Bridging the divide: when policy profits from research.
Summers, Lawrence
In an interview with the Public Broadcasting Service (PBS), you
said, "If one wants to understand why some countries are more
successful and some countries are less successful, the answer lies
overwhelmingly in their own policy choices." Is there a correlation
between nations' integration of academic research into policymaking and their success in the world economy?
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
I would not want to identify successful integration of academic
research as the dominant determinant of a country's success. On the
other hand, there is no question that US prosperity over the last 50
years has had a great deal to do with research that has come out of
universities, whether it is the Massachusetts Institute of Technology
(MIT) and Route 128, Stanford and Silicon Valley, or, in a previous
period, the land-grant colleges. There is enormous potential for
academic research to have a positive impact.
In terms of national policy, countries that have proceeded
thoughtfully have done very well: for example, the job that Mervin King,
a former economics professor, is doing as the head of the British
Central Bank; the crucial role that Domingo Cavallo, an economics
professor, played in Argentine economic reform; or the very influential
work that Stanley Fisher, a former MIT economics professor, has done at
the IMF. All of these are cases where an academic background and
academic knowledge contributed very substantially to successful
outcomes.
The New York Times credited you as being the principal architect of
the Mexican economic recovery following the 1995 Mexican economic
crisis. Could the integration of academic theory and policy have
prevented the Mexican economic crisis of 1995? Did you use theory to
structure Mexico's recovery?
Nobody is going to be able to predict market crises. If a market
crisis is easily predictable, somebody can profit by buying or selling.
It is in the logic of market crises that they are not going to be
completely predictable. Experience with stabilization programs and
experience coming from the vocabulary of economic research was an
enormously valuable thing for me; for President Ernesto Zedillo, who has
a Yale University Ph.D. in economics; and for Mexican Finance Minister
Guillermo Ortiz, who has a Stanford University Ph.D. in economics. I
think our shared vocabulary of economics and shared set of economic
theories were enormously constructive in working through the response to
that crisis. We absolutely did use academic theory to address the
crisis.
You have stated that economic theory has a particularly strong
impact on policymaking. Do you think that other academic fields such as
international relations have a similar influence?
There is no question that what US President John F. Kennedy learned
at Harvard as he wrote his undergraduate thesis Why England Slept was
very important in shaping the approach he took toward Asia and Vietnam.
Henry Kissinger was enormously influenced by his study of Metternich and
the stable order that was created for 100 years by Metternich's
diplomacy. Samantha Power's book A Problem from Hell is serving as
a spur to do more--and yet we are still doing too little--with respect
to Darfur.
Of the Asian financial crisis, you told PBS, "We had a sense
that this was a new phenomenon--that this was probably the way the world
was going to be with markets increasingly interlinked, even if it had
not been the way markets had always been. This is one of the things that
encouraged us to take bolder kinds of responses." Do new situations
and crises lead policymakers to look to academia?
It is always better to be ahead of the curve than to be behind the
curve. The kinds of ideas that were being pursued were very much
affected by economic research. It was a remarkable commentary that I sat
during the Asian financial crisis with Chinese Premier Zhu Rongji in the
same room where Mao received Nixon for the first time, where people had
been executed hundreds of years ago in China. After we talked for a
while, he asked whether I was the same Larry Summers who had been a
professor of economics at Harvard. He started talking in great detail
about the respective views of Professor Joseph Stiglitz of Columbia
University and of Stanley Fisher, Governor of the Bank of Israel, on
movements of interest rates in response to capital outflows. That was a
demonstration that these ideas make a difference.
Another example is the idea that there should be a price for
pollution. It is an idea that was an outrage 35 years ago. Liberals
thought it was a license to pollute, and conservatives thought it was a
fine on good businesses. Today it is accepted as a generally wise thing
to do. The idea of congestion tolls in major cities was once a crazy
idea, and now it is making a very real and large difference in London in
reducing traffic and making it easier for people to get around. In a
daily, weekly or monthly time frame, policy is usually motivated by a
variety of political forces. Over the mid and long term, policymaking
has a great deal to do with ideas.
What is your perspective on the divide between academia and
policymaking?
Much of what academics do is positive analysis. They try to
describe what is, not what should be done. Policymakers have the
challenge of acting. The two fill different roles, but I think they very
much interact with one another.
As US Secretary of the Treasury and chief economist at the World
Bank, did you feel you were either an academic or a policymaker, that
you could not be both?
