For an alternate social policy: the production of public service.
Laurell, Asa Cristina
I. Introduction
The crisis and economic adjustment policies of the 1980s added a
dramatically high social cost to an accumulation of unresolved social
problems. Data from international organizations reveal that close to
half of all Mexicans now live in poverty, and of those, some 17 to 20
million are officially classified as living in extreme poverty, i.e.,
they are unable to afford even the minimum essential diet.(1)
Although the severe depression of wages and growing underemployment and unemployment (Gutierrez, 1989) explain a good deal of the
deterioration in the social conditions of working people, another
contributing factor is the reorientation of social policy and the 27%
decrease in social spending between 1981 and 1989 (Poder Ejecutivo
Federal, 1989a). The most relevant consequences of this situation are,
on the one hand, a decreasing satisfaction of health care and
educational needs, and, on the other hand, a marked deterioration of the
public and quasi-state institutions that supplies these services.
The magnitude of the social problems contrasts with the lack of
emphasis they are given in official proposals and measures taken to
resolve the crisis. This is clearly related to the government's
neoliberal approach, which emphasizes the fiscal crisis and the
excessive size of the state. Thus, the strategy outlined in the
1989-1994 National Development Plan (Poder Ejecutivo Federal, 1989b) --
which is essentially a continuation and deepening of the
neoliberal-neocorporatist project of the previous administration --
claims that social welfare will be achieved through economic growth
based on private investment; state action as a solution to social
problems is only emphasized in reference to aiding the most impoverished
groups, particularly through Pronasol (the Mexican government's
poverty program). However, a social policy with these characteristics
represents a political problem for the government, which finds it
necessary to present economic and social policies as though they were
conceptually separate. This is expressed in the ideological formulation
regarding how the state-as-property-owner is incompatible with the
social state.(2)
Nevertheless, a growing number of social and political
organizations are attempting to project alternate solutions to the
crisis by giving maximum priority to social democracy. That is, they
propose as the goal of their projects an economic recovery directed
toward guaranteeing the fulfillment of the population's social
rights. The existence of abroad current representing this perspective
highlights the need to promote debate about the alternatives available
to social policy as a state tool for addressing unresolved social
problems and guaranteeing social rights.
This article attempts to contribute to this process by analyzing a
specific area of social policy, specifically, the production of health
and education services. The first section assesses the principal changes
since 1983, recognizing the continuity of policies since that date and
the current problems in this area. Then the article delineates the
strategic axes of an alternate policy that (1) makes the strengthening
and the democratic transformation of the public institutions that
produce the services priorities, (2) favors the redistribution of social
wealth toward the working classes, and (3) paves the way for eventually
removing the obstacles to the integration of single systems of health
and education with universal access. This allows us to clearly present
the option implicit in the government's project and contrast it
with the option delineated here. Only in this way can we generate an
informed public debate, which is a necessary condition for democratic
participation in the resolution of social and political problems.
II. A Diagnosis
As a point of reference to characterize social policy, one can
distinguish, in broad terms, between two general models that are based
on the character and importance of the state's role in regulating,
producing, and financing activities designed to guarantee the welfare of
the population. The first model would be an assistance-oriented social
policy, in which social services are treated as commodities and state
intervention is reduced to a few gestures of social assistance directed
toward the indigent population. This social policy corresponds to the
liberal state and is driven by the market. The second model would be a
policy of social welfare based on recognizing that the population has a
series of social rights that are a public concern and that the state has
a duty to fulfill. This policy corresponds to the welfare state and is
driven by state action in which the market is clearly subordinate.
Crisis and Social Policy
It is interesting to review certain aspects of the relationships
among crisis, productive restructuring, economic policy, and social
policy, since the corresponding debate tends to be more ideological than
factual. There is general consensus that any solution to the crisis
necessarily entails a process of productive restructuring to permit
resolution of the problems of technological backwardness, productivity,
and competitiveness. However, contrary to the general argument,
neoliberal economic and social policies are not necessarily the means to
achieve restructuring. An example is Sweden, where, under a
social-democratic government and with a powerful trade-union movement,
productive restructuring was carried out while maintaining an advanced
policy of social welfare and preserving full employment and the previous
wage levels (Therborn and Roebroek, 1986).
In contrast, where neoliberal policies have dominated, as in
England and the U.S., social inequality has increased through a
regressive redistribution of social wealth, while both unemployment and
the size of the poor population have increased significantly
(Taylor-Gooby, 1989). These changes have produced what Mike Davis (1986)
has called a pattern of overconsumption-underconsumption. However,
despite these features and the fact that the discourse of the New Right
proclaims the end of the welfare state through a combination of cuts in
social spending, privatization of public services, and the targeting of
social spending solely on indigent groups, this agenda has not been
implemented completely in countries with consolidated welfare
institutions like England (Taylor-Gooby, 1989). Thus, during the onset
of Thatcherite neoliberal policy, from 1975 to 1981, social spending was
not reduced; in fact, it continued to grow, although at a slower rate
(an average of 2.5% annually) than during the previous period. Social
services were not privatized and a coherent policy of focussing social
spending never materialized (Ibid.).
