus, in the future federal welfare
responsibility for the poor may again expand in some ways where state
and local governments are unwilling or unable to act. In the following
section we revisit the motivation behind state and local
governments' support for welfare devolution.
Why Did State and Local Governments Support the 1996 Welfare
Legislation?
State and local governments supported passage of the 1996 welfare
legislation for several reasons. First, state and local officials, with
the general agreement of many U.S. citizens, felt that local
governmental units were better equipped than the federal government to
slow the rate of growth of welfare populations and welfare spending.
Second, prominent Republican governors expressed a desire for tax
reductions and budget cuts (Videka-Sherman and Viggiani, 1996; Weaver,
1996). Republican congressional leaders viewed devolution as a potential
solution to their problems, beyond reducing the national deficit and
increasing congressional support among Republican governors (Weaver,
1996). Many Democrats viewed it as an opportunity to reach out to
conservative elements of their constituencies (Abramovitz, 2000).
A third initial driving force of devolution was the support of the
National Governors' Association for state autonomy over welfare
programs (Brown and Corbett, 1997; Katz, 1995; Lurie, 1997; E. Peterson,
1995; G. Peterson, 1995; The Economist, 1995). Led by the Republican
Governor's Association, many governors expressed a willingness to
accept limited federal funds for welfare, in the form of block grants,
in exchange for unprecedented state autonomy in structuring program
reforms. These proposed reforms were seen as an opportunity for the
states to develop innovative new welfare programs (Bailey and Koney,
1996; Katz, 1995), as well as to economize by saving administrative
costs and relying more heavily upon private industry and community
organizations (e.g., churches, nonprofit agencies, etc.) to support
reforms (Corbett, 1997; Shapiro, 1987; Watson and Gold, 1997). The use
of block grants allows state governments to support private industry in
their own states and potentially to conserve funds by contract ing out
portions of welfare administration. Although welfare benefits vary
greatly across states, many state governors maintained that a move to
unrestricted welfare block grants would not result in a reduction of
their commitment to serve the most vulnerable citizens (Chernick and
Reschovsky, 1996; E. Peterson, 1995).
Although tribal representatives were not as actively involved as
were state governors in designing the welfare legislation of 1996,
tribal governments have historically sought to self-administer tribal
social and economic development programs (Pandey et al., 1999a; 1999b).
A primary argument in favor of devolution to tribes is that tribal
members are better positioned to address the unique challenges and
problems faced by American Indians due to their distinct culture, strong
history of oppression, and geographic isolation (Ibid.). Moreover, the
PRWORA acknowledges the scarcity of economic development and
self-sufficiency on reservations. Tribal governments also favored the
devolution of federal authority in welfare reform because of the greater
flexibility and simplified administrative and reporting requirements.
Fourth, although the passage of PRWORA officially designated the
devolution of AFDC, actual devolution had already occurred in many ways
through the states' use of waivers to experiment with welfare
reform. As a result, many of the changes required by the new law, such
as time limits and work requirements, came as a direct result of
innovative state programs and were actually already underway in the
states (Governors' Bulletin, 1997). Although it is too early to
tell if these reform initiatives will prove successful, welfare
caseloads decreased significantly as a direct result of these waiver
programs.
State Welfare Reform Initiatives
By 1995, more than 51 welfare demonstration programs were operating
in 27 states (Public Welfare, 1995). When PRWORA was signed into law in
1996, 46 states already had experimental programs underway (Gallagher et
al., 1998). Many of these programs were much bolder and multidimensional
than earlier welfare experiments, and many involved initiatives designed
to influence personal and community responsibility. In Wisconsin,
Learnfare required teen mothers to meet school attendance requirements
in order to collect benefits. Ohio provided a bonus to teenage parents
who returned to high school after dropping out if they had fewer than
five absences in a month (Editor's Report, 1992). Demonstration
programs in Mississippi and Texas involved a wide range of community
partners, including faith-based organizations. Massachusetts, Oregon,
Missouri, Maryland, Pennsylvania, and others offered financial
incentives to encourage employers to hire welfare recipients
(Governors' Bulletin, 1997).
Participants in the "To Strengthen Michigan Families"
program develop a contract of actions that may involve establishing
paternity, attending parenting or training classes, and increasing work
hours (Governors' Bulletin, 1997). Attributed to the use of this
social contract are a drop of 60,000 cases from the welfare rolls and an
all-time high of 29% of AFDC recipients earning income in that year
(Engler and Abraham, 1995; Governors' Bulletin, 1997). In
Tennessee's "Families First" program, welfare recipients
also create a personal responsibility plan that commits recipients to 40
hours a week of work, training, or school attendance. This program also
provides daycare and transportation, but has an 18-month time limit on
benefits (Governors' Bulletin, 1997). Many other states have put
resources into childcare for welfare recipients to overcome the serious
challenges faced by welfare parents making the transition from welfare
to work (Ibid.).
