Japan-U.S. relations toward the 21st century.
Shank, Gregory
Japan and Asia will undoubtedly figure prominently in the future of
the United States economically, politically, and strategically. Yet
despite much fanfare about President Clinton's involvement in the
Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) talks, a coherent policy toward
this region appears to be a low priority in Washington. Relations with
Japan, the strongest U.S. ally in Asia after World War II and
America's most important partner in the world today, have reached
an all-time low. In the popular U.S. media, the representation of Japan
both in novels and on screen, promotes an adversarial relationship.
Central to the conflict is economic rivalry in the context of prolonged
world recession. The future of these two nations holds much more in
common than a mutual worship of urban consumer culture, baseball, and
business acumen. Below I will sketch the probable relationship between
Japan and the U.S. at the millennium by examining the scenarios of
futurists and well-known scholars in this area.
At the level of the world-economy, more than half the world's
populetion is located in Asia, making it the future site for low-wage
work forces and potential unsaturated markets. Over the last decade,
East Asia has become the most dynamic economic success story in the
world. The eight Asian economies designated by the World Bank as
"dynamic" (Japan, Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore, Taiwan, China,
Malaysia, and Thailand) have seen their collective gross domestic
product rise from $922 billion in 1971 to $3.43 trillion 20 years later
(in constant dollars). In 1971, the combined size of these eight
economies was just 33% of the U.S. economy; by 1991, that figure had
reached 76%. At this rate, the eight will equal the size of the U.S.
economy in 2002 (Mead, 1994).
According to the International Monetary Fund, China now has the
world' s third largest economy, trailing only the U.S. and Japan
(Nomani and Greenberger, 1993). China's economy has been growing at
a rate of more than 10% per year. Japan is China' s leading trading
partner, investment partner, source of foreign aid, and source of
technology (Johnson, 1993). Of consequence for regional stability, East
Asia is now the world's leading growth market for aerospace and
weapons technology, and each year China has posted double-digit
increases in its defense budget (Mead, 1993).
U.S. and Japanese economic expansion in the 21st century will require
China as a market, a production zone, and a force for political
stability. Because the present market zones of Japan and the U.S. are
reaching saturation, China is the next logical arena. Since wage costs
are becoming too high even in the Four Dragons and Southeast Asia, China
is needed as a production zone. China's wages will not reach those
levels for another 20 to 30 years (Wallerstein, 1993).
None of the above means that Asia is about to become the locus of the
next hegemony, but it is perhaps becoming the principal region of
capitalist accumulation (Amin, 1994: 346-347). According to Ikeda
(1994), in the coming century, the postwar expansion of the Japanese
enterprise networks will continue, and East Asia's weight in world
affairs is expected to increase. This expansion will take place in the
context of a U.S.-lead interstate system where the Japanese state
remains a junior and more or less dysfunctional partner. Although
Japanese dominance over a regional economic bloc would appear to be a
foregone conclusion, such a scenario underestimates Japan's
vulnerability despite its global commercial preeminence. A primary
impediment is Japan's wartime behavior, on the basis of which
neither China nor Korea would accept being subordinated to Japan.
Maintenance of an inter-Asian equilibrium therefore will depend on
forces external to the region, with the United States the only candidate
for this role.
Japan will therefore remain tied to the United States in the future;
in the process, the primacy of the U.S. on the world scene will be
prolonged. Japan will continue to rely on U.S. military strength,
especially with Korean reunification and China's growing military
might. Despite pressures from the nationalist Right, which seeks to make
Japan a military power coextensive with its economic prowess, the
expansion of Japanese military strength will be slow considering its
recent history and the consequences this holds for Asian attitudes and
Japanese internal politics.
Japanese citizens have struggled to maintain the "Peace
Constitution" adopted after the Pacific War. The U.S. has argued
that Japan must carry more of the economic burden for maintaining the
U.S.-dominated defense structure, and during the Gulf War, Japan
contributed (against much public opposition) to the financial costs of
carrying out the war. Thereafter, Japanese troops were integrated into
the United Nations peacekeeping force in Cambodia Asian neighbors,
fearful of a resurrection of Japanese military control in the region,
signaled alarm. Yet only 10% of Japanese males surveyed are willing to
defend their country. The legacy of Hiroshima and Nagasaki is a strong
countervailing force against militarism.
Rising powers have historically aligned themselves with a declining
hegemonic power, as was the case with the United States and the waning
British empire. Japan could similarly form a bloc with the United
States. The positions of all the dynamic Asian countries in the
world-system will be reinforced if they follow their current trajectory.
Japan's economic ascendance is not likely to cast her as the center
of controversy, however. Future conflict, according to Amin (1994), will
emerge between China and the United States as the major antagonists.
China's development threatens all global equilibria, and
consequently threatens the United States. Consequently, China may take
on the political representation of East Asia in the interstate system
and it is possible that the next round of world-systemic contradiction
will involve a regional dimension. How the United States reacts to these
Asian developments will dictate all future strategies of alliances.
The implications of Japan's (and Europe's) historical
relationship with the United States are discussed by Wallerstein (1993:
145-157). He argues that Japan and Europe have become relatively
stronger, while the United States is a lot less strong - economically,
politically, culturally - than it was in the 1960s. After World War II,
Japan and Europe were able to rapidly catch up with the U.S. as an
industrial power. After 1945, by entering late into an expanding
world-economy, Japan was able to take advantage of productivity leaps
afforded by newer machinery and relatively cheaper skilled labor. The
resulting disparity in productivity growth steadily grew through the
1970s and 1980s. Even today, Japan's work force receives the lowest
share of national income in the five leading industrial countries, and
its share is falling. Wages have risen only half as fast as productivity
in the past 15 years (Thurow, 1992: 126).
In addition, due to the Cold War, the U.S. invested in costly weapons
development, maintained an expensive worldwide military establishment,
and invested in strategic allies - politico-military costs that Germany
and Japan did not have to bear. Sheltered under the U.S. strategic
umbrella and enjoying a virtually demilitarized status after 1945, Japan
spent a mere one percent of its GNP on defense while U.S. totals ranged
from five to 10 percent and beyond. The Truman and Eisenhower
administrations provided hundreds of millions of dollars of aid to
Japan, granted it large military contracts during the Korean War, and
pressed the World Bank and other institutions to lend generously to
Japan (Silk and Kono, 1994:115). Japan's economy was pumped up by
its role as a staging/repair area and supply source for massive U.S.
procurements during the Korean War and later the Vietnam War.
As a corollary to rapidly stimulating economic recovery and
consistent with its practice in Western Europe after World War II, the
CIA intervened in Japan in the 1950s and 1960s by spending millions of
dollars to support the conservative Liberal Democratic Party (LDP) to
make the country a bulwark against communism and to undermine the
Japanese Left. The secret payments promoted structured corruption and
one-party conservative democracy in postwar Japan (Engelberg et al.,
1994).
The end of the Cold War brought about the disintegration of the LDP
and popular domestic outcries against the political systems of both
Japan and Italy, particularly over the issue of corruption. As Johnson
(1993) points out:
Throughout the Cold War standoff the United States supported the
ruling Italian and Japanese elites with alliances, funds, access to the
American market and, when needed, CIA assistance. The aim was to prevent
the Italian Communist Party or the Japan Socialist Party from coming to
power, even though both were considered legitimate - in Italy because of
partisan activity against the Germans during World War II, and in Japan
because of opposition to the Japanese-American Security Treaty. Had
either party come to power, it would have broken with the United States
and adopted policies of neutralism at best or alliance with the Soviet
Union or China at worst.
Therefore, neither Italy nor Japan developed a genuine two-party
system, like that in Germany, in part because of the bipolar strategic
implications of their doing so. In both countries the United States
supported regimes that were known to have connections with the
neofascist Right and the criminal underworld - the Mafia in Italy and
the yakuza in Japan - simply because they were anti-Communist. It should
come as no surprise, then, that Italy and Japan experienced severe
political crises as soon as the Cold War rationale for their ruling
establishments disappeared.
The existence of the Soviet Union provided the United States with a
raison d'etre for a word political role that Western Europe and
Japan still are unable or unwilling to shoulder. In Japan, the collapse
of Cold War imperatives, coupled with a period of prolonged economic
stagnation, has combined with generational and demographic pressures
caused in part by the Japanese public's long period of forced
underconsumption to push the political system into a crisis of
leadership and legitimacy (Ibid., 1993). Despite the current economic
and political malalse, Japan shows every sign of leading the economic
pack in the proximate future. Indeed, forecasters expect the Japanese
economy (now two-thirds the U.S. total at current exchange rates and
perhaps equaling it in size by the year 2000) to grow even faster than
that of the U.S., and probably faster than Europe's, for the rest
of the century (Kennedy, 1993: 142). During the next five years of world
depression (i.e., through 1998), however, the primary aim of the
Japanese and other governments will be to minimize the pain:
Japan's state budget has a more solid base than do those of its
competitors, and it will therefore have less difficulty in shouldering
domestic social costs. And during the following 25 years of the
world-economy's likely expansion - under the impetus of new,
relatively monopolized leading industries - the prime challenge to the
world's great economic rivals will be to foster conditions that
will allow them to become the locus of world capital accumulation. In
the 1980s, Japan did the most to get the edge in applied innovations in
the leading industries of the future (Wallerstein, 1993).
Within Asia, Japan has become the major supplier of intermediate
producer goods that the other Asian economies cannot yet manufacture
themselves. These goods are ultimately incorporated into finished
products that are exported to the U.S. market. As its huge trade surplus
reveals, Japan is the primary beneficiary of this trading system. Many
analysts have noted that this model of export-led growth succeeded so
long as the United States maintained its historic role as the main
market for East Asian manufactured goods. Yet the U.S. economy is no
longer growing fast enough to continue to absorb all of this output and
mounting deficits constrain its ability to afford them.
In the not too distant future, the dynamic Asian economies must find
a new engine of growth. In the 21st century, the rest of the word will
impose restrictions to prevent Japan from increasing exports and
capturing market share at its current pace. Japan will then be compelled
to shift from a producer-driven economy to a consumer-driven economy, a
boon to its consumers who at long last may begin to share in the
country' s enormous wealth (Thurow, 1992: 249-250, Johnson, 1993).
The formation of quasi trading blocks in Europe and North America will
hasten this development, for it will require Japanese companies to
operate as insiders, not outsiders, in those zones. Japan could also
begin to supply aid and assistance to its neighbors because help is
needed rather than because it is profitable (Johnson, 1993).
Until that time, the United States will continue to persuade the
Japanese to adopt measures that are not in their immediate economic
interest or else face trade sanctions. Retaliatory measures, however,
would harm the United States as much, if not more, than it would Japan
because the U.S. needs Japan's capital as much as Japan needs U.S.
markets. Japan also needs access to U.S. research and development
(R&D), which continues to hold a clear lead. If the U.S. government
were to cease to sustain public tensions with the Japanese in the
commercial arena, U.S. corporations would move on their own toward
arrangements with the Japanese. U.S. and Japanese enterprises would
continue to drift toward interlocking industrial partnerships that would
preserve and extend jobs in both countries (Wallerstein, 1993).
In Jamerica, futurists Alvin and Heidi Toffler (1994) explore the
obstacles to and advantages of a hypothetical merger of the United
States and Japan into a single superpower (along the lines of
Europe's monetary union and political integration). Though
improbable - due to racism in the U.S. and nationalist sentiment in
Japan and to the threat this merger would pose to the pan-Asian
equilibrium - the U.S. and Japanese economies and cultures have become
so tightly interconnected that such conjecture sheds light on possible
approaches to resolving currency and trade frictions. If one were to
combine the economic strength of Japan and the United States with the
military potential of the U.S, plus its enormous informational power,
the resulting alliance could dominate much of the earth for decades.
In the Toffler's view, however, the locus of global political
power will probably shift away from nation-states in the coming century.
The historical moment for Jamerica has passed. It was based on an
accumulation strategy favoring big countries, with large populations and
economies, that characterized the era of Second Wave industrialism, when
"smoke-stack industries" and "economies of scale"
enjoyed enormous advantages in the world economy. Those advantages are
diminishing with the rise of Third Wave, knowledge-based economies.
