Australian local government amalgamation: a conceptual analysis population size and scale economies in municipal service provision.
Dollery, Brian ; Byrnes, Joel ; Crase, Lin 等
ABSTRACT: A common argument advanced by proponents of Australian
local council amalgamation proposals is that 'bigger is
cheaper' due inter alia to the existence of substantial economies
of scale in local council service provision. This argument typically
asserts that local councils with larger populations can provide
municipal services at lower costs per unit of output than local
authorities with smaller population bases, thereby conflating population
size with the theoretically distinct concept of scale economies. This
short paper examines this argument in the light of standard economic
theory. We conclude that it is fallacious to use population size as a
proxy for scale economies in Australian local government.
1. INTRODUCTION
Since the mid-nineties, several Australian local government
jurisdictions have embarked on ambitious local council amalgamation
programs, notably Victoria, South Australia and New South Wales, with
Queensland presently engaged in a radical forced merger process. A
common premise that 'bigger is better' in local government has
underpinned all these structural change proposals, based largely on the
putative proposition that substantial scale economies existed in local
council service provision (Dollery, Byrnes and Crase, 2008), (2) despite
the paucity of empirical evidence in support of this contention (Byrnes
and Dollery, 2002). An even more unfortunate twist has occurred in the
application of the 'bigger is cheaper' dogma to the
implementation of forced amalgamation programs to actual local councils;
population size has become the proxy for scale economies. Thus state
Departments of Local Government have deliberately designed new
constellations of merged councils on the assumption that larger
populations subsumed greater economies of scale. Greater population size
has thereby become synonymous with increased scale economies.
The conflation of population size with scale economies by state
government policy makers is vividly illustrated in the controversial
2007 Queensland forced amalgamation program. On the 17 April 2007, the
ongoing Size, Shape and Sustainability (SSS) local government reform
process was abruptly abandoned through administrative fiat by the
Queensland state government in favour of a program of forced
amalgamation. Under its Local Government Reform Program, the Queensland
government appointed a Local Government Reform Commission to make
recommendations on compulsory local council mergers by August 2007. The
official case for the rejection of the SSS process was set out in Local
Government Reform: A New Chapter for Local Government in Queensland
(Department of Local Government, Planning, Sport and Recreation
(DLGPS&R)) (2007) on the basis that local councils had not proceeded
speedily enough with the SSS program. The Reform Commission released its
Final Report entitled Report of the Local Government Reform Commission
(State of Queensland (Local Government Reform Commission)) (2007) on 27
July 2007. It recommended that the number of local councils be
compulsorily reduced from 157 to 73 organizations, including the
Brisbane City Council. Almost all of the recommendations of the Reform
Commission were passed into law in the Queensland Parliament on 10
August 2007.
In its Final Report, the Commission deliberately recommended the
amalgamation of councils with small populations into larger units with a
greater mass of people in order to increase the 'size and
strength' of these communities (p.8). The Commission argued the
benefits of council consolidation were fourfold: Economies of scale;
more efficient infrastructure delivery; more skilled staff; and improved
financial governance and standards implementation. With respect to scale
economies, the Commission presented neither conceptual nor theoretical
evidence on either the existence of widespread scale economies in local
government or the presumed relationship between population size and
economies of scale. It simply assumed that amalgamated councils with
larger populations would experience a significant reduction in the
average costs of service provision regardless of demographic
characteristics, the nature of service provision, or any other factors.
In common with its predecessors in other Australian states, the
Queensland Reform Commission thus assumed a monotonic relationship
between population size and the unit costs of service provision
characterized by an increasing returns to scale production function. (3)
According to this view, larger populations necessarily implied lower
average costs and therefore could be perfectly conflated with scale
economies. This short paper seeks to demonstrate that this presumption
is false; population size does not automatically translate into
economies of scale in local government services. Indeed, in principle,
population size need bear no systematic relationship to scale economies
at all.