This discrepancy between discourse and deeds can only be explained
as a function of real political processes. That is to say, to the extent
that governmental action has to be submitted to the electoral test in
countries with parliamentary regimes, the governing party cannot violate
basic societal values without risk of losing the election. Thus, for
example, while some privatization may be acceptable to a majority of the
electorate, this is not true of the elimination of social benefits that
in many cases have become universal social values (Therborn, 1985).
Accordingly, only in the U.S., where workers' interests are not
expressed clearly through a political party and where the poorest social
sectors suffer substantial political exclusion, were there significant
setbacks in social policy with a sustained process of privatization of
health services and education (Navarro, 1989).
This situation marks an important difference between the developed
countries and Mexico, since what is a discourse with limited practical
implications in the former has become reality in our country. Here the
neoliberal economic project has been instituted under conditions of
political weakness on the part of workers, a situation explained by the
corporatist regime of the state party and by the refusal of the
Institutional Revolutionary Party (PRI) to recognize the defeat of its
project in the 1988 electoral process. Thus, as a general tendency,
there has been a serious rollback in the fulfillment of social rights
and a switch toward an assistance-oriented policy in accord with
neoliberal postulates. Moreover, it should be emphasized that the
changes in social policy are taking place in the context of a selective
social-security system and restrictive benefits coverage.
Tendencies in the Production of Services
In the area of health services and education, the central goals of
neoliberal projects -- such as those being implemented in Latin America under the determined meddling of international agencies such as the
World Bank and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (Marquez and Engler, 1990) -- are budget cuts, concentration of public
spending on groups in extreme poverty, decentralization, and
privatization.(3) In Mexico, the first three are explicit policies or
easily observable. Although the intent to privatize has not been
declared publicly, privatization is nevertheless clearly en route, as we
shall see below.
Despite repeated declarations about the priority of education and
health, important budget cuts for these areas were made in the 1980s.
Consequently, by the end of the decade, government expenditures on
health and education were even 27% less than in 1981, after having been
cut in half in 1986 and 1987. In addition, the population grew by nearly
20% during the decade, resulting in a per capita decline of 38% in
public spending on health and education.
Likewise, in relation to total public expenditures, spending on
education decreased from 8% to 5%, while spending on health dropped from
4.7% to 2.7%. Contrast this decline with the high and increasing
percentage of public expenditures dedicated to servicing the debt (from
25.9% in 1980 to 60.9% in 1989). It is also worth noting these
tendencies in the context of United Nations recommendations that 8% of
the gross domestic product (GDP) be spent on education and 5% on health:
by the end of the decade Mexico was spending only 2.5% and 1.6%
respectively.
Given the budget restrictions, current expenditures were privileged
over investment. Thus, in the health sector overall, investment declined
by 71% between 1982 and 1983, and by 1986, it represented only 30% of
the 1982 figure. This tendency was even more marked in social security
institutions where investment declined by 75% in 1983 and remained at
the same level in 1986 (Ochoa, 1990). Likewise, in education,
investments in physical plant declined and efforts already underway to
consolidate basic services were suspended (PRD, 1990). This sustained
restriction of investment not only impeded expansion of services, but
also provoked a gradual deterioration.
The policy of focusing public spending on the most impoverished
groups is most clearly expressed in the founding of Pronasol, an
organization that has as its explicit goal the channeling of resources
to groups living in extreme poverty. However, dating from the last
administration, this policy has been carried out by setting
institutional priorities and changing the schemes for financing distinct
institutions. Thus, health and education institutions have been given
the explicit priority of covering the basic level, i.e., primary care in
health (SSA, 1984) and primary school in education (SEP, 1989), as
budget allocations alternate between cutbacks and recovery.
Additionally, during the last administration, the federal government
reduced its financial obligations to IMSS (Mexican Social Security
Institute), leaving almost the totality of its financing to patrons and
workers, and channeled the freed-up resources to the Secretariat of
Health (Diario Oficial, 1986).
Although the policy of focussing spending on the most impoverished
groups might seem just, it must be judged within the socioeconomic
context of Mexico and in relation to the social-policy model it implies.
No one can deny the drama of extreme poverty experienced by 17 million
Mexicans, but neither can one deny the fact that nearly half the
population lives in conditions of poverty and that the absolute majority
of workers are experiencing a serious deterioration in their living
conditions. Given this situation, to focus spending on the poorest
groups is not a just policy, but rather an ideological artifice to
justify the state's neglect of its constitutional obligation to
guarantee the social rights of all Mexicans. To this can be added the
fact that Pronasol, which is administered at the discretion of the
executive, is marked by political manipulation and clientelism.
The model of social policy taking shape is much closer to that of
an assistance-oriented policy than to a policy of social security. That
is because it does not present a social-policy scheme aimed at making
social benefits universally available to the population; on the
contrary, it is a model based on a redistribution of diminished public
spending toward the poorest stratum at the expense of other pauperized
sectors, as is clearly illustrated by the financing of IMSS.
The third central element of the neoliberal projects,
decentralization, has been promoted in both the health and education
sectors since the last administration and it continues to be a declared
intention of the National Development Plan (PND). Again, this is a
proposal that, in the abstract, may seem attractive given the oppressive
centralism of the Mexican system. However, the characteristics and
effects of decentralization demonstrate its serious limitations.