Although states such as Michigan and Tennessee are considered to be
innovators in the area of welfare reform, Wisconsin has served as a
model for the nation, even with mixed reviews from critics (see, for
example, Boehnen and Corbett, 1996a; Bush, 1996; Department of Workforce
Development, 1996; Engler and Abraham, 1995; Ethridge and Percy, 1993;
Lurie, 1996; Mead, 1997; Moore, 1997; Vitale, 1995; Wiseman, 1996).
Beginning with an innovative approach to the federal JOBS program and
culminating with Wisconsin Works, welfare reform in Wisconsin has taken
place in several stages. Between 1986 and 1994, Wisconsin's welfare
caseload declined by 23% (Mead, 1997), while the nation's total
increased (Bush, 1996; Wiseman, 1996). Real benefits of AFDC in
Wisconsin were reduced by 31% during this period, while the real value
of the need standard declined by 26%. It is noteworthy that by reducing
the payment standards of AFDC, the available welfare benefit package
became less attractive than labor market wages (Wiseman, 1996).
Wisconsin Works (W-2) -- a "work-based system of public aid
providing services, subsidies, and opportunities to help parents
establish their own means of support, primarily through work, and then
help them maintain long-term self-support" (Bush, 1996:1) -- was
the groundbreaking program that made Wisconsin a leader in the area of
welfare reform. Signed into law in early 1996, W-2 was established to
end individual entitlement to cash assistance through a four-tiered
program of assessment training, community service jobs, trial
(subsidized) employment, and unsubsidized employment. With a 60-month
lifetime limit on benefits, W-2 provided the first fully articulated
model of how block grants could be used to restructure a state welfare
program (Wiseman, 1996).
Common traits shared by most of the state demonstration programs
are a reduction in welfare caseloads and an initial increase in
expenditures for welfare (Ganzglass, 1996; Long and Wissoker, 1995;
Moore, 1997; Wiseman, 1996). Florida, Vermont, and Wisconsin, three of
the first states to receive approval for time-limited welfare
demonstrations, found that changing the focus of welfare from a cash
entitlement to a work requirement was an expensive proposition. All
three states experienced high expenditures, although Florida and
Wisconsin expect to see a savings pattern in the longer-run. Regardless
of the expense, state officials judged the implementation of flexible
time limits to be worth the initial cost (Ganzglass, 1996). In contrast,
the "Family Independence Program" in Washington state cost
much more than AFDC, and the program outcomes were exactly the opposite
of expectations. Under this ambitious program, which was structured in a
manner similar to the federal JOBS program, employment fell and welfare
participation rose (Long and Wissoker, 1995).
A review of state and local government support of recent welfare
reform legislation indicates that beyond their desire for tax cuts,
budget cuts, and flexibility in spending, officials gained confidence
from waiver implementations. Many states will see changes in savings as
welfare recipients reach their time limits and caseloads decrease.
States are also experiencing a windfall of funds as the level of federal
reimbursement continues at 1995 levels (through 2002). Even so, state
and local governments face many challenges under welfare devolution.
What Are the Challenges of Devolution?
This section reviews the welfare reform literature and focuses on
how current or former welfare users have faired under the 1996 federal
welfare legislation.
Welfare caseloads declined, but the poverty rate remained high.
Decentralization of central authority, accompanied by reductions in
federal funding, resulted in a decline in welfare caseloads without much
improvement in the economic conditions of poor women with children.
Under devolution, welfare caseloads have declined in every state in the
nation (DHHS, 1998) and, although less rapidly, on many Indian
reservations (Pandey et al., 2002; 1999b). Although states are
encouraged by the nationwide drop in caseloads of more than 40%, whether
due to employment or sanctions, most do not have enough information
about what happens to these welfare leavers (Tweedie, Reichert, and
O'Connor, 1999). Moreover, the decline in welfare caseloads has not
resulted in a decline in poverty.
Critics of welfare reform under block granting argue that
behavioral-based welfare, or social engineering via TANF, is not
effectively bringing poor families and individuals out of poverty
(Abramovitz, 2000; Cancian and Gordon, 1996; Ethridge and Percy, 1993;
Moore, 1997; Polit, London, and Martinez, 2000). Welfare reform efforts
have coincided with the U.S. economic boom, and welfare participants
seem to have benefited from the good economy. As long as the country
experiences low levels of unemployment and a strong economy, the market
will support a successful welfare-to-work program. A summary of studies
in nine states shows that between 50 and 70% (Mississippi is an
exception with only 35%) of former welfare recipients are currently
employed or have work earnings (Tweedie et al., 1999). However, most
families who leave welfare are still dependent upon some form of public
assistance (e.g., Food Stamps, Medicaid, or subsidized childcare), and
somewhere between one-fifth and one-third of families who leave w elfare
return within a few months (Ibid.). Critics are concerned about welfare
recipients in low-wage jobs and about the potential displacement of
current workers if the economy weakens (Cancian and Gordon, 1996).