My primary responsibilities, particularly at the Treasury, were as
a policymaker, but as a policymaker I was very much influenced by what
academics were saying. I worked very hard to try to keep up with the
best thinking.
In your time with the US Treasury and the World Bank, what did you
observe to be the primary factors affecting how academic theory was
incorporated into policy?
Every once in a while, there is an opening. When there is an
opening, people look for the set of ideas that can fill that opening.
The opening can be created in the issue of global warming because the
temperature goes way up one summer; the opening can be created in
foreign policy because of a crisis in a particular country; the opening
can be created because of a particularly forceful expression of an idea.
Most of the time, I do not think research is having an effect, but
research is always there.
At a certain moment the world is ready, and research can make a
very big difference. Sometimes--not always, not often--the transition
from inconceivable to inevitable can be very rapid.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Has there been a memorable instance in which your own theories or
academic suggestions were or were not implemented?
Something I had been concerned with as an academic was the idea of
the inflation of fixed bonds. The idea that there would be bonds that
would preserve purchasing power seemed to be a powerful idea in that it
would give insurance to savers trying to save for their retirement, and
they would not lose out because of inflation. It also seemed to me that
fixed bonds would be very powerful and would give us a market indicator
of inflation expectations by looking at indexed and other bond yields.
That was something I had written on and advocated as a professor along
with many other academic economists. I was proud to push that process
along at the US Treasury and to work to institute that instrument as a
permanent part of the financial environment in the United States and, as
a consequence, in many other countries as well.
Have you had a theory or an opinion as an academic that you were
forced to discard as a policymaker?
As an academic, I would have been for a more aggressive approach to
free trade than was politically feasible during the time I was in
government. I made the arguments, but in the end the administration of
US President Bill Clinton, which had a very good record on trade
overall, did not go quite as far in promoting free trade as I would have
liked simply because of the political forces.
What specific factors prevent academic theory from becoming policy?
Factors include the inability to convince others because the case
is not being made persuasively enough, because policymakers do not know
things that academics know, or because academics are wrong in not seeing
the full particulars of the situation. There have been ideas about which
academics were very enthusiastic that the political process did not
accept, and it turned out to be a good thing that the political process
did not accept those ideas.
Various academic ideas were quite popular for a time--for example,
the idea of a negative income tax to guarantee annual income. It is
probably just as well that this proposal was never accepted by the
political process. There were also various ideas for permanent
wage-price guidelines, permanent income policies that were seen as
attractive ways to control inflation and unemployment in the 1970s, that
were not accepted. We are probably better off that they were not
accepted.
Should policymaking experience be weighed along with academic
accomplishment in selecting and granting tenure to professors?
Being a tenured professor at Harvard or any top university is
ultimately about teaching and scholarship. The university is hugely
enriched by professors who practice, adjunct professors of various
kinds, and lecturers who are not completely on an academic path but have
enormously valuable experience that they can bring to the university. I
suspect that over time we as a university may well want to see more such
people here. At the same time, we will want to keep the main ladder of
hiring through the more traditional teaching and research route.
How have you tried to bridge the divide between academia and
policymaking in initiatives during your tenure as president of Harvard?
Harvard ultimately makes its biggest contributions through its
teaching and its scholarship. We try to identify crucial areas, whether
it is the study of Islam or global health, whether it is the scientific
research in genomics at the Rodale Institute that is so central to the
establishment of a cross-university bioethics program or the
introduction of joint programs between public health schools and the law
school or the business school and the medical school. All of these
things seem to me to be terribly important. The ways in which the
university can best contribute are through its teaching and research. I
think that Harvard makes an enormous contribution in those regards.
Is the separation of academia and policy largely positive or
negative? Are there benefits to this separation?
Researchers are at their best when they are doing research
motivated by truth rather than by a political agenda. A certain measure
of distance is probably a healthy thing. I would not want to see more
academic research brought under the control of policymakers. If research
became staff work for policymakers, it would lose some of its creativity
and vitality.
What is the best way to integrate academic theory and research and
policymaking?
I do not think there is any simple way. The best policymakers will
be following the best thinking. The best universities will be trying to
provide the best thinking on the most important questions. The two will
naturally come together.
LAWRENCE SUMMERS, former US Treasury Secretary and Chief Economist
at the World Bank, is a University Professor at Harvard.