Decentralization was decreed by the executive and has been implemented
undemocratically -- from the top down. It couldn't be any other
way, since it was never intended to redistribute real decision-making
power over programs among those involved in the services, i.e., the
government agencies, the clients, and the workers. Even had this
occurred, it would have been a mere formality in Mexico's
corporatist system, in which democratic mechanisms do not operate in the
absolute majority of city governments and mass organizations, thus
impeding any real representation of citizens and workers, both rural and
urban.
In addition, the haste with which the process was undertaken did
not allow for adequate technical preparation (Menendez, 1990). Under
these conditions, the resources transferred to the state and municipal
levels did less to increase institutional efficiency than to provide a
pork barrel for local groups. Finally, the decentralization precipitated
conflicts in both sectors between bureaucratic groups who tried to
defend or promote their particular interests. Particularly notable among
such conflicts are those between the Public Education Secretariat (SEP)
and the National Union of Education Workers (SNTE) in the education
sector and between the Health Secretariat (SSA) and the Social Security
Institute (IMSS) in the health sector. In the face of such realities,
decentralization appears to be suspended because of its very high costs
in terms of institutional functioning. Nevertheless, given that the
neoliberal variant of decentralization is a means of dismantling the
state that permits the implementation of new schemes for service
products and financing, it will probably continue once the necessary
institutional adjustments have been made.
Problems New and Old
Among the problems provoked or aggravated by this social policy is,
in first place, a growing inequality between the different groups and
social classes in terms of real access to services, as well as the type
and quality of services available to each. Behind such problems is the
abandonment of a social-security policy whose goal it was to build
singular education and health institutions with universal access. In
contrast, the current policy results in the definitive separation and
divergent development of the subsystems in both education and health.
Within the education system, there is an ever growing inequality of
resources available to public and private services. Such a tendency
cannot be stopped with a public policy of restricted spending, which
means setting priorities not for education overall, but only for the
primary level. Moreover, within the public school system, there is an
unequal distribution of resources at the local and regional levels that
leaves poor zones clearly disadvantaged and has an impact on educational
opportunities. Thus, after a 6.6% increase in school enrollment in
1980-198 1, there has been a tendency toward stagnation since 1984-1985,
with growth rates below 1%. In addition, of the children who enroll in
primary school (grades one through six), 21% never make it to the third
grade -- in other words, they do not become fully literate -- and only
61% finish sixth grade. The progressively exclusionist nature of the
school system means that only 48.5% enter secondary school (grades seven
through nine), 28.6% begin high school (grades 10 through 12), and 9.8%
enter the university, of which only half finish (Fuentes, 1989). This
pattern of unequal educational opportunities is closely linked to family
economic conditions and tends to be most serious in rural areas.
However, it is notable that the primary school completion rate from the
Federal District declined from 86% in 1988 to 80% in 1989 (Poder
Ejecutivo Federal, 1989a: 185).
The situation of health services is similar. Despite the formation
of the National Health System during the last administration, this
sector is divided into three subsystems:
1. The state sector, with a small budget, which directs services
to the
population with the fewest resources;
2. The public social-security system, which is directed
essentially to
organized workers and their families; and
3. The private sector, generally endowed with abundant resources
and
directed toward upper middle sectors and the bourgeoisie.
While the state subsystem essentially guarantees selective primary
care to those who are not members of the public social-security system
and leaves 10 million without coverage (Ruiz de Chavez et al., 1988),
the social-security institutes, in principle, cover those who qualify
for all three levels of care. However, the demand for services increased
substantially because of the increasing number of those insured by the
public social-security system -- social-security coverage increased by
35% between 1982 and 1989 -- and of those excluded from private health
insurance due to its high cost. Simultaneously, the budget per person
insured decreased by 46% (Poder Ejecutivo Federal, 1989a),(4) forcing
these institutions to strengthen the bureaucratic obstacles to access to
their services. In this way, since 1986, when coverage began to increase
rapidly, all indicators of services provided (general and specialization
consultations, hospitalizations, births, etc.) have declined
systematically in relation to the number of insured (Ibid.)
Another factor making access to public health and education
services difficult is the introduction or the increase of various types
of fees. Likewise, access to private services, which depends directly on
economic capacity, has clearly been restricted due to their high cost
and to the eroded buying power of many middle-income salaried employees.
Neoliberal policies have also led to an increase in serious labor
conflicts in public institutions, by forcing public-service workers to
shoulder the burden of resolving contradictions created by resource
cutbacks. These workers have suffered marked wage decreases since 1983
(Rodriguez, 1990). Accompanying this phenomenon has been a growing wage
differentiation between the public and private sectors. This situation
tends to drain the public sectors of its most skilled personnel and
channels them into the private sector.
Additionally, the processes of rationalization based on the ideas
of scientific management of labor -- which conceives of the experience
and initiative of workers not as a positive potential, but as something
that should be regulated and suppressed -- have led to the growing
vertical control of labor and the imposition of strict norms. The direct
effect is a process of deskilling institutional labor. This situation
has further contributed to the abandonment of employment in public
institutions and to a recomposition of the skill levels in the public
sectors, together with a tendency toward its feminization, as has become
commonplace in poorly paid and unskilled jobs (Kent, 1986). Added to the
deskilling of labor, there has been a deterioration in the conditions of
work as a result of the policy of providing more services without a
corresponding increase in the resources necessary to carry out the work.