The paper itself is divided into three main parts. Section 2
provides a synoptic description of the concept of economies of scale in
local government service provision as it is used in economic analysis.
Section 3 considers the relationship between population size and scale
economies within the institutional context of Australian local
government. The paper ends with some brief concluding remarks.
2. ECONOMIES OF SCALE
The nature of production processes carried out in organizations
that create goods and services determines scale economies, size
economies and scope economies (Varian, 1992; Ferguson, 1969). In these
organizations production normally combines various input factors, such
as capital, labour, land, materials and technical knowledge, in varying
proportions to a technologically defined process that produces single or
multiple goods and services. In economic theory, the relationships
between input factors and outputs are characterized by production
functions. This technique has yielded a classification system, expressed
in terms of returns to scale, for different types of relationships
between inputs and outputs. In essence, returns to scale refers to how
output reacts to increases or decreases in all inputs taken together.
For instance, if all inputs are doubled, then returns to scale will
indicate whether output will increase in the same proportion (i.e.
constant returns to scale), in greater proportion (i.e. increasing
returns to scale), or in smaller proportion (i.e. decreasing returns to
scale). In general, economic theory holds that as the physical scale of
production increases, production processes will first exhibit increasing
returns to scale, followed by constant returns to scale, and finally by
decreasing returns to scale. By allowing all inputs to increase, even
inputs such as physical plant and buildings, the concept of returns to
scale deliberately assumes that the passage of time involved is
sufficiently extensive to allow developments like these to occur. In
theoretical terms, this is known as the long-run and must be
distinguished from the short-run in economic jargon which allows the use
of only some inputs to increase.
In principle, two countervailing influences affect the nature of
returns to scale. In the first place, as production increases this
allows for greater specialisation in the use of input factors thereby
raising productivity, which leads in turn to increasing returns to
scale. Secondly, difficulties in adequately managing ever larger
production mount as production rises, which serve to decrease factor
productivity and induce decreasing returns to scale. Eventually the
complexities associated with scale will negate the gains from factor
specialization; this inevitably results in decreasing returns to scale.
Whereas returns to scale refer to the physical relationship between
factor inputs and outputs, economies of scale transform this
relationship into monetary values. In other words, increasing returns to
scale translates into increasing economies of scale (i.e. falling
average costs), constant returns to scale into constant economies of
scale (i.e. constant average costs), and decreasing returns to scale
into diseconomies of scale (i.e. rising average costs). In formal terms,
economies of scale occur where an increase in output reduces the unit
cost of output. If cost is represented by a cost function (C) that
depends on the quantity of output (Q), then scale economies is given by
C(Q1 + Q2, 0 < C(Q1, 0) + C(Q2), 0).
In the local government context, a useful way of depicting returns
to scale is provided in Figure 1 below:
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 1 shows a variable returns to scale production function AA
alongside line BB representing constant returns to scale. Segment 1-2 of
AA illustrates increasing returns (or falling unit costs), segment 2-3
constant returns (constant average cost), and segment 3-4 decreasing
returns (rising unit costs). It must be stressed that in a complex
organisation, like a local council, providing a wide range of goods and
services, each output will have its own production function akin to AA
with its own unique characteristics since it will embody its own
combination of physical and human input factors. This means that ranges
1-2, 23 and 3-4 will differ for each good and service. In other words,
scale economies will not be uniform across the range of services
provided by an individual Australian council. It should also be added
that in real-world local government, input combinations will not
typically occur along the production function AA since a degree of
technical inefficiency almost always occurs; that is, the most
economically efficient level of inputs is not always employed to produce
services.
Dollery and Fleming (2006, p.274) have considered economies of
scale in the Australian municipal milieu. They argued that 'if
councils each produce their own services and there are substantial
aggregate economies of scale, then it follows that a system of numerous
small municipalities will result in higher expenditures for the same
level and composition of output than a system of fewer larger
councils'. But particular scale characteristics pertain to specific
services. It thus follows that 'the most efficient level of
production will depend on the type of service in question', which
implies that 'where local government produces a range of different
services, each with its own unique production characteristics, no single
size of government will be able to produce all services at the minimum
possible cost for each service'. This argument echoes
Sancton's (2000, p.74) conclusion that 'there is no
functionally optimal size for municipal governments because different
municipal activities have quite different optimal areas'.
According to Dollery and Fleming (2006, p.274), 'in general,
labour-intensive, customer-orientated services, such as municipal
rangers, health inspectors, etc., generate few scale economies because
their idiosyncratic nature means that an increased volume of services
requires a correspondingly larger number of employees'. In
contrast, 'capital-intensive services, like sewage disposal and
domestic water supply, usually yield significant economies of scale
since the cost of fixed assets can be spread across a greater number of
homes'. In terms of local government amalgamation policy,
'consolidation of councils into one larger council can thus reap
scale economies through outcomes such as higher utilization rates of
fixed assets owned by the council, greater opportunity to exploit the
benefits of specialization, and discounted bulk-purchasing of
inputs'. However, 'scale diseconomies can occur when
enlargement of the boundary of a council makes it more difficult to
manage its activities'. Moreover, 'management problems
typically proliferate when amalgamation breaks the close links between
small councils and their residents'.
Dollery and Fleming (2006, p.275) draw two main implications from
their analysis. Firstly, 'whether scale economies or scale
diseconomies exist depends on the nature of the municipal service in
question and it is a moot point whether aggregate economies or
diseconomies characterize council service activities as a whole
(especially since other factors potentially related to organizational
size, like economies of scope, are simultaneously at play)'. This
conclusion is reinforced when the shift in the composition of Australian
local government service provision over the past two decades is taken
into account (Dollery, Wallis and Allan, 2006). Over this period, local
councils in all Australian local government jurisdictions have moved
from relatively capital-intensive 'services to property' to
comparatively labour-intensive 'services to people'. Thus, the
impact of scale economies on production costs has steadily fallen.
Secondly, Dollery and Fleming (2006, p.275) contend that since 'the
existence and magnitude of scale economies and scale diseconomies
depends on the particular municipal service under consideration',
it follows that 'the ability of small councils to accrue scale
economies by purchasing services with substantial scale economies from
other service producers or to enter into "resource-sharing"
arrangements with neighbouring local authorities in any event removes
much of the force of the 'bigger is cheaper' argument'.
Scale economies are conceptually distinct from size economies;
while scale economies hold input proportions constant as output expands,
economies of size permit input proportions to change as output increases
(Deller, Chicoine and Walzer, 1998). In practice, whereas this
distinction often makes little real difference, it does sometimes
matter. Dollery and Fleming (2006, p. 275) provide a useful illustrative
example:
For instance, suppose several local authorities combine their
administrative functions, thereby saving some of the costs incurred
by individual councils producing the same core outputs but each
carrying out their own administrative functions. The inputs into
administrative functions are likely to be applied in proportions
different from those used to provide core council services. It is
likely that clerical inputs would have a smaller cost share,
changing the overall proportions of input use, when councils
combine their administrative functions. On the other hand, scale
economies achieved through the discounted bulk-purchasing of inputs
by a consolidated group of councils might entail negligible changes
in cost shares among inputs.
3. POPULATION SIZE AND SCALE ECONOMIES
As we have seen, the rationale for Australian local government
amalgamations programs invariably rests on claims that inter alia
'bigger is cheaper' on grounds that substantial economies of
scale exist in local government service provision. The translation of
this theoretical presumption into policy practice always involves the
conflation of population size with council size. Policy makers thus
merge small spatially adjacent local authorities into bigger
geographical entities with larger population masses in order to reap
assumed scale economies in service provision.