Under this more decentralized model, regions - some of them binational or even multinational - may become more important centers of economic
and cultural activity than nations or even super-nations.
We are currently in a period of transition. To this point, Japan has
focused on a set of 10 clear priorities for expanding economic power,
which the Tofflers summarize as "the Japanese model." This
model was so successful that other Asian countries tacitly adopted
virtually the same list (Toffler, 1994b).
1. Economic development is more important than any other form of
development.
2. Exports are more important than domestic goods.
3. The nation is more important than the corporation.
4. The company is more important than the person.
5. Big business is more important than small business.
6. The quality of products is more important than the quality of
life.
7. The producer is more important than the consumer.
8. Homogeneity is more important than heterogeneity.
9. Obedience is more important than creativity.
10. Men are more important than women.
Centralized strategic guidance in "industrial policy"
succeeded initially by promoting the investment of capital in
electronics and semiconductors. By the 1980s, Japan' s
manufacturing processes led the world. Japan now possesses close to
three-quarters of the world's robots and more automated workplaces
than anywhere else on earth (Kennedy, 1993: 157). Its major companies
concentrated on top-quality precision products made by educated and
well-paid workers using information-intensive technology. They created
the world's most "intelligent" consumer products by
embedding intelligence, in the form of microchips, into the goods they
exported. Yet the strategy's focus on manufacturing was also its
main limitation.
According to Toffler (1994d), advanced Third Wave economies cannot
base themselves primarily on hardware and goods manufacture, but must
also incorporate software and services. The world is now moving from a
hardware-based to a highly competitive software-based global economy.
Such software creates high-value-added goods, and Japan lags behind the
U.S. in this leading industry. Japan has also fallen behind in laying
cable of any kind, in satellite communications, and in developing a
Third Wave decentralized and interactive multimedia infrastructure at a
time when the United States is racing toward a digital web connecting
every home that will revolutionize the economy itself.
Thus, the very priorities that helped Japan and Asia become
successful Second Wave economies, including the single-minded drive for
economic growth, have become questionable, even counterproductive, as
these economies shift to a Third Wave structure. As Toffler (1994b)
explains:
To create a strong economy while allowing the environmental and
social order to degenerate, as in the United States, or to stagnate, as
in Japan, calls into question the very goal that motivated generations
of workers and salarymen to work endless hours. Today in Japan, as in
the United States, one finds industrial plants moving out to cheap labor
centers overseas, leaving behind an economy ever more dependent on
brains, rather than brawn. Manufacturing employment flattens out or
recedes as services and information jobs multiply, and a different kind
of worker appears with different needs and wants.
Japan has a society that is the envy of Europe and the United States
- a society whose streets are safe, whose levels of violence are low, a
society that is clean and seemingly well ordered. Yet, measured in terms
of daily comfort, commuting time, physical environment, bureaucratic
frustration, invasions of privacy, prices paid for consumer goods, and
other measures of the "good life," daily life in Japan still
leaves much to be desired.
Peter Drucker (1994) has also observed that knowledge has become the
central, key resource that knows no geography. "Knowledge applied
to existing processes, services, and products is productivity; knowledge
applied to the new is innovation." The Japanese shot themselves
into the world economy by concentrating on productivity, while the U.S.
concentrated on innovation. Since it took the U.S. 50 years to move from
more efficiently copying British inventions to learning how to be
inventive in the 20th century (Thurow, 1992: 248-249), Japan will also
attain this ability in time. Each is now attempting to overcome their
respective weaknesses. This is the central dynamic in the restructuring
of industries around knowledge as well as the shifting of work offshore.
In the U.S., this trend aggravates racism since assembly-line work is no
longer available as a conduit to middle-class status. In Japan, it
exacerbates workplace discrimination based on gender.
The U.S. is already well along in suffering the effects of
"downsizing." Japan had hoped to be bailed out by labor
shortages caused by an aging population. Drucker also points out that
Japanese companies have become overstaffed in management because their
education system demands that if you finish high school, you can't
be a blue-collar worker, you must be a clerk; if you finish college, you
must be a professional or a manager. Since everyone in Japan now at
least finishes high school, there is an incredible surplus of clerks and
would-be managers.
Under the pressure of the protracted slump, a rising yen, and other
factors affecting competitiveness, Japanese firms have established
plants overseas, have begun to question the lifetime employment system
for core workers, and introduced painful domestic job losses in
Japan's industrial heartland. Called kudoka, or "hollowing
out," the concept is deja vu for U.S. and European workers who
watched segments of their manufacturing bases move overseas in the 1960s
and 1970s. Japan's low unemployment rate - now 2.9%, the highest
since June 1987 - appears to have prevented kudoka from becoming an
explosive political issue (Desmond, 1994). (A recent study by the
Sumitomo-Life Research Institute, Inc., found that the real Japanese
unemployment rate is closer to six percent rather than the official
figure, approaching that of the United States because of "in-house
unemployment" - employees called "window-sitters" who do
next to nothing, but remain on the payroll [Silk and Kono, 1994:119].)
Even though Japan could lose 1.26 million industrial jobs, or 9.1% of
the total, by the year 2000 if overseas-investment growth averages 20% a
year, the powerful bureaucracy, mainstream labor unions, and the
Ministry of International Trade and Industry have shown little concern
over kudoka (Desmond, 1994). It is widely believed that because of its
declining birth rate, Japan faces a serious long-term labor shortage. In
any event, it is estimated that strong growth in Japanese investment
abroad will reduce Japan's worldwide trade surplus by $22.7 billion
a year over the next seven years - thereby addressing a politically
sensitive issue. This loss of "manufacturing culture" is
already reflected in the rising number of talented youth heading into
merchant banking rather than engineering (Kennedy, 1993: 146).
As noted, Japan's demographics create favorable labor-market
conditions in terms of unemployment. Japanese life expectancy is the
highest in the world today and, partly as a reaction by Japanese women
against traditional expectations of a child-rearing role, the fertility
rate fell to 1.57 children per woman in 1989 - well below the average
2.1 children per woman needed to maintain the overall population. If
there is no reversal of these trends, by 2025 the ratio of
over-sixty-fives to Japan's total population will rise to one in
four, the highest among the leading industrial countries. With
increasingly fewer workers supporting every retired person, the required
increases in payroll taxes and social security contributions could
transform Japan from the most lightly taxed OECD country to one of the
most heavily taxed (Ibid: 154-155).
An obvious solution to restoring a balance between the size of the
Japanese work force and the numbers of elderly dependents would be to
allow other Asians clamoring for work to immigrate to Japan.
Participation in trading blocks implies some level of labor mobility,
including a willingness to digest guest workers. Because of its
reluctance to make its society easier for outsiders to join, however,
Japan is not likely to be able to create a common market to rival the
European Community (Thurow, 1992: 251). Tactless remarks by Japanese
politicians about the social weaknesses of America's multicultural,
multiracial population reveal that concerns about preserving
"Japan-ness" will outweigh utilitarian arguments in favor of
increased immigration (Kennedy, 1993: 155).
Most likely, increases in productivity and robotics will minimize the
effect of labor shortages and reduce the need for a guest-worker program
in Japan. Japan's larger companies have dealt with the domestic
labor shortage by going multinational. These firms have shown great
ability in managing foreign workers, eliciting greater productivity than
foreign managers can, but in the economics of the 21st century, firms,
will be required to integrate managers from different cultures and
nationalities into a homogenous team (Thurow, 1992: 248).
As a result of the internationalization of the Japanese economy, an
estimated 600,000 Japanese now reside overseas (excluding permanent
residents and immigrants). At the same time, the highest available
estimate of the number of foreign workers in Japan is 300,000 - less
than one-quarter of one percent of the total Japanese population (in
contrast to figures of between 7% and 13% in many European countries in
the mid- 1980s). There were virtually no migrant workers in Japan until
the mid-1980s because of the abundance of low-wage labor within Japan,
the two main sources being farmers and women (Lie, 1992: 36-37). Women
constituted a large pool from which low-wage and part-time workers could
he drawn according to the fluctuations of the economy. By the mid-
1980s, the rural exodus had created a serious labor shortage in the
countryside and most women had already become integral to the industrial
labor force. During the expanding economy of the 1980s, sheer economic
necessity forced many employers - smaller firms, merchants, and farmers
- to rely on foreign workers to do jobs avoided by the Japanese.