Evidence from other studies suggests that even women who have found
jobs are worse off. A study from Oregon indicates that while welfare
caseloads declined, the poverty rate in that state increased
(ECONorthwest, 1998), indicating that available jobs are not paying
enough to lift these women out of poverty. Similarly, in Wisconsin,
despite rapid growth in the economy and a tremendous decline in the
welfare rolls, the number of poor declined marginally, and the number of
extremely poor (below 50% of the poverty level) increased sharply from
1989 to 1997 (Moore and Selkowe, 1999). Another study indicates that in
1996, over 2.7 million children (19% of all poor children) came from
families whose heads of household worked full time year round, but
earned incomes below the official poverty threshold (Wertheimer, 1999).
This indicates that forcing parents directly into work may get their
children off welfare, but it does not guarantee that they will escape
poverty (Ibid.). While the U.S. economy is booming, increa sing numbers
of poor families, many of whom are employed, are turning to food
pantries, soup kitchens, and other emergency food services to survive
hunger (America Press, 1998; Revkin, 1999a; 1999b; U.S. Conference of
Mayors, 1999).
Wages at the lower rungs of the economic ladder will be kept down
due to the massive supply of low-wage workers. Studies in nine states
that have tracked former welfare recipients (NCSL, 1998) indicate that
most have jobs that pay between $5.50 and $7.00 an hour, higher than the
minimum wage, but not enough to lift a family out of poverty. Although
state tracking studies provide little evidence to indicate an increase
in homelessness, child neglect, or child abuse (Tweedie et al., 1999),
working mothers report more material hardship than do welfare mothers.
According to Jencks (1997), the reason for this hardship is that single
mothers' expenses (in the forms of childcare, transportation,
healthcare, and clothing) rise sharply when they work. In Wisconsin,
although welfare leavers report substantially higher earnings and Earned
Income Tax Credits (EITC) post-welfare, their net incomes are actually
lower in the year following exit due to the decline in benefits such as
TANF and Food Stamps (Cancian et al., 20 00). Only 26% of the 1997
welfare leavers in this study had total incomes above the poverty level
in 1998.
Many advocates argue that for low-wage work to be a viable option
for women with children, a government support system with a wide range
of subsidies is needed (Savner, 1996). States and local governments will
have to focus on education and job training (Pandey et al., 2000), the
creation of better-paying jobs, childcare, transportation, and
healthcare (Moore, 1997; Pandey et al., 2002; 1999b). These resources
are particularly important for women leaving welfare under the TANF
program. In a study comparing welfare leavers under early Wisconsin
reforms and welfare leavers under TANF, Cancian et al. (2000) found
higher rates of exit under TANF, as this more stringent program pushes
mothers with fewer skills into the low-wage labor market. For these
women, consistent work is uncommon, as indicated by the median of three
employers for 1995 welfare leavers.
Decentralization and inequality. Although devolution offers
governments an opportunity to be more responsive (Conlan, 1998), when
accompanied by reductions in federal funding, it diminishes the ability
of local governments to respond effectively to local needs (Gold, 1996;
Donahue, 1997b; Pandey et al., 1999a, 1999b). The devolution of welfare
administration provides greater flexibility for states and local
governments to design and manage creative support programs for the poor.
It also increases the risk of failing to adequately support poor
families and children, especially during an economic downturn. Moreover,
rural areas of the United States have not experienced the economic
growth enjoyed by the rest of the country, making this population
especially vulnerable to funding cuts (Pandey et al., 2002; 1999b). To
respond effectively to poor women with children in rural areas, economic
growth and support programs must be evenly distributed across the United
States (World Bank, 1999).
With the federal contribution in the form of a fixed block grant,
states are responsible for the remaining fiscal burden, particularly as
the real value of the block grants declines over time (Corbett, 1997).
Federal requirements for monitoring and reporting are also greatly
reduced in this approach, thus increasing the potential for radically
different benefit levels within and across states. As a result,
devolution in the 1990s may have increased inequality, as levels of
support to poor families may vary within and between states (Donahue,
1997b; Conlan, 1998; Weir, 1997).
There has also been a resurgence of questions about who is or is
not deserving of help. Welfare benefits, no longer an entitlement, will
be available only to those persons deemed to be deserving by local
authorities. Because over 95% of adult welfare recipients are women,
women experience these reforms disproportionately (Mink, 1998a). As
Piven (1998: 68) notes, the logic of restrictive new welfare policies is
"simply to eliminate the possibility of a welfare-to-work tradeoff
for many women, and to worsen the terms of the welfare option for many
others." Limits on time and personal behavior will force women to
take whatever work is available, regardless of their ability to support
a family.
Local variations in programs have created a nightmarish complexity
of services and eligibility criteria that may vary from county to
county. The Office of the Inspector General of HHS reports that
fragmentation or subcontracting of the TANF program has at times
resulted in confusion for TANE recipients about whom to call regarding
sanctions (GAO, 2000). TANF recipients have had to explain their
circumstances multiple times to different people, and even then
sometimes received conflicting information. Further, the mandate is so
broadly written that the benefit may vary depending upon how a case is
evaluated.