The public-service workers are the ones who must daily confront the
pressure from clients and the complaints about deficient services,
without being able to count on the material conditions and
decision-making power to improve them.
The discontent of public-service workers is further aggravated
because the decline in wages and working conditions has been
unilaterally imposed from above and outside the framework of any
effective bargaining. A sign of such discontent is the continual
resurgence of democratic trade-union movements in health and education
institutions.
Budget cutbacks, authoritarianism, the deskilling of labor, and
poor working conditions have provoked a marked deterioration in public
services that has contributed to an erosion of their prestige in
society. Slowly, they have been transformed from institutions that
legitimate the state (Navarro, 1976) to sites of social conflict in
which clients who find it increasingly difficult to obtain services
clash with those who produce the services under inadequate conditions.
Conflict and eroding prestige are found most intensely in those
institutions that have deteriorated most drastically, or in those used
by organized sectors, or those most able to make their demands felt,
such as the institutions of social security and higher education.
It is within the context of the growing deterioration and eroding
prestige of public institutions, both state and para-state
organizations, that we can discern the possible paths toward the
privatization of education and health care. First, we must distinguish
between charging for public services as a means of financing them and
privatization per se. Second, it does not appear that the dissolution of
public institutions, along the lines of what has been done to public
enterprises, is being considered. The basic feature of privatization,
then, is the parallel growth of private initiatives, with their
expansion into sectors previously covered by the state. The
privatization of some public services is occurring, but not to the
extent that the private sector will become dominant in these areas, as
it has, for example, in Brazil (Cordeiro and Zavaleta, 1987). Although
these features are shared by both the health and education sectors,
there are some differences in their concrete manifestations.
Privatization of education is being carried out directly, that is,
with the increased number and importance of private institutions. For
example, while the public budget dropped by 39% between 1982 and 1988,
private spending on education grew by 24%, coming to represent 10% of
total expenditure on education in 1988 (Fuentes, in PRD, 1990). Although
this increase has occurred at all levels of education, particularly
noteworthy is the growing importance of private universities, both
numerically and politically. Take, for example, the well-known role
played by the Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo de Mexico (ITAM) as an
adviser and producer of cadre for the current government, or the rapid
expansion of the Instituto Tecnologico de Monterrey, which now has 25
campuses throughout the country.
The expansion of private medical services runs up against the
obstacle of its high cost (Ruiz de Chavez et al., 1988), and
consequently it requires mechanisms for a guaranteed and stable market.
The existing market among small, high-income groups is not a sufficient
base for such expansion, which appears to be possible only through
medical insurance, particularly group insurance. If this is the case,
the clientele sought by private institutions will have to be organized
labor, with incomes set above the minimum wage -- in other words, those
making up the principal part of the population insured by the
social-security institutes. Seen in this light, a series of developments
appears quite logical: the deterioration and delegitimation of the
social-security institutes, the state's partial withdrawal from
financing them, the granting of unsolicited group medical insurance for
groups such as university employees (SITUAM, 1990), and new regulations
on the participation of foreign capital in insurance markets (Zepeda,
1990). These developments point toward the expansion of the private
market through group medical insurance. The result of such a process
would be to seriously weaken the social-security institutes, since they
would lose their role as the motor force in the expansion of
social-security benefits to the entire population and would be
redirected toward providing services to the poorest sectors of workers
and to administering programs such as IMSS-Complamar within the
framework of an assistance-oriented policy. Thus, there would not be a
direct privatization of the social-security institutes, but rather a
privatization of services previously provided by them.
Another fact pointing to such a form of privatization is that
private group medical insurance is now in place among employees of
banks, the subway system, insurance companies, and many companies in
Monterrey. Additionally, we must consider the fact that the production
of medical services is highly and increasingly profitable: the
before-tax income for the industry represented 63% of the gross product
in 1989 and grew to 70% in 1988 (Ruiz de Chavez et al., 1988). Likewise,
contrary to general belief, private medicine is now an important force
within the Mexican health system: it employs 157,000 people and
represents 40% of the gross domestic product of medical services
(Ibid.).
However, in the face of the tendency toward privatization, there is
an important countertendency toward the defense of public institutions.
Thus, while it is true that the daily shortcomings and difficulties
encountered by everyone tend to be interpreted as inherent to public
institutions and as justifications for their privatization, there is a
growing collective consciousness that the problem is not necessarily in
public institutions as such, but rather in the policy orientation
imposed on them. Consequently, in the union struggles of recent years --
e.g., those of the teachers, the IMSS, and the university employees --
and in the struggles of the "users," there has been an
insistence on the defense, recovery, and democratic transformation of
public institutions. When this has occurred, the conflict between
workers and users has been converted into a strategic alliance around
common goals, which forms the trench of resistance against the
neoliberal project and the embryo of a project for alternative change.
III. For an Alternate Policy
This analysis of the development and the current situation of
health and education services reveals the necessity of proposing a total
reorientation of social policy and, within this framework, of
delineating the strategic principles for solving the problems described.