The "problem" of foreign workers centers on people from
underdeveloped Asian countries, over 80% of whom entered Japan through
the agency of Japanese recruiters and brokers, including the yakuza and
illicit enterprises, to do work described as 3K (kitsui, kitanai, and
kiken), which can be rendered in English as 3D: difficult, dirty, and
dangerous. The overwhelming majority of women worked in the sex
industry, while most men worked in construction and other physically
demanding but low-paying jobs (Ibid.: 38).
"Nativist" Japanese conservatives have argued for banning
foreign workers. The polemics ignore the plight of the resident minority
populations of Koreans and Chinese in Japan who were forcibly relocated
there during World War II to work in coal mines and weapons factories.
Thus, Japan's unresolved war legacy arises again in a reassertion
of the prewar ideology of Japanese racial superiority and an ongoing
anmesia about Japan's past colonialist and nationalist-militarist
ventures. The domestic hysteria over foreign workers plays upon the
presumed threat posed by "impure" foreigners, the
"other," who bring with them crime and other social ills. Not
surprisingly, many instances of deportation occur as a result of
citizens reporting non-Japanese-looking people to the local police
(Ibid.). The mean-spirited approach recently adopted in the U.S. to the
issue of immigration shows that the Japanese are far from unique with
respect to such unexamined attitudes.
In Preparing for the Twenty-First Century, Paul Kennedy (1993:
137-138) argues that Japan is the country best prepared for the
technologically driven global changes of the 21 st century and is least
likely to be hurt by gross and direct damage from global overpopulation,
mass migration, and environmental disasters. While increasing domestic
consumption and reducing trade surpluses to assuage domestic and
external critics, Japan is also engaged in one of the most extensive
industrial retoolings that the world has ever known. It has identified
new areas of very high value added (satellites, jet fighters,
supercomputers, etc.) and is moving into them as quickly as possible. At
the same time, the movement offshore of industries represents more an
expansion of the Japanese subcontracting network to East Asia and a
shedding of low-value-added product lines than a genuine "hollowing
out."
Japan's success in positioning itself in major growth markets
and in outper-forming the world's other successful exporters has
led some analysts to suggest that Japan (1) must be following a
long-term strategy formulated by businessmen and bureaucrats in Tokyo,
and (2) is pursuing an entirely different accumulation strategy from
that of the other successful Western powers. The implication of the
first point is often that if competitors are to successfully go head to
head with Japan, then some sort of "industrial policy" is
required, with massive state intervention on behalf of industry.
However, it could also be argued that Japan's long-term economic
expansion is driven by the intense competitiveness of its major
corporations in their struggle for global market shares. The implication
of the second, "revisionist," argument is that if Japanese
capitalism is of a truly different order, then its ascendance in the
world system will not necessarily be followed by the inevitable relative
economic decline suffered by Holland, Britain, and possibly the
present-day U.S. as their preeminence in manufacturing eroded. Thurow
(1993) and Fallows (1993a, 1993b) intelligently explore the differences
between Japanese and U.S. entrepreneurial and government practices.
As Silk and Kono (1994:116) note, one must be wary of a
"revisionist" U.S. trade policy based on the assumption that
Japan is inherently different and must remain so, for such an assumption
could exacerbate economic conflicts and reduce chances for economic
cooperation.
American "revisionists" have long argued that Japanese
capitalism is not only different from but essentially incompatible with
Western capitalism a view that key members of the Clinton
administration, including President Bill Clinton himself, appear to
share. Laura D' Andrea Tyson, chief economic adviser to the
president, contends that Japan's capitalism differs from
America's, so that sometimes quotas "are the only possible
solution."