Documenting regulatory and income differences and their effect on
the poor is critical to understanding the strengths and weaknesses of a
decentralized welfare system. In the U.S., not all states received
federal dollars for evaluation, and federal funding for performance
evaluation is even scarcer at the tribal level (Pandey et al., 1999a;
1999b). Studies that monitor the performance of antipoverty programs at
the local level are imperative as these programs are decentralized.
Since the performance of social programs for the poor depends upon the
objectives and restrictions of local governments, outcomes for the poor
will be very diverse. The federal government must have a means of
evaluation that takes into account the diversity and outcomes of social
programs administered locally. Lack of such a mechanism could result in
increased inequalities within and between states and local governmental
units.
Local governments' capacity to manage welfare devolution. Not
all local governments are positioned to take on these responsibilities.
As shown above, successful implementation of welfare programs requires
extraordinary staff, as well as monetary and community resources that
many local governments lack. Tribal governments are a case in point.
Although states are mandated to assume the responsibility of
implementing 1996 welfare legislation, tribes have an option to do so.
An examination of the recent experiences of several tribes within
Arizona reveals that not all tribes are technically and administratively
equipped to undertake a task of this magnitude (Pandey et al., 1999a;
1999b). Moreover, as the federal trust relationship is devolved, tribes
must count on the discretion of states to share limited resources
proportionately with tribes. As of January 2000, only 21 Indian Tribal
Organizations in the country were administering their own tribal TANF
programs.
Isolation of local governments. A decentralized welfare system has
the potential to isolate local governments. Reduced federal requirements
for monitoring and reporting increase the potential for radically
different benefit levels within and across states (Donahue, 1997b;
Conlan, 1998; Weir, 1997). "Voicelessness and powerlessness are
intimately linked to material poverty; participation in local and
national decision-making not only helps outcomes for the poor directly,
but it also helps to improve the quality of development policies"
(The World Bank, 1999:46). Both horizontal and vertical flows of
information may be limited, thus decreasing knowledge of events outside
local service areas and further limiting local governments. For example,
American Indian tribes were not actively involved in the welfare debate
and do not have experience comparable to that of state governments in
the administration of welfare programs. Nor do tribes have all the
resources necessary to assume tribal welfare programs without t he
assistance of states (McCarthy, 1999; Pandey and Collier-Tenison, 1999).
Again, state and tribal governments must forge new relationships if
tribes are to have the opportunity to administer their own welfare
programs.
Erosion of individual dignity. Devolution has increased
privatization of welfare services, but it has not sufficiently increased
competition among the qualified bidders (GAO, 1999). Anecdotal evidence suggests that devolution without much competition could strip away the
basic rights and dignity of the poor. According to Bernstein (1999),
participants in welfare-to-work programs through the city are not
protected from sexual discrimination and sexual harassment in the
workplace because these women are not considered employees. Furthermore,
current or former welfare recipients from rural Missouri described overt
sexual harassment and their fear of losing benefits if they were to
complain (Pandey and Collier-Tenison, 1999). Some of these focus group
respondents had left a job or refused to take a job when their employers
made sexual advances toward them. When discussing sexual harassment, one
woman stated, "it feels like you can't get a job unless you
give something."
The restrictive policies passed by many states will push or
humiliate women currently on welfare to find work (Piven, 1998). Rules
of paternity establishment compel welfare recipients to "disclose
private matters in exchange for cash and medical assistance -- to answer
questions like: Whom did you sleep with? How often? When? Where?"
(Mink, 1998a: 151-152). Moreover, studies in nine states report that
less-educated women may have trouble understanding complex program
requirements and the consequences of noncompliance (GAO, 2000). These
families are more likely to be sanctioned and a few indicate that they
had to place their children in the care of others or that they had
become homeless.
Because tribal governments are not subject to federal requirements
for due process hearings, American Indian welfare populations may also
have difficulty advocating, or even fully knowing, their rights
(McCarthy, 1999). Although tribal sovereignty may allow a greater focus
on the unique needs of poor American Indians, it may also create a new
roadblock to accessing assistance or justice. Reports of unfair
sanctions, welfare application systems that deter needy people from
applying for benefits, and recipients whose medical benefits had been
cut illegally indicate that welfare recipients are not receiving equal
protection under the law (Houppert, 1999; Welfare News, 1999; Kaplan,
1999).
Conclusion
Welfare reform in the 1990s resulted from a need for budget
restraints and a push for flexibility in program development and
implementation by the states (Conlan, 1998; Corbett, 1997;
Videka-Sherman and Viggiant, 1996). Yet, the economic conditions of, and
opportunities for, women living at the margins of a society do not
necessarily improve with decentralization of welfare programs from
federal to state and local governments. Even with a booming economy and
dramatically lowered welfare caseloads across the country, including
many Native American communities, the poverty conditions of many women
with children have remained the same or have improved only marginally.