Quite apart from the conceptual incoherence of this assumption
(Dollery and Fleming, 2006), and the lack of empirical support for
economies of scale in Australian local government service provision
(Byrnes and Dollery, 2002), several additional arguments can be advanced
to attack the conflation of scale economies with population size. (4) In
the first place, the notion that population can be employed as a measure
of scale carries the implicit presumption that population size and
service output are very closely positively correlated. Indeed, this
presumption formed the basis for the only and very influential study by
Soul (2000) on the topic in Australia that has frequently been cited by
advocates of amalgamation. In his doctoral thesis, Stephen Soul (2000)
examined the effect of council size (as measured by population) on gross
expenditure per capita. He concluded that increasing population yields a
lower level of gross expenditure per capita up to a council size
somewhere between 100,000 and 316,000 people, at which point 'scale
diseconomies' begin.
It is easy to demonstrate that population size cannot service as a
satisfactory proxy for service output. For instance, in a local
government area with a given population, many other
'non-discretionary' factors can influence the aggregate costs
of service provision, apart from the number of residents (Worthington
and Dollery, 2002). In the physical realm, topography, precipitation,
soil type, temperature range, and so forth, will all obviously affect
the costs of service provision, with population held constant. After
all, in a hilly, rainy and climatically extreme local council
jurisdiction, roads, sewerage systems, stormwater drains and other
physical local government infrastructure will be more expensive to
provide per capita than in its flat, dry and temperate counterpart with
the same population. Similarly, the demographic characteristics of a
given municipal population size can vary widely. The age profile of the
community, especially the numbers of very young and elderly people,
seasonal fluctuations in the composition of residents, particularly in
areas with residential education facilities, will have pronounced
effects on the 'services to people' dimension of local
government output. Much the same applies to socioeconomic factors. For
example, the level and distribution of income and wealth in the
community will influence the degree of commercial development, the
nature of housing, the need for public amenities, and the like, play a
pivotal role in determining the cost of service provision (Dollery,
Byrnes and Crase, 2007).
Secondly, assuming that population size accurately proxies service
output ignores considerations of service quality. Service quality in
turn has an obvious and decisive influence on the costs of service
provision. Although state and territory legislatures in all Australian
local government jurisdictions almost always mandate minimum uniform
standards in local government service provision (Worthington and
Dollery, 2001), local councils can and frequently do provide services
that exceed these minimum levels. Street lighting, coverage by paved
sidewalks, public park size and amenity quality, sports facilities,
amongst a myriad of typical municipal services, vary widely between
local government areas within the same local government jurisdiction.
This has major effects on the costs of service provision that are
completely independent of population size. Furthermore, the cost
incurred to meet a given standard (such as potable water purity
standards) may differ substantially from council to council as a result
of exogenous influences.
Finally, Oates' (1972) famous decentralisation theorem
demonstrated conclusively that the efficient provision of services by
the public sector requires that decision-making be made by the level of
government 'closest' to the people who consume these services,
provided that spatial differences in tastes occur. Accordingly, the
composition and quality of local services should be decided by local
councils to the greatest extent possible to reflect local preferences.
In political science, this is sometimes referred to as the subsidiarity principle. Worthington and Dollery (2001) have shown that Australian
local government is characterised by immense diversity. It is thus not
surprising that, despite the imposition of uniform standards by state
governments in many areas of service provision, local councils
nonetheless often modify the mix of circumstances to meet local demands
from the local community. In other words, local government policy is an
important determinant of local service provision.
The nature of local preferences (as expressed through local council
policy) will obviously affect the structure of service provision and
thereby the cost of service provision. For instance, in many
crime-ridden Australian local government jurisdictions, local councils
have responded to community concern by installing security cameras,
bright lighting, etc., in shopping districts and other public precincts.
Moreover, in this respect, the impact of local council policy will be
independent of population size. This yet again demonstrates that
population size cannot accurately proxy local government output.
4. CONCLUSION
Australian local government policy makers have always been
historically wedded to the idea that 'bigger is cheaper' in
local council service provision. This assumption has lead to structural
reform policies aimed at the amalgamation of small, adjacent local
councