Pressing concerns: questions for the Euro area.
Alesina, Alberto
The big question for today's international monetary system is:
will the Euro survive? I believe that it will, and that Euro-land will
muddle through its current serious difficulties.
The common currency in Europe has run into two problems. One was
well understood by skeptics of the entire plan of a monetary union in
Europe, while a second was less anticipated. The first is the fact that
countries with very different levels of productivity growth are tied
together by a common exchange rate and monetary policy.
Countries like Greece, Portugal, Spain, and Italy would benefit, at
least temporarily, from a devaluation of their currencies to help them
overcome their economic stagnation, which seems to have followed the
Great Recession of 2008-2009. Other means of adjustment certainly exist,
but those would imply lower growth or even a reduction in monetary wages
to compensate for the relatively strong Euro and the low productivity
growth in these countries. Such adjustments are also politically
difficult, and devaluations would, at least in the short run, help. In
addition, the European Central Bank will have to follow a monetary
policy not only specifically targeting the needs of these countries, but
also considering the needs of the Euro area as a whole, which includes
other economies on more solid ground like Germany.
The second problem emerged from the ability of many countries to
borrow at very low rates during the first decade of the Euro. Greece,
Spain, Ireland, and Portugal could borrow abroad at rates close to those
of Germany because the exchange risk was removed. These countries thus
went on borrowing sprees and became intoxicated by the temptation of low
interest rates in world markets. Ultimately, however, the market woke
up, realized that Greece is not Germany in terms of fiscal solidity, and
demanded compensation for risk. The system then unraveled, and the
higher interest rates demanded by markets increased the fiscal problem
of these indebted countries. The worse the finances of these countries
became, the more the market demanded compensation for risk and higher
interest rates. This demand, in turn, caused deficits to rise,
ultimately creating a vicious circle that started with Greece, went to
Ireland and Portugal, and marginally touched even Spain and Italy.
At this point, a third problem of a political nature surfaced: the
lack of an institutional process to deal with crises of this nature.
Europe was like a town hall deciding how to organize its fire department
while several houses burned. Many observers advocated more power for
European-level institutions in the area of fiscal policy. Everybody
recognized that the Growth and Stability Pact, set up to ensure fiscal
prudence, was failing due to lack of enforcement. Yet the burden of
fiscal restraint will remain in domestic hands, as national governments
prove reluctant to abandon any fiscal discretionary power. They have
exercised this power with monetary policy, but fiscal policy is more
directly linked with politics. Government alliances are kept intact with
fiscal favors, constituencies are "bought" with spending
programs, and fiscal transfers are the glue that keeps government
together. This is why most governments want the European Union off their
fiscal turf. Although Germany is pushing for fiscal rules to be added to
the national constitution, it is unlikely that many countries will
follow.
Thus, the question at the beginning of this piece can be rephrased
with two more specific ones: will European countries manage to live
together with the same exchange rate and the same monetary policy? And
will they be more fiscally prudent in the future? The answer to both
questions is yes, at least for the foreseeable future. The cost of
abandoning the monetary union would be quite large, possibly entailing
trade isolation, serious transaction costs, and major loss of
credibility for the exiting country with the associated high borrowing
costs. As for fiscal prudence, various European countries seem to have
learned the lesson from their recent near-death experience and are
indeed trying to put their fiscal houses in order, some more
aggressively than others. Does this trend mean that Europe is out of the
tunnel? Not quite. Some debt restructuring (partial default) for Greece
is likely, and some contagion effects will surely follow and influence
other countries. If productivity does not increase quickly in southern
Europe, growth differences will persist for a while, creating tension
for the monetary policy of the European Central Bank.
The economic road ahead is rocky for Europe, and the second decade
of the Euro will be much more difficult than the first. The Euro area
needs fiscal restraint, a better mechanism for crisis resolution, and
structural reforms, especially in southern European countries to make
them more competitive. Hopefully, the European leaders have understood
this message from the recent crisis.
ALBERTO ALESINA serves as the Nathaniel Ropes Professor of
Political Economy at Harvard University.