Their conditions are likely to worsen as the economy slows because they
are already at the margin and are least prepared to deal with economic
downturns. We cannot, however, ignore the striking early success of some
state programs. Many women do prefer work (in a job paying a living
wage) to welfare. Former welfare recipients report increased self
-esteem and improved relationships when they successfully move from
welfare to work (Sing, Kauff, and Fraker, 1999). Thus, longer-term
evaluations are needed before declaring the 1996 welfare reform either a
failure or a success.
In the last few years, welfare evaluation studies have primarily
indicated a need for the expansion of support services (e.g., childcare,
healthcare, and transportation) that make it possible for welfare
recipients to work. Although Congress under the Clinton administration
showed a willingness to increase funding in these areas, it is uncertain
how the Bush administration will influence welfare policy. It is
imperative to build in these protective services now, regardless of
whether the welfare system is centralized or devolved. Finally, still
missing from the welfare reform debate is the importance of institution
building and information sharing, the need to reduce inequality, and the
imperative of preserving the rights and dignity of the poor and
marginalized women and children. More research must be devoted to these
areas.
SHANTA PANDEY, Ph.D., is Associate Professor in the George Warren
Brown School of Social Work, Washington University, Box 1196, One
Brookings Drive, St. Louis, MO 63130; e-mail: Pandeys@gwbmail.wustl.edu.
SHANNON COLLIER-TENISON, M.S.W., is a Doctoral Student and Research
Associate at the George Warren Brown School of Social Work. This
research is supported by grants from the U.S. Department of Health and
Human Services and the U.S. Department of Agriculture, Washington, D.C.
The opinions expressed are solely those of the authors.
REFERENCES
Abramovitz, M.
2000 Under Attack, Fighting Back: Women and Welfare in the United
States. New York: Monthly Review Press.
1994 "Challenging the Myths of Welfare Reform from a
Woman's Perspective." Social Justice 21,1:17-21.
America Press
1998 "Hunger on the Rise. "America Press Inc.
178.3(January 31):3(1).
Bailey, D. and K.M. Koney
1996"InterorganizationalCommunity-Based-Collaboratives: A
Strategic Response to Shape the Social Work Agenda." Social Work
41,6:602-611.
Bernstein, N.
1999 "Federal Agency Accuses City of Illegally Ignoring
Harassment." The New York Time s Online
(October1).At:http://search.nytimes.com/search/dailybinlfastweb?getdo
c+site+site+22986+0+wAAA+federal%7Eagency%7 Eaccuses%7Ecity.
Boehnen, E. and T. Corbelt
1996a "Welfare Waivers: Some Salient Trends." Focus:
Newsletter for the University of Wisconsin-Madison IRP 18,1: 34-37.
l996b "Work-Not-Welfare: Time Limits in Fond du Lac County,
Wisconsin." Focus: Newsletter for the University of
Wisconsin-Madison IRP 18,1: 77-81.
Borut, D.
1996 "Aspirations and Accountability: Local Government in the
Era of Devolution." National Civic Review 85: 23-27.
Brown, B. and T. Corbett
1997 Social Indicators and Public Policy in the Age of Devolution.
Special Report No. 71. University of Wisconsin-Madison, Institute for
Research on Poverty and School of Social Work.
Brown, CJ.
1940 Public Relief 1929-1939. New York: Henry Holt and Company.
Buckley, Jr., W.F.
1996 "Big Day for Federalism." National Review 48
(October 28): 82.
Bush, A.
1996 Replacing Welfare in Wisconsin. Welfare Policy Center: Hudson
Institute.
Available: www.file:///A/replcwel.htm.
Cancian, M. and L. Gordon
1996 "Making Mothers 'Work.'" Dissent 43:
73-75.
Cancian, M., R. Haveman, D.R. Meyer, and B. Wolfe
2000 Before and After TANE: The Economic Well-Being of Women
Leaving Welfare. Institute for Research on Poverty, Special Report No.
77. Available: http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/irp/.
Caraley, D.
1998 "Separating Fiction from Reality: A Case Against
Dismantling the Federal Safety Net." Available at
http://www.epn.org/sage/rscarale.html.
1996 "Dismantling the Federal Safety Net: Fictions Versus
Realities." Political Science Quarterly 111,2: 225-25 8.
Casse, D.
1997 "Why Welfare Reform Is Working." Commentary 104,3:
36-42.
Chemick, H. and A. Reschovsky
1996 "State Responses to Block Grants: Will the Social Safety
Net Survive?" Focus: Newsletter for the University of
Wisconsin-Madison IRP 18,1: 34-37.
Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives
1996 Green Book. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Conlan, T.
1998 From New Federalism to Devolution: Twenty-five Years of
Intergovernmental Reform. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institute Press.
Corbett, T.
1997 Informing the Welfare Debate: Perspectives on the
Transformation of Social Policy. Institute for Research on Poverty.
Special Report No. 70. Available: http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/irp/.
1996 "Understanding Wisconsin Works (W-2)." Focus:
Newsletter for the University of Wisconsin-Madison IRP 18,1: 53-54.
Department of Health and Human Services (DHHS)
1998 Total AFDC/TANF Families and Recipients in the United States,
1993-1998. Available: http://www.acf.dhhs.gov/news/caseload.htm.
Department of Workforce Development (DWD)
1996 Introducing the End of Welfare. Report No. 2116. State of
Wisconsin: Department of Workforce Development. Available:
www.dwd.state.wi.us/notespub/aboutDWD/21 16_126.htm.
Donahue, J.D.
1997a "The Devil in Devolution." The American Prospect
42: 47.
1997b Disunited States. New York: Basic Books.
ECONorthwest
1998 Comparing Recent Declines in Oregon's cash Assistance
caseload with Trends in the Poverty Population. Silverton, Oregon: The
Oregon Center for Public Policy. Available:
http://www,ocpp.org/1998/rpt98O8caseloadpov.pdf/.
Economist, The
1998 "More Neighbourly Government. (Devolution of Political
Power in the United States.)" The Economist 345,8049 (January 3).
Philadelphia: The Economist Newspaper Ltd.: 25-26. Available:
http://web3.searchbank.com/infotra...on/
616/475/20128305w3/13!xm_2andbk.
1995 "Talking 'Bout a Devolution." (Turning Welfare
over to the States Using Block Grants.) The Economist 334 (February 4):
23-24.
Editor's Report
1992 "The New Welfare Debate: What the States Are Hoping to
Accomplish." The American Enterprise (March/April): 16-18.
Engler, J. and S. Abraham
1995 "No Devil in Devolution: Governor Engler and Senator
Abraham Take Aim at Robert Rector's Views on Block Grants."
National Review 47,16: 38-39.
Ethridge, M. and S. Percy
1993 "A New Kind of Public Policy Encounters Disappointing
Results: Implementing Learnfare in Wisconsin." Public
Administration Review 53,4: 340-347.
Gallagher, L.J., M. Gallagher, K. Perese, S. Schreiber, and K.
Watson
1998 One Year After Federal Welfare Reform: A Description of State
Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) Decisions as of October
1997. Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute.
Ganzglass, E.
1996 Findings from the Manpower Demonstration Research corporation:
Study of Time-Limited Welfare in Three States. NGA Issue Brief.
Available: www.nga.orgfPubs/JssueBriefs/1996/960524ManpowerDemo.asp.
General Accounting Office (GAO)
2000 Welfare Reform: State Sanction Policies and Number of Families
Affected. (GAO Publication No. HEHS-00--44, March.) Washington, D.C.:
U.S. Government Printing Office.
1999 Social Service Privatization: Ethics and Accountability
challenges in State Contracting. (GAO Publication No. HEHS-99-41.)
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
1998 Welfare Reform: States Are Restructuring Programs to Reduce
Welfare Dependencies. (GAO Publication No. HEHS-98-109, June.)
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
1994a Families on Welfare: Sharp Rise in Never-Married Women
Reflects Social Trend. (GAO Publication No. HEHS-94-92, May.)
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Printing Office.
1994b Families on Welfare: Teenage Mothers Least Likely to Become
Self-Sufficient. (GAO Publication No. HBHS-94-l15, May.) Washington,
D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Gold, S.D.
1996 "The Potential Impacts of Devolution on State Government
Programs and Finances." Available:
http://www.urban.org/testimon/goldtest.htm.
Goldberg, L.
1996 "Come the Devolution." The American Prospect
24:66-71.
Gordon, L.
1994 "What Future for Social Policy? Welfare Reform: A History
Lesson." Dissent 41,3: 323-328.
Governors' Bulletin
1997 "Welfare Reform: Nation's Governors Mark Law's
First Anniversary." Governors' Bulletin: Online WEB Edition
31,17. Available: www.nga.org/ Welfare/WelfareDocs/bul-970818.htm.
Hagen, J,L.
1995 JOBS Program. Encyclopedia of Social Work. 19th Edition.
Washington, D.C.: NASW Press: 1546-1552.
Houppert, K.
1999 "You're Not Entitled! Welfare 'Reform' Is
Leading to Government Lawlessness." The Nation (October 25).
Available: http:/www.thenation.com/issue/ 991025/1025houppert.shtml.
Jencks, C.
1997 "The Hidden Paradox of Welfare Reform." The American
Prospect 32 (May- June): 30-40.
Jost, K.
1996 "The States and Federalism." The CQ Researcher 6,34:
793-816.
Kaplan, J.
1999 "The Use of Sanctions Under TANF." Welfare
Information Network (April). Available:
http//www.welfareinfo.org/sancsionissue_notes.htm.
Katz, J.
1995 "Governors Group Sidelined in Welfare Debate."
Congressional Quarterly Weekly Report 53,20 (May 20): 1423 (3).
Kaus, M.
1992 The End of Equality. New York: Basic Books.
Kingsley, G.
1996 "Perspectives on Devolution." Journal of the
American Planning Association 62: 419-426.
Kuttner, R.