Japan's reform process is equally rife with political
considerations. According to Johnson (1993), Japan's economic
planners had estimated that U.S. politicians would not begin to take
U.S. economic decline seriously until the 1996 presidential election.
Japanese strategists concerned with their country's post-Cold War
future hoped to make Japan's position in Asia unassailable before
shifting to a domestic, demand-driven economy. Putting a cynical spin on
the reform process, Johnson views the political turmoil in Tokyo less as
a harbinger of genuine change than a diversion stage-managed to lead
U.S. officials to postpone their demands for trade and other economic
reforms.
As Japan comes out of the recession, however, it will be easier for
it to satisfy international demands. Japanese analysts are skeptical,
however, about the prospects for real change - in contrast to a
reorganization of the LDP under a new name - and are concerned that
schisms in the opposition coalition and a weak political leadership will
leave the bureaucracy on its existing course. The structure of power in
Japan, with its detailed linkages between the governing bureaucracies,
politicians, corporate elite (the so-called Iron Triangle), and
organized crime, remains fundamentally unaltered. The first opposition
prime minister, Morihiro Hosokawa, to take office after the collapse of
the LDP soon fell from power due to the corruption inherent in Japanese
money politics. Only to the extent that Japanese citizens insist more on
immediate improvements in the quality of their lives rather than
deferring the good life for future generations to enjoy, then, will
popular pressure become a countervailing force to bureaucratic inertia.
REFERENCES
Amin, Samir 1994 "The Future of Global Polarization."
Review 17,3 (Summer): 337-347.
Desmod, Edward W. 1994 "Pacific Rim: Beyond the Trade
Game." Time Magazine (February).
Drucker, Peter 1994 "Post-Capitalist: A Conversation with Peter
Schwartz." Wired 1.3 (March).
Engelberg, Stephen, Tim Weiner, and James Sterngold 1994 "CIA
Funded Japan Conservative Party: Operation Helped LDP Stay in Power for
Three Decades." New York Times, reprinted in San Francisco Examiner (October 9): C-10.
Fallows, James 1993a "Looking at the Sun." The Atlantic
Monthly (November): 69-100.
1993b "How the World Works." The Atlantic Monthly
(December): 61-87.
Ikeda, Satoshi 1994 "Japanese Accumulation Structure and the
Postwar World-System." Social Justice 21:2 (Summer).
Johnson, Chalmers 1993 "Japan's Post-Cold War Destiny: The
Tremor." The New Republic (August).
Kennedy, Paul 1993 Preparing for the Twenty-First Century. New York:
Random House.
Lie, John 1992 "Foreign Workers in Japan." Monthly Review
(May).
Mead, Waiter 1994 "The New Economics: The Tigers and the
Bees." Worth Magazine (February).
1993 "The New Economics: Japan and the Domino Theory."
Worth Magazine (July).
Wallerstein, Immanuel 1993 "Foes as Friends?" Foreign
Policy 90 (Spring): 145-157.
Nomani, Asra and Robert Greenberger 1993 "China's Economy
Is Ranked as World's Third Largest." The Asian Wall Street
Journal (May 21-22): 2.
Silk, Leonard and Tom Kono 1994 "Sayonara, Japan Inc."
Foreign Policy 93 (Winter): 115-131.
Thurow, Lester 1992 Head to Head: The Coming Economic Battle among
Japan, Europe, and America. New York: William Morrow and Company.
Toffler, Alvin and Heidi 1994a "America and Japan as One
Nation." Part I. Adapted from Jamerica. Tokyo: Fuso Sha. New York
Times Special Features.
1994b "Are Asia's Priorities Obsolete?" Part II.
Adapted from Jamerica. Tokyo: Fuso Sha. New York Times Special Features.
1994c "Services and Software: How Japan's
Technonationalists Missed the Boat." Pan III. Adapted from
Jamerica. Tokyo: Fuso Sha. New York Times Special Features.
1994d "How Asian Tremors Could Threaten the Global
Economy." Pan IV. Adapted from Jamerica. Tokyo: Fuso Sha. New York
Times Special Features.
GREGORY SHANK is a member of the Editorial Board of Social Justice
(P.O. Box 40601, San Francisco, CA 94140).