The Inter-American Development Bank presents ... pushing for progress. Women, work, and gender roles in Latin America.
Nopo, Hugo
The world, and particularly Latin America, has experienced
important changes regarding the role of women and men during the last
three to four decades. Women's visibility at home, at school, in
the labor markets, and in society in general, has evolved significantly.
Concurrently, men's role has evolved as well. This article will
discuss these trends, highlighting the pending issues towards a better
participation of females in the labor markets and outlining some
possible courses of action.
Female school achievement has increased more than that of males.
For those born by 1940, males achieved on average an extra year of
schooling over females (six vs. five years respectively), while for
those born by 1980, females attended an extra quarter of a school year
more than males (9.5 vs. 9.2 years). The gender gap in schooling for the
cohort born in 1968 reversed from being male-dominated to being
female-dominated. The only countries for which the academic gender gap
has not reversed are Bolivia and Guatemala, two countries with large
indigenous populations, which may suggest important linkages between
gender and ethnic disparities among these countries.
It is also interesting to note that this improvement in female
schooling occurred at the higher end of the schooling distribution.
While by 1992, 16.35 percent of working females and 10.66 percent of
working males had some (complete or incomplete) tertiary education in
the region overall, by 2007 those percentages were 26.05 percent and
17.26 percent respectively. The global phenomenon of higher schooling
achievement among females began earlier in Latin America than in the
rest of the world.
Female labor force participation has increased, while that of males
remains almost constant. Whereas by the beginning of the 1990s one-half
of Latin American women participated in the labor markets, either
working or looking for a job, nowadays it has reached almost two out of
three women in most of the region. The most recent studies at the
Inter-American Development Bank reveal that most of the increase in
female labor force participation can be explained by the increase of
participation amongst young married women, suggesting a cohort effect.
During the same period, male labor force participation remained almost
constant in the region. In other regions, male labor force participation
even dropped (as in OECD countries, for instance) However, males still
dominate labor markets to the point that three out of five workers in
the Latin American region are males. Occupational segregation by gender
is still largely prevalent in the region as well.
The share of female-headed households has also shown substantial
increases. By the beginning of the 1990s, females headed 1.2 percent of
complete households (those where there are both husband and wife
present) and 79.8 percent of single-headed households. Such percentages
have increased to 9.2 percent and 82.3 percent respectively by the late
2000s, with the most significant increase in complete households.
Besides the challenges that represent the measurement of male and female
headship, the data trends show that a picture of increasing female
headship, even in those households where there is a father present, is
gaining space in the region. Also, the data shows that female-headed
households are at both extremes of the income distribution. Some
household-head females correspond to the profile of a single young woman
in professional or managerial positions with young children (age one or
two at most) at the upper extreme of the income distribution. Some other
household head females correspond to the profile of a low-educated
single mother, with many children (three or more), and an informal job
in the service and commerce sectors, around or below poverty lines.
Fertility has dropped and the region has been characterized by
notorious cross-country heterogeneity, not only in terms of fertility
rates, but also in the speed at which these rates have been dropping. In
Argentina and Uruguay fertility rates started to decrease as early as in
the 1930s. Countries like Bolivia, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua, and
Paraguay, in contrast, still showed high fertility rates by the mid
1990s, but recent years show a decrease as well. This is reflected in
the statistics about the presence of children in Latin American
households. While by the beginning of the 1990s one in nine working
women (11 percent) lived in a household where there was at least one
child of age six or younger, by the end of the first decade of the 2000s
this percentage almost halved. A similar situation took place for males:
the percentage living in households with children dropped from 16
percent to 9 percent. This phenomenon, which has been linked to delays
in women's age at first child and higher prices in the labor
markets, suggests an alleviation of household responsibilities, at least
those related to childbearing and childrearing. For the countries that
began the demographic transition early, however, the responsibilities
are shifting to the care of the elderly and the sick.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Marriage, education, and work decisions have evolved. As mentioned
above, most of the increase in female labor force participation has been
due to an increase in participation among married women. Furthermore,
the most significant increase can be seen among those who married more
educated husbands than themselves and, not surprisingly, those with no
children and no elderly relatives at home. Also, recent work by Ricardo
Hausmann and his coauthors reveals that skilled women are less likely to
be married (or cohabiting) than unskilled women and skilled men. It is
less likely for skilled women who are married to work than unmarried,
skilled women. Also, skilled women in Latin America are more likely to
marry a less skilled husband than in other regions, simply as a result
of relative abundance and scarcity in the mating markets. When marrying
a husband less skilled than themselves, women are more likely to Work
than when marrying an equally skilled husband.