1995 "You Say You Want a Devolution?" The Washington Post
(September 24). Available: http://epn.org/kuttnerl/ bk950924.html.
Long, S.K. and D.A. Wissoker
1995 "Welfare Reform at Three Years: The Case of Washington
State's Family Independence Program." The Journal of Human
Resources 30,4: 766-790.
Lurie, I.
1997 "Temporary Assistance for Needy Families: A Green Light
for the States." Publius 27,2: 73-87.
1996 "A Lesson from the JOBS Program: Reforming Welfare Must
Be Both Dazzling and Dull." Journal of Policy Analysis and
Management 15,4: 572-586.
McCarthy, RJ.
1999 "Tribal Welfare Reform: The Miner's Canary."
Clearinghouse Review (March-April): 554-566.
Mead, L.M.
1997 "Optimizing JOBS: Evaluation Versus Administration."
Public Administration Review 57,2: 113-123.
1992 The New Politics of Poverty: The Nonworking Poor of America.
New York: Basic Books.
1986 Beyond Entitlement: The Social Obligations of Citizenship. New
York: Free Press.
Mink, G.
1998a "Feminists, Welfare Reform, and Welfare Justice."
Social Justice 25,1: 146-157.
1998b "The Lady and the Tramp (U): Feminist Welfare Politics,
Poor Single Mothers, and the Challenge of Welfare Justice."
Feminist Studies 24,1: 55-64.
Moore, G.
1997 "Wisconsin Welfare Plan Lacks Compassion, Hope."
Forum for Applied Research and Public Policy 12: 27-34.
Moore, T.S. and V. Selkowe
1999 The Growing Crisis Among Wisconsin's Poorest Families: A
Comparison of Welfare Caseload Declines and Treads in the State's
Poverty Population -- 1986-1997. A report by The Institute for
Wisconsin's Future, Wisconsin. Available:
http://www.execpc.com/[sim]iwf/reports/FoodStampRep.pdf/.
Murray, C.
1984 Losing Ground: American Social Policy, 1950-1980. New York:
Basic Books, Inc.
Nathan, R.P.
1997 "The Newest New Federalism for Welfare: Where Are We Now
and Where Are We Headed?" Rockefeller Report. Available:
http://www.rockinst.org/rockrep3.htm.
Nathan, R.A. and J.R. Lago
1990 "Intergovernmental Fiscal Roles and Relations."
Annals of the American Association of Political and Social Scientists
509 (May): 36-47.
National Conference of State Legislation (NCSL)
1998 "Requiring Welfare Recipients to Work." Available:
http://www.ncsl.org/statefed/welfare/wklegbrf.htm.
National Journal, The
1995 "A Spotty Track Record." National Journal 27,23
(June 10): 1382.
Office and Commission on Navajo Government Development, The
1998 Local Governance Act: Strategic Implementation Analysis.
Window Rock, Arizona: The Navajo Nation.
Orthner, D.K. and R.S. Kirk
1995 "Welfare Employment Programs: Evaluation."
Encyclopedia of Social Work, 19th Edition. Washington, D.C.: NASW Press:
2499-2507.
Pandey, S., E.F. Brown, L. Scheuler-Whitaker, and S.
Collier-Tenison
2002 "Welfare Reform on American Indian Reservations: Initial
Experience of Service Providers and Recipients on Reservations in
Arizona." Journal of Social Policy (forthcoming, January)
Pandey, S., M. Zhan, S. Neely-Bames, and N. Menon
2000 "The Higher Education Option for Poor Women with
Children." Journal of Sociology and Social Welfare 27,4: 109-170.
Pandey, S., E.F. Brown, L. Scheuler-Whitaker, B. Gundersen, and K.
Eyrich
1999a "Promise of Welfare Reform: Development Through
Devolution on Indian Reservations." Journal of Poverty 3,4: 37-61.
Pandey, S., E.F. Brown, L. Scheuler-Whitaker, B. Gundersen, K.
Eyrich, and L. Villarreal
1999b Implementation of the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families
(TANF) on American Indian Reservations: Early Evidence from Arizona.
Working Paper, St. Louis, MO: Kathryn M. Buder Center for American
Indian Studies, George Warren Brown School of Social Work, Washington
University.
Pandey, S. and S. Collier-Tenison
1999 "Poverty and the Public Agenda: The Devolution of Welfare
Administration Authority from Federal to State and Local
Governments." Paper presented at the Role of the State in Poverty
Alleviation III Workshop, sponsored by International Social Science
Council/Comparative Research Programme on Poverty (CROP) and
UNESCO/MOST, November 7-10, Amman, Jordan.
Peterson, E.P.
1995 State Response to Welfare Reform: A Race to the Bottom?
Welfare Reform Brief No. 8 (May). Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute.
Peterson, G.
1995 A Block Grant Approach to Welfare Reform. Welfare Reform Brief
No.1, (April). Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute.
Piven, F.F.
1998 "Welfare and Work." Social Justice 25,1: 67-81.
Piven, F.F. and R.A. Cloward
1993 Regulating the Poor: The Functions of Public Welfare. New
York: Vintage Books.
Polit, D.F., A.S. London, and J.M. Martinez
2000 Food Security and Hunger in Poor, Mother-Headed Families in
Four U.S. Cities. A Project on Devolution and Urban Change. Working
paper by Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation (MDRC). Available:
http://www.mdrc.org/Reports2000/UrbanChange/FoodSecurityHunger.ht/.
Powers, E.
1999 Block Granting Welfare: Fiscal Impact on the States.
Occasional Paper 23, Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute.
Public Welfare
1995 "Welfare by Waiver: Section 1115 Lets States Experiment
with AFDC Within Limits." Public Welfare 4-5.
Reischauer, R.D.
1989 "The Welfare Reform Legislation: Directions for the
Future." P.H. Cottingham and D.T. Ellwood (eds.), Welfare Policy
for the 1990s. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press: 10-40.
Revkin, A.
1999a "Welfare Policies Altering Face of Lines at Charities
Offering Food." The New York Times (February 26). Available:
http://www.nytimes.com/library/national/regional/022699food.html/.
1999b "As Demand for Food Donations Grows, Supplies Steadily
Dwindle." The New York Times (February 27). Available:
http://www.nytimes.com/library/national/regional/022799food.html/.
Rivlin, A.
1991 "Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government:
Strengthening the Economy by Rethinking the Role of Federal and State
Governments." Journal of Economic Perspectives 5: 3-14.
Savner, S.
1996 "Creating a Work-Based Welfare System Under TANF."
Washington, D.C.: Center for Law and Social Policy. Available:
http://epn.org/clasp/welf2.html/.
Shapiro, J.
1987 "Why States Can Do What Uncle Can't." U.S. News
and World Report 103,26: 35-37.
Sing, M., J. Kauff, and T. Fraker
1999 "Work and Welfare: Iowa Families Tell Their
Stories." Mathematica Policy Research, Inc. Available:
http://www.mathematica-mpr.com/iowafamilies.pdf.
Skocpol, T.
1998 Protecting Soldiers and Mothers: The Political Origins of
Social Policy in the United States. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of
Harvard University Press.
1995 Social Policy in the United States: Future Possibilities in
Historical Perspective, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Steuerle, C.E. and G. Mermin
1997 "Devolution as Seen from the Budget." New
Federalism: Issues and Options for States, Series A, No. A-2.
Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute: 1-5.
Szanton. P.L.
1991 "The Remarkable 'Quango': Knowledge, Politics,
and Welfare Reform." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management
10,4: 590-602.
Tweedie, J., D. Reichert, and M. O'Connor
1999 "Tracking Recipients After They Leave Welfare."
National Conference of State Legislation (NCSL). Available:
http://ncsl.org/statefed/welfare/leavers.htm.
U.S. Conference of Mayors
1999 A Status Report on Hunger and Homelessness in America's
Cities. Available: http://www.usmayors.org/uscm/homeless/hunger99.pdf.
U.S. Congress
1997 June. Available:
ftp://ftp.loc.gov/pub/thomas/c104/h3734.enr.txt. HSOVER
1996 Personal Responsibility and Wark Opportunity Reconciliation
Act of 1996, Public Law 104-193.
Videka-Sherman, L. and P. Viggiani
1996 "The Impact of Federal Policy Changes on Children:
Research Needs for the Future." Social Work 41,6: 594-601.
Vitale, B.
1995 "Why Welfare Fares Well in Wisconsin." Insight on
the News 11,31:16.
Watson, K. and S. Gold
1997 "The Other Side of Devolution: Shifting Relationships
Between State and Local Governments." The Urban Institute Press
(September). Available: http://newfederalism.urban.org/html/other.htm.
Weaver, R.K.
1996 "Deficits and Devolution in the 104th Congress."
Publius: The Journal of Federalism 26: 45-85.
Webster's Ninth New Collegiate Dictionary
1988 Springfield. MA: Merriam Webster.
Weir, M.
1997 "Is Anybody Listening'? The Uncertain Future of
Welfare Reform in the Cities." The Brookings Review 15,1: 30-33.
Welfare News
1999 "New York City Admits Monitoring Insufficient to
Establish Proper Processing of Applications for Food Stamps, Medicaid,
and Cash Assistance: Court Bars Opening of More Job Centers."
Welfare News (September). Available:
http://www.welfarelaw.org/monitoring.htm.
Wertheimer, R.F.
1999 "Working Poor Families with Children." Washington,
D.C.: Child Trends. Available:
http://www.childtrends.org/workingpoorhtm/.
Wiseman, M.
1996 "State Strategies for Welfare Reform: The Wisconsin
Story." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 15,4: 515-546.
World Bank
1999 "Poverty Reduction and the World Bank: Progress in Fiscal
1998." Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
Wright, J.
1998 "The Price of Civilization: Comment on Peter
Eisinger's 'City Politics in an Era of Federal
Devolution.'" Urban Affairs Review 33,3: 326-329.