The task, then, is to make a proposal that allows for overturning
neoliberal social policy and to put forth feasible measures that favor a
democratic transformation, strengthening, and expansion of public
institutions, as well as a deepening of their role in redistributing
social wealth toward the working classes. We must caution that
feasibility has to be addressed in economic and political terms. This
reality should be considered as the starting point for an alternate
project, so that its construction can help change the correlation of
forces in favor of the popular-democratic bloc.
Universal and Free Public Services
The complete reorientation of social policy will rest on the basic
principle that the state has the obligation to guarantee social rights;
in other words, fulfillment of social rights is seen as a public
function. In the Mexican case, this means reclaiming the constitutional
mandate regarding social rights as a central guideline of a social
policy based on a universal public system of social welfare. Any
proposal not based on this principle tends to deepen social inequality.
The dichotomous public-private health and education systems have
been shown to have serious disadvantages from the point of view of
social equality. This can be illustrated with the case of the United
States, where the private sector has become the main obstacle to the
establishment of a national health service, because it considers this a
threat to its particular interests and has sufficient power to block it
(Whities and Salmon, 1987). In other words, one of the principal
problems stemming from the development of an important private sector is
that it acquires the strength to block and confine the growth of the
public sector. Moreover, the model of private production of services
increases their costs and creates coverage deficits. Thus, for example,
no other country spends as much on health care as the United States --
11% of GDP -- without even providing services to all of the population
-- 16% are without stable coverage (Navarro, 1988).
Under current conditions in Mexico, it is not possible to
immediately restore public and egalitarian systems of education and
health care with universal and free access; moreover, obstacles are
greatest in the health system. However, there is no impediment to taking
specific measures aimed at paving the way to that goal. This would
necessarily mean a central, active, and dynamic role for the state.
Democratization of Public Action
Today, antistatist discourse is fed by the discrediting of state
activity characterized by the authoritarian and discretionary exercise
of power, favoritism, bureaucratism, clientelism, inefficiency, and
corruption. The discourse of privatization builds on this real situation
and proposes only one solution to such problems: transfer many of the
state's functions into private hands. Yet this obscures the
alternate solution, which is the democratic and technically competent
transformation of state activities and institutions.
Many of the current characteristics of state action stem directly
from the Mexican political regime -- presidentialist, run by a state
party, and based on corporatist domination of society -- that has been
further unbalanced by the now hegemonic group. The precondition for
transforming the state and public affairs is, therefore, the destruction
of the current political regime and the construction of another based on
political democracy free of corporatist domination. However, building a
new public practice also requires:
1. Promoting a series of concrete changes that guarantee new power
relations between civil society and the state;
2. Sufficient resources distributed on an equitable basis;
3. Effective mechanisms to regulate and control public and private
activity;
4. Honest public functionaries trained to do their jobs.
In Mexico, a system of electoral competition between parties
representing the different social and political forces would be a
mechanism to redistribute power between the state and organized society,
since the party projects would have to submit themselves to a popular
vote. Likewise, a different distribution of authority and duties among
the executive, legislative, and judicial branches would allow for
greater citizen involvement in the conduct of the state. However, for
the theme addressed here, it is necessary to go beyond electoral
democracy and a new division of powers, to propose specific mechanisms
to implement the four points noted above.
The organization of the Mexican state confers extraordinary power
on the political bureaucracy, something that, under the current rupture
of the social pact of the Mexican Revolution, prevents the correlation
of forces in society from being expressed through public institutions.
Likewise, both because of its historical formation and of the sharpening
of general sociopolitical and high-level intra-institutional
contradictions, the political bureaucracy has become so autonomous that
it is now possible to talk about the rise of a "bureaucratic
subject" (Kent, 1987). To break this extraordinary bureaucratic
power and to continue with the democratization of the institutions, the
correlation of forces in society must be expressed in the institutions,
and, in addition, a new correlation of institutional forces must be
built.
Bureaucratic power is based fundamentally on control over
decision-making processes and state resources. Therefore, it is
necessary to provide mechanisms that diminish the discretionary powers
of the upper bureaucracy and force it to:
1. Subject itself to general policy guidelines that are
democratically set;
2. Share decision making with those involved in the specific
problems
(workers and consumers); and
3. Submit their actions to a systematic evaluation by organized
society.
One such mechanism would be to establish a system of democratic
planning (not just nominal) to set the general guidelines for social
policy and the goals for change, subject to approval by the legislative
branch. Likewise, an aspect of the powers and duties of the planning
bodies would be to systematically evaluate and report on the results of
the programs, in terms of problems solved or real changes made, rather
than on the basis of actions taken. That is, health programs should be
evaluated in terms of how they have improved health conditions and not,
for example, based on the number of consultations or vaccinations
givens, etc. Education programs should be assessed in terms of decreased
illiteracy rather than the numbers enrolled in adult education, or in
terms of our collective ability to resolve the scientific-technical
problems of society, rather than the number of research papers
published.
If one of the central goals is to construct a new correlation of
forces and one that is expressed in state institutions, then we must
also base planning on the concept of strategic planning, particularly as
formulated by Testa (1987), in which a central element is the problem of
institutional power in its technical, administrative, and political
manifestations. "Policy" is defined as a proposal for
repartitioning power and "strategy" as the form of putting a
policy into practice. To present the problem in these terms focuses the
question of change as conflict between social and political forces and
allows us to think about the implications of different strategies in
terms of the strengthening or weakening of the forces involved (Chorny,
1990). In this general framework, it is also necessary to develop
specific regional and local planning in the hands of representative,
decentralized agencies with real power supported by the information
necessary to make decisions.
Democratic and Egalitarian Decentralization
Another means of changing public action would be the process of
democratic decentralization, as distinct from current decentralization.
However, given the difficulties in making decentralization democratic
and egalitarian (Belmartino, 1989), we would first have to guarantee the
resolution of various problems.
The first revolves around the question of equity and its relation
to the content and quality of services, as well as to funding schemes.
In this regard, there would have to be guarantees that decentralization
would not become a pretext for providing selective and cheap services to
the poor in a public subsystem, while maintaining other types of
services in the other subsystems (Menendez, 1990). Given that this
separation is justified by the shortage of resources, funding must be
managed with national redistributive criteria. In other words, we cannot
have funding schemes based on local taxation that tend to broadly
reproduce the inequality among rich and poor states and cities. In
addition, even though there should be decentralized decision-making
power, this must not be allowed to depart from the general social-policy
guidelines. This is particularly important in Mexico where, even
assuming a radical change in the political regime, structures of local
control will not necessarily be broken open.
A second type of problem is related to effective democratization,
given the many negative experiences with "popular
participation," e.g., in the form of health committees or parental
associations. Therefore, it would be necessary to establish management
bodies made up of popularly elected representatives from parties, social
organizations, and the institutions involved, and endowed with the power
to make decisions, manage resources, and evaluate programs. These bodies
should have sufficient authority, within the general guidelines, to
solve specific problems at the local level and the responsibility to
account for their actions before those they represent. At the same time,
this involves a struggle against authoritarian and clientelist practices
and coming up with mechanisms to provide the necessary elements of
judgment to the members of the management bodies, so as to avoid their
being controlled by those with exclusive access to scientific-technical
knowledge.
The third type of problem is the need to develop technical and
administrative skills at the local and state levels, since incompetence
in these areas has caused disasters in the already weak services of the
periphery. Access to resources and democratic management will do little
good if those administering the programs don't know how to make
them work. The problem is not simple, because it involves simultaneously
seeking to maximize technical and administrative competence while
minimizing the predominance of technical-administrative power; this can
only be carried out with a new political culture.
Finally, it would be necessary to guarantee that decentralization
would not diminish the labor-union rights of workers through the
pulverization of their unions or the disappearance of national
collective contracts. In addition, it will also be necessary to
thoroughly democratize these unions, a process already under way,
especially among teachers. In this context, we should underscore that
union democratization is not only a legitimate demand of the workers,
but also a condition for democratic decentralization, which requires
genuine representation of health and education workers.
Strengthen, Transform, and Democratize Public Institutions
The final goal or, if you prefer, the utopian horizon put forth in
the proposed alternate social policy is a universal public system of
social welfare. As noted, this project faces serious obstacles in the
short run, but the proposed measures should lead in the right direction
and contribute to its construction. Given the specific characteristics
of the health and education systems, the concrete steps toward
institutional reorganization and reorientation are different in each
case.
Thus, bringing about a free unitary health service with universal
coverage and access requires undertaking the integration of the public
and social-security subsystems. The first steps, then, would be to
establish a Secretariat of Health and Social Security, a single
social-security institution, and uniform legislation, norms,
orientation, and content of institutional services and financing. The
principal problem is to avoid allowing the integration of the
institutions to lead to even greater deterioration of services because
of a sudden excess of demand, since this has been an important element
in delegitimating health reform in other countries.(5)
There is also an immediate need for reconstruction and
strengthening of the institutes, to reverse their deterioration and
improve the quality of services. This entails providing them with the
necessary resources and mobilizing the collective and creative capacity
of the workers; both questions will be addressed below. Likewise,
improving institutional action entails an emphasis on preventive and
primary health care, with maximum and integral attention paid to
establishing programs at the municipal and community levels, with the
participation of democratic bodies and labor unions in planning and
management. However, complete fulfillment of the right to health
protection does not permit restricting access to primary care; rather,
it requires the harmonized growth of all three levels of care and the
construction of a system of referral and counterreferral.
Given that the education sector is divided between the public and
private systems, the problem is to strengthen the public system and to
recapture its role as rector of education and scientific research. As
with the health system, this means making available the necessary
resources and mobilizing the creative capacity of the workers.
In light of the growing numbers of people without access to the
basic cycle and their exclusion at successive levels of education, a
maximum priority must be to guarantee that the basic cycle is obligatory
and free, and to begin creating conditions that favor real access for
all youth to education. Likewise, it is necessary to reinforce the role
of public institutions of higher education, both in the formation of
professionals and in research into the strategic problems facing
society. Achieving these goals, however, depends not only on a
quantitative expansion of educational institutions, but also on changes
in curricular and research orientation and pedagogical innovation, so as
to address the demands created by the necessary expansion of educational
access to the masses of the population (Fuentes, 1988).