However, women are still lagging behind men in one crucial factor:
labor earnings. Women have achieved important progress in their
participation in the labor markets and the human capital they bring into
it, but the markets still fail to reward them appropriately. Or, in a
dynamic perspective, the speed at which gender earnings disparities are
reducing does not seem to align with the speed at which women gain
schooling and human capital. Current prime-age workers are precisely the
cohort for which the gender schooling gap reversed from being
male-dominated to a female-dominated one. The gender earnings gap,
however, is not only far from a similar reversal, but also far from
parity.
Gender earnings disparities
By the beginning of the 1990s, the region's average indicated
that for every 100 monetary units females earned in the labor markets,
males would earn 116.32, a 16.32 percent gap. By 2007, this gap was 8.8
percent. The gap has dropped almost eight percentage points in almost
two decades, but it still favors males and it does not reflect the
favorable human capital characteristics that women have. However, these
gender earnings gaps could well be the result of gender differences in
individuals or in the job characteristics that the labor markets reward.
Hence the observed gender disparities are somewhat misleading as the
correct comparison of earnings disparities should be made on the basis
of comparing earnings of individuals with similar characteristics.
A sequence of work done and forthcoming at the Inter-American
Development Bank has been documenting the extent to which gender
earnings disparities correspond to gender differences in observable
individual and job characteristics. The first result to highlight from
this line of research is the role of education in explaining the
earnings differentials. It is somewhat paradoxical that besides having
more schooling, women still earn less than men, as will be discussed
later in this article. When comparing males and females with the same
age and schooling, the earnings gaps are actually higher than those
originally observed, and they show a smaller drop than the one shown by
the unconditional gaps (25 percent by the beginning of the 1990s and 22
percent by the end of the first decade of the 2000s respectively).
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Another variable that plays an important role in the analysis of
gender earnings disparities is part-time work, defined as working 30
hours or fewer per week. The inclusion of such a variable also increases
the gender earnings gap. A refined exercise was made such that male and
female earnings with the same age, schooling, presence of kids at home,
presence of other income-generator at home, the urban/rural divide, type
of employment (distinguishing self-employed, employees, and employers),
and time worked (distinguishing part-time, full-time, and over-time
workers) were compared. The results showed that the gender earnings gap
was 34 percent in 1990s and 30 percent by the mid 2000s, more than
double what the unconditional gap shows.
These average gender earnings gaps also show important
heterogeneity within the labor markets. Females' underpayment with
respect to males with the same characteristics is more pronounced among
poor and low-educated workers, those in small firms or self-employed,
and diose working part-time or with no formal labor contract. The good
news, however, is that these same segments of the labor markets where
the gender disparities are more pronounced are also the segments that
have shown the biggest reductions in the earnings gaps. When looking at
particular countries within the region, it is in Brazil where the gender
earnings disparities are the highest, but it is also in this country
where the drop in the gaps has been the largest. The gaps are declining
and this has been happening where they are wider. The speed of this
reduction, however, has not been reflecting the speed at which related
characteristics, such as females' education, have improved. There
is still much work to be done.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Persistent disparities
If women's credentials are improving, what explains such
resilient gender earnings disparities? Traditionally, two of the most
prominent explanations have been discrimination and gender roles. Recent
evidence suggests that information can be an effective antidote against
discrimination. Gender roles, deeply embedded in the culture, may
require a longer-term approach.
There are good indications that discrimination can be alleviated
with information. Joseph Altonji and Charles Pierret pioneered this with
the idea that discrimination, if present, should fall with tenure (as
information about real productivity reveals with tenure), validating it
with US data. More recently for Latin America, specifically Peru,
Castillo, Petrie, and Torero have shown in an experimental setup that
individuals tend to stereotype. In the absence of information, when
pressed to make decisions regarding group formation, individuals use
observable characteristics such as gender, skin color, and height as
proxies for productivity. When real information about productivity is
revealed, individuals do not use these proxies anymore and base their
decisions on the productivity data instead. Information trumps discrimination. Also, the Bank's finding that the gender earnings
disparities are most pronounced among the self-employed gives less
credence to the idea of employer discrimination in the Latin American
labor markets.
The finding that female underpayment is more pronounced in
part-time work, small firms, and informal jobs is also revealing. All of
these point to an employment characteristic that females prefer:
flexibility. As a matter of fact, while one in four women work part-time
in Latin America, it is only one in ten men who do so. Flexible labor
force participation is a predominantly female terrain. Such preference
for flexibility is not just an innate characteristic of women; rather,
it arises as a result of the constrained decision-making women have to
make in order to participate in labor markets. Given the traditional
division of labor within households, and hence females' greater
responsibilities at home, many women can only participate in the labor
market if the position offers flexibility. This reduces their bargaining
power for higher earnings, configuring the situation just outlined.
Available data on time use substantiates the explanation above.
Between 70 percent and 80 percent of the time devoted to domestic work
in Latin American households is the contribution of women, far more than
women's contribution in other societies. For instance, in the
United States and the United Kingdom, women's contribution is
around 60 percent. When a woman in Latin America works part-time, her
share of domestic work rises to roughly 80 percent, while her share for
full-time work is between 60 percent and 70 percent. This, as well as
the number of hours devoted to work weekly, has not changed much during
recent years.
