Necessary reform? The IMF and international financial architecture.
Cooper, Richard N.
The most salient issue of those concerned with the international
financial architecture back in mid-2007 was "governance," in
particular governance of the International Monetary Fund (IMF). This
involved, among other things, the selection of future Managing Directors
(by convention since 1946 always a European), representation on the
Executive Board (which is responsible for the operating decisions of the
IMF), and voting rights, which were based on out-dated formulae. The
"legitimacy" of the IMF was said to be in doubt. This concern
with governance was against a backdrop of excellent performance of the
world economy since 2002, high and widespread growth, and low inflation
but rising commodity prices, which helped exporters of primary products.
The IMF had made no significant loans since 2003, many countries had
repaid their outstanding debts to the IMF (down from US$107 billion in
2003 to US$15 billion in 2007), and with low interest income the IMF was
anticipating difficulty in meeting its normal operating expenses.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Much has changed since mid-2007. The likelihood of worldwide
recession has moved governance reform to the back burner--or, in the
views of some, made it more urgent. There is much talk of the need to
reform the international financial system substantively and calls for a
second Bretton Woods, recalling the international meeting in 1944 that
agreed on the main features of the post-1945 international monetary
system and that led to the creation of the IMF and its sister
institution the World Bank.
However, a key unasked question lies behind these calls: if
international financial governance had been plausibly different, would
it have markedly attenuated the magnitude of international ramifications
of the evolving financial and economic crisis? My tentative answer is
negative, as international organizations such as the IMF are constrained
by the limitations on international action. But that is not to say that
the IMF does not warrant an expanded role.
A New Governance Proposal
There were signs of difficulty in the US subprime mortgage market
beginning in 2007, when defaults had begun to rise and construction of
new residences had declined from their peak in 2005. This even had a
modest international impact, as two French mutual funds suspended
trading because they could not properly value some of their securities
backed by US mortgages. But all this seemed to be mainly a US problem,
no doubt manageable.
However, by mid-2007, events were changing, often rapidly and
dramatically: the seizing up of asset-backed commercial paper markets in
August 2007, requiring large injections of liquidity both by the
European Central Bank and by the Federal Reserve; the failure and
government takeover of Northern Rock, a major British mortgage firm; the
takeover of Bear Stearns, America's fifth largest investment bank,
by JPMorgan Chase with strong financial assistance from the Federal
Reserve; government financial support to two large US mortgage
institutions, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac; unusual support to AIG, the
world's largest insurance company; the failure of Lehman Brothers,
the fourth largest US investment bank; and by September 2008 a general
flight to safety and aversion to risk among most financial institutions.
By the fall of 2008 the IMF was back in the lending business, with
loans to Iceland, Hungary, Ukraine, and Pakistan, and more in the works.
Governance issues had receded in deference to more operational
concerns--not only for the IMF, but also for other parts of the
international financial structure, such as the several committees of the
Bank for International Settlements charged with improving financial
regulation, the Financial Stability Forum, and of course for governments
and central banks as the world seemed to be sliding into recession, or
worse.
Edwin Truman and I put forward a proposal in February 2007 to
reform the governance of the IMF, addressed to the issue of legitimacy.
Briefly, our proposal called for revising the formulae by which IMF
voting rights (and borrowing rights) are established, giving modestly
greater weight to all small countries, substantially greater weight to
many rapidly developing countries (so-called emerging markets), less
weight to medium-sized European countries; reducing the number of
Europeans (nine of 24, counting Russia) on the Executive Board; and
increasing IMF quotas by about 50 percent both to accommodate the rising
value of world trade and to avoid any reduction in quota that otherwise
would have occurred with the re-weighting of voting rights. (The last
quota increase was in 1998.)
The IMF addressed the issue of governance in a report of March 2008
to its Governors. The proposal would reduce the voting share of the 26
industrial countries by 2.6 percentage points, and Europe's share
by 1.6 percentage points, compared with 14 percentage points and 11
percentage points, respectively, in the Cooper-Truman proposal. Thus the
Fund remains dominated by Europeans, both in votes (31 percent) and in
Board representation. Whether this modest agreed change (but not yet
fully implemented, since amendment to the Articles requires
parliamentary ratification) responds to calls for greater legitimacy
remains to be seen.
One can nonetheless play a thought experiment: suppose the
Cooper-Truman proposal had been adopted in 2002. Would the IMF responses
in 2007-2008 have been markedly different from what they were? Would the
IMF have significantly attenuated the international crisis? I believe an
honest answer must be negative.
Part of the reason for this answer is that the key central banks,
including most notably the US Federal Reserve, responded vigorously to
the emerging financial crisis with a speed, magnitude, and
unorthodoxy--providing general liquidity in abundance, supporting
specific institutions whose failure would have threatened much wider
damage, and extending swap lines to selected foreign central banks in
excess of US$700 billion--that it would be difficult to imagine coming
from the IMF as an international organization under any plausible set of
governance arrangements.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Exploring Alternative Regulatory Agencies
The IMF is not a regulatory agency, and is not staffed adequately
to be a regulatory agency, although it occasionally gives advice to
member states on desirable financial regulation. However, the Bank for
International Settlements in Basel, Switzerland, plays host to several
international committees that are concerned with financial performance
and regulation: committees on banking supervision, on the global
financial system, on payment and settlement systems, on markets, and on
counterfeit deterrence. These committees regularly brought together
relevant officials from national capitals to discuss common problems and
to identify potential problems. The best known product is agreement on
the so-called Basel II risk-based capital requirements for banks that
are heavily engaged in international activities. For large banks, it
placed reliance on sophisticated individual bank risk assessment models,
models that apparently failed signally during the recent financial
turmoil.
In addition to the BIS committees there is the Financial Stability
Forum, created with 12 member countries in 1999 to assess risks and
vulnerabilities affecting the international financial system and to
encourage and coordinate action to address them. In April 2008 the FSF submitted a report to the G-7 finance ministers that called for action
in five areas: strengthened oversight of capital, liquidity, and risk
management; enhanced transparency and valuation; the role of credit
ratings; strengthened official response to risks; and arrangements for
dealing with stress in the financial system. It built on earlier work,
but obviously action was too late to avoid the financial meltdown of
September 2008.
The bottom line: there has been no shortage of fora for discussions
among relevant national regulatory authorities about potential financial
problems. But they evidently were deficient in imagination and/or unable
to convey effectively their concerns to the national political
authorities who alone could have taken effective action.
The key problem is this: in a period of economic euphoria, when
everything seems to be going well, no one wants to take away the punch
bowl, to use the colorful metaphor of former Federal Reserve chairman
William McChesney Martin. As time goes on, personnel in financial
institutions change, and each new generation of traders and financial
managers believes it is intellectually and technically superior to its
predecessors. Moreover, they maintain that they have nothing to learn
from their experiences, particularly their unhappy experiences. Their
world is different from that of their elders. In addition, the system of
rewards in the private financial community has placed a premium on
short-term performance and has neglected long-term risk.
Under these conditions, it is difficult to imagine structural
changes at the international level that would either have prevented the
financial crisis or substantially ameliorated it.
The IMF at a Glance
Voting Power of IMF Member States
Europe 31%
Remaning Countries 39%
Other Advanced Economies 13%
United States 17%
-Current membership: 185 countries, of which 30 are considered
"advanced economies"
-Total quotas: $352 billion, advanced economies contribute 63% of
quotas
-Outstanding loans: $ 19.4 billion
-Biggest contributors: United States, Japan, Germany, France, United
Kindom
International Monetary Fund, 2009
Note: Table made from pie chart.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Expanding the IMF's Role
However, the crisis is not yet over, and as the world economy
slides into recession the IMF can play an important role in mitigating
the damage, particularly to countries heavily dependent on inflows of
foreign capital that have now diminished or even dried up. The
Short-term Liquidity Facility (SLF) of US$100 billion created by the IMF
in October, with its relaxed lending conditions, is a partial response,
but with limitations both in magnitude and in coverage. Moreover, the
total resources of the IMF, at about US$250 billion, are hardly adequate
to deal with a financial crisis of the current magnitude. Hungary alone,
a country of 10 million people, will absorb US$15 billion.
One can imagine a much bolder version of the IMF, a true lender of
last resort. Since the late 1960s the IMF has had the capacity to create
international money, called SDRs (for Special Drawing Rights, but that
term is not helpful in understanding them). Financial journalists dubbed
them "paper gold," since they represented a functional
substitute for monetary gold, exchangeable among official monetary
authorities and other designated institutions such as the BIS and the
World Bank for national currencies. SDRs were created to help satisfy
the long-run liquidity needs of the world economy. (SDRs are now defined
as a weighted average of four currencies: the US dollar, the euro, the
British pound, and the Japanese yen, so has an exact value that changes
from day to day with market exchange rates among these currencies). They
were issued on only two occasions, in 1970-72 and 1979-81, in total
amount of SDR 21.4 billion (roughly US$32 billion today). With the huge
growth in international reserves, to over US$5 trillion, they now play a
negligible role in provision of international liquidity, and then mainly
for transactions with the IMF itself. But the SDR could become an
important source of liquidity during periods of financial crisis, such
as the present.
The IMF's Articles of Agreement could be amended to allow the
IMF to create SDRs not only to satisfy long-term official demands for
international liquidity, but also to respond quickly to periods of
intense increase in demand for liquidity, with tight terms of reference such that when the period of crisis passed the liquidity would again be
mopped up, i.e. repaid to the IMF. But during the crisis there need be
no limits on the issuance.
Under current arrangements the SDR can only be held by monetary
authorities of countries that are members of the IMF (such as their
central banks) and other designated institutions. Thus to deal with a
market crisis the SDRs would have to be converted into the national
currencies relevant for dealing with the financial crisis, which the
relevant central banks could do.
A more ambitious change would be to allow SDRs to be held by
private financial institutions, or even by any private party. They would
become a kind of global money, at least for large institutions, and
could coexist with national monies, which people would continue to carry
in their pockets.
A compromise proposal was made some years ago by Professor Peter
Kenen of Princeton University, whereby a special clearinghouse would be
established that was allowed to hold SDRs, and commercial banks would be
able to deal with this clearing house in transactions denominated in
SDRs but actually executed in national currencies. This enlargement of
the potential use of the SDR would give the IMF the financial capacity
to deal with crises large in magnitude. Of course it would have to
develop the procedures to use the funds effectively when necessary,
which would require giving appropriate authority to the Executive Board,
which resides in IMF headquarters in Washington; or (with modern
technology) convening as necessary their superiors, ministers of finance
(including the US Treasury Secretary) around the world.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
While the IMF is not suited to be a regulatory agency, it could and
should beef up execution of its periodic surveillance of the
macroeconomic conditions of member countries to include greater focus on
the soundness and potential risks attending the practices of their
financial institutions, and in particular compliance with international
best practice as determined in other fora. Coordination of regulatory
policies would remain in the hands of the various Basel-based
committees.
This proposed change would require amending the IMFs Articles of
Agreement, and this would require parliamentary ratification around the
world. It would thus be too late to rectify the situation in the current
crisis. But it is not too early to think about how to prepare ourselves
to deal effectively, at the global level, with the next major financial
crisis.
RICHARD N. COOPER is the Maurits C. Boas Professor of International
Economics at Harvard University. He has previously worked as the
Chairman of the National Intelligence Council and as the Chairman of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.