Strengthening the public sectors requires an express policy
regarding the private sectors in health and education, since, as we have
seen, they tend to mutually condition one another. Therefore, it is
necessary, first to regulate the private production of services,
establishing both norms of quality and price controls. It is also
necessary to reverse the tendency of the private sector's
increasing weight so that it does not gain greater political force and
become an obstacle to the expansion of the public sector. Likewise, we
will have to consider specific mechanisms of control over the
pharmaceutical and medical-equipment industries, to reduce their high
cost and influence over the model of care.
Another central aspect for improving and transforming public
services is to restore, in the near term, the economic and working
conditions of public workers and to rehabilitate organized labor. This
would permit bases to be established for a new "institutional
pact" in order to mobilize the collective ability of the workers to
creatively confront the necessities of health and education. Without
such a basic institutional accord, the best programs would fail upon
encountering the resistance of the workers.(6) The rehabilitation of
labor means a process of permanent training and updating of skills and
information, but it also means a reorganization of labor to increase
workers' control and decision-making ability over their labor.
Along with this goes the need to reestablish democracy in the labor
unions as an integral part of institutional democratization.
Democratization of the management of the institutions is part of
the general democratization of public action. Thus, it means
establishing management bodies with the effective participation of
workers and users, harmonizing their functions with those of other
democratic bodies. Particular attention must be paid to the criteria for
democratically appointing the leading cadre of the institutions and of
setting norms for their performance. Minimally, these should include
professional ability and the duty to carry out policies set by the
management bodies and to be accountable to them. Likewise, we must
undertake a vigorous fight against the various forms of corruption and
abuse of power, submitting the management of institutions and public
funds to censure by the democratic management bodies with the aid of
systematic audits.
Increase of Resources and Redistribution of Social Wealth
The main argument made to justify the neoliberal slant of social
policy is the scarcity of resources, which has allegedly required the
cuts in social spending, the focusing of resources on the poorest
groups, and the increasing responsibility born by society (read each
individual) for satisfying health and education needs. As a consequence,
public services have been turned into a marginal instrument for the
general redistribution of social wealth, since they have almost no
impact on the extremely asymmetrical distribution of disposable income between profits and remunerations (Poder Ejecutivo Federal, 1989a).
Moreover, with the policy of maintaining a budget surplus so as to
guarantee debt-service payments, working people do not even get back as
public services what they paid out in the various taxes that brought in
income six times greater than social spending (Ibid.).
Thus, it should be clear that the current policy of maintaining
health and education spending levels below international norms is not an
unavoidable necessity, but rather a conscious choice. An alternate
policy, based on different priorities, would allow for a rapid increase
of the state's budget and the channeling of resources into social
spending,(7) with the added advantage that a greater supply of public
health and education services is not necessarily inflationary. In
addition, a policy of wage recovery would automatically increase the
incomes of the social-security institutes, since they are directly
proportional to the wages of the insured.
However, to channel the necessary resources for the
universalization of high-quality public services and turn them into a
real mechanism for redistributing social wealth would require a
fundamental revision of distributive policy, both in terms of wages and
taxes. Regarding the latter, and directly related to the problem of
financing health and education services, special taxes directed
specifically toward these services and a substantial increase in
social-security quotas should be explored. Possible special taxes could
include taxes on the sale of private health and education services and
on alcohol and tobacco. The first is justified because of the high
profit levels in the production of private services (Ruiz de Chavez,
Marquez, and Ochoa, 1988). Regarding alcohol and tobacco, there are
several ways of implementing a tax; one way would be to prohibit
advertising these products and to establish as a tax a percentage
equivalent to advertising expenditures, which would not affect the price
structure -- or, alternatively, to set a tax of 100% on sales that would
additionally satisfy those who believe that price is a disincentive to
consumption.
Increasing social-security quotas paid by employers has the
attraction of directly changing the distribution between profits and
wages, assuming that the increase would not be passed on in the final
price of the product. In addition, increasing Social Security payments
has been one of the principal mechanisms for increasing state income in
other countries (Baillet and Zimmermann, 1989). This could be an
important mechanism for financing the construction of universal health
and education services.
Within the framework of substantial and increasing expenditures on
health and education, it would be possible to set up financing schemes
that would lead to more rapid rates of growth in the most backward areas
without sacrificing spending directed toward all public services. That
is, an alternative with such characteristics sets priorities for a
general expansion of public services and, within this framework, seeks
to resolve in the short run the main accumulated problems -- all of
which runs counter to the current policy of restricting public resources
and then focusing the reduced spending on the poorest groups.
NOTES
(1.) See the PNUD study, Proyecto regional para la superacion de la
pobreza, Mexico, 1989, cited in Provencio (1989); and Rojas (1990). (2.)
See Table 1 of Primer Informe del Gobierno (Poder Ejecutivo Federal,
1989a). (3.) See, e.g., Contreras (1986), Haignere (1986), Bello (1983),
Balmartino and Bloch (1984), and Fleury (1989a). (4.) Figure adjusted
according to the National Consumer Price Index. (5.) See, e.g., Fleury
(1989b) and Berlinguer (1982). (6.) See, e.g., Fleury (1989a) and
Torresgoitia (1987). (7.) See, e.g., Clark (1989).
REFERENCES
Baillet, A. and H. Zimmermann 1989 La evolucion reciente del sistema
impositivo de Mexico y Alemania. Mexico: F.F. Elbert. Bello, J. 1983
"Politica sanitaria argentina 1976-1981." Cuadernos
Medico-sociales 23. Belmartino, S. 1989 "Politicas sociales,
discusion de una alternativa." Cuadernos Medico-sociales 49-50.
Belmartino, S. and C. Bloch 1984 "Las politicas de salud y
bienestar social en Argentina." Estudios Sociologicos 2,5/6: 277.
Berlinguer, G. 1982 Gli anni difficile della riforma sanitaria. Bari: De
Donato. Chorny, A. 1990 "El enfoque estratigico para el desarrollo
de recursos humanos." Educacion medica y salud 24, 1, Clark, R.
1989 "Una politica economica para el corto plazo." Cuadernos
Politicos 57. Contreras, R. (ed.). 1986 Salud publica, privada y
solidaria en el Chile actual. Santiago: PET. Cordeiro, H. and H.
Zavaleta 1987 "Analisis de la practica medica actual en America
Latina. Alternativas y tendencias." Analisis de las organizaciones
de salud. Washington, D.C.: OPS. Davis, M. 1986 Prisoners of the
American Dream. London: Verso. Fleury, S. 1989a "La politica de
salud en una transicion conservadora." Cuadernos Medico-sociales
48. 1989b Reforma sanitaria. Sao Paulo: Abrasco. Fuentes, O. 1989
"El acceso a la escolaridad en Mixico." Cuadernos Politicos
58. 1988 "Universidad y democracia. La mirada hacia la
izquierda." Cuadernos Politicos 53. Gutierrez, R. 1989 "La
decada perdida de los 80's." El Cotidiano 32. Haignere, S.S.
1986 "The Application of the Free Market Model in Chile."
International Journal of Health Services 13,3: 389. Kent, R. 1987
"La organizacion universitaria y la masificacion." Sociologica
2,5. 1986 "Los profesores y la crisis universitaria."
Cuadernos Politicos 46. Marquez, P.V., and T. Engler 1990 "Crisis y
salud: retos para los 90." Educacion Medica y Salud 24,1: 7-26.
Menendez, E. 1990 "Continuidad y discontinuidad del proyecto
sanitaria mexicano. Crisis y reorientacion neoconservadora." I.
Almada (ed.), Salud y crisis en Mexico. Mexico: Siglo XXI. Navarro, V.
1989 "Why Some Countries Have National Health Insurance, Others
Have National Health Services, and the U.S. Has Neither." Social
Science and Medicine 28,9: 887. 1988 "The Arguments against a
National Health Program: Science or Ideology." International
Journal of Health Services 18,2. 1976 La medicina bajo el capitalismo.
Barcelona: Grijalvo. Ochoa, M. 1990 "Politica de gasto en el sector
salud (1977-1986)." I. Almada (ed.), Salud y crisis en Mexico.
Mexico: Siglo XXI. PRD 1990 1989: Informe de la situacion nacional.
Mexico. Poder Ejecutivo Federal 1989a Primer Informe de Gobierno. Anexo
estadistico. Mexico. 1989b Plan Nacional de Desarrollo: 1989-1994.
Mexico. Provencio, E. 1989 "El nuevo plan y la politica
social." Cuadernos de Nexos 13. Rodriguez, C. 1990 "La
respuesta social. Los trabajadores de la salud." I. Almada (ed.),
Salud y crisis en Mexico. Mexico: Siglo XXI. Rojas, C. 1990 "La
solidaridad una urgencia social." Speech given at the Centro de
Estudios Mexico-Americanos, published in La Jornada 25-26/1. Ruiz de
Chavez, M., M. Marquez, and M. Ochoa 1988 El enfoque de la salud como
sector social. Mexico: SSA. SEP 1989 Programa para la modemizacion
educativa. Mexico. SITUAM 1990 Seguro familiar de gastos medicos
mayores. Mexico: Boletin Informativo. SSA 1984 Programa Nacional de
Salud. Taylor-Gooby, P. 1989 "Welfare, Hierarchy, and the |New
Right': The Impact of Social Policy Changes in Britain,
1979-89." International Sociology 4,4: 441-446. Testa, M. 1987
"Estrategia, coherencia y poder en la propuesta de salud."
Cuadernos Medico-sociales 38-39. Therborn, G. and J. Roebroek 1986
"The Irreversible Welfare State." International Journal of
Health Services 16,3: 332. 1985 "Los trabajadores y las
transformaciones del capitalismo avanzado." Cuadernos Politicos 43.
Torresgoitia, J. 1987 Democracia y salud La experiencia de Bolivia.
Santiago: ILPES/UNICEF. Whities, D. and J.W. Salmon 1987 "The
Propietarization of Health Care and the Underdevelopment of the Public
Sector." International Journal of Health Services 17,1. Zepeda, M.
1990 "El periodico legislativo de fin de ano." Coyuntura, No.
0.