Policy options
With this panorama of progress and the pending challenge regarding
parity in the labor markets, some policy options arise. Alternative
actions may seem numerous, but this article will focus on three:
legislation for equality of opportunities; information diffusion to
reduce stereotyping, foster attitudinal changes, and nurture egalitarian
values; and effective alleviation of women's household
responsibilities.
Legislation regarding gender parity is not new in the region. As a
matter of fact, most countries have some sort of anti-discriminatory law
and protection of women within their systems. Such legislation is full
of good intentions but, unfortunately, most of them generate unintended
behaviors that are not conducive to gender parity. A law that, for
example, requires equal pay for all males and females performing the
same job encourages employers either to prevent employees'
promotions or to hire informally. This, in turn, introduces distortions
to the labor markets provoking a sub-optimal use of resources at both
the micro and macro level.
Legislation promoting parity should be conceptualized in a more
integral way, analyzing both intended and potentially unintended
consequences of the law. A common mistake of such laws is to pretend to
regulate outcomes (employment, wages, or special benefits) instead of
inputs (time availability, for instance). A renewed focus on inputs
needs to be in place. A good example could be the promotion of paternity leaves. Currently, leaves for recent mothers notoriously surpass those
for recent fathers. This, as has been argued, serves as a source of
inequity as it reduces females' employability. An equalization of
maternity and paternity leaves may help level the playing field
regarding hiring decisions for males and females. Leave equalization may
also generate positive consequences out of the labor markets as well.
Encouraging men and women to devote the same time to their newborns and,
hence, home, may also induce more harmonic households, with fairer
intra-household bargaining and decision-making. This in turn would help
to nurture a more equitable split of responsibilities, time, and
opportunities within households. Of course, a single regulation like
this one, even with good enforcement and conscious compliance, would not
do much for a more egalitarian society if it is not accompanied by a set
of concurrent measures in different spheres.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Secondly, as discussed in this note, information diffu sion can be
an effective tool to reduce stereotyping in day-to-day activities.
Sometimes, however, these information flows cannot be produced at the
speed the markets require. Not all social interactions can benefit from
information flows, like the experimental example in Peru. Then, the
alternative becomes generating information flows geared towards more
permanent, not situation-specific, cultural and attitudinal changes. One
fruitful avenue in that regard has been the introduction of placement
tied with mentoring and networking programs. Getting women into the
workplace has helped to change (male and female) employers' and
coworkers' perceptions, trumping stereotypes. But more massive
tools are needed.
Soap operas, for instance, have worked as effective instruments for
such massive cultural and attitudinal changes. Work by Chong and La
Ferrara has illustrated how the subtle introduction of role models in
Brazilian soap operas, over the course of decades, induced changes in
fertility and divorce rates in the Brazilian middle class. Massive
campaigns to make people more aware about misperceptions regarding
gender roles at the workplace and day-to-day life may play an important
role. But bear in mind that egalitarian values are not spontaneously
generated; they require some time to be nurtured.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Such nurturing has to start at home during the early years and then
continue at school. In this respect, there still are pending issues.
Work done in Peru at Group for the Analysis of Development (GRADE)
suggests that the schooling system nurtures gender stereotypes. An
analysis of school textbooks there revealed that two-thirds of human
images that appeared on 4th and 6th grades textbooks were boys while
just one-third were girls. Females' images were predominantly
related to leisure and domestic work, while those related to male
activities were more linked to labor and schooling. Such subtle, and
most likely unconscious, communication of stereotypes need to be
eradicated. As already outlined in this note, more women are attending
school, yes, but a pending question is "What are they learning
there?" There is room for action along these lines.
The third recommendation, to alleviate women's restrictions on
time use and household responsibilities, may be more costly than the
previous two. Nonetheless, its effects are more likely to be seen in the
short and the long run than the previous two. The reality is that women
are in charge of taking care of kids at home, reducing their
possibilities of fully participating in the labor markets. Hence, an
effective way of alleviating those responsibilities is promoting
alternative daycare options. Expanding the networks of early child
development (ECD) facilities and extending the school schedules for
primary students can work in the desired direction. Preliminary evidence
on this reveals that the length of the school shift is important.
Currently short school schedules fail to free up enough time for female
participation in the labor markets. Or, they allow only part-time
participation, with substantial earnings disparities, as discussed
above. An effective freeing up of females' time to devote to the
labor markets along these lines would not only produce short-run
economic gains. This would also be a profitable long-run investment in
better education.
HUGO NOPO is a Lead Research Economist for Education at the
Inter-American Development Bank. His research considers the use of
applied econometrics to the understanding of labor markets, educational
systems, inequality and poverty, with a focus on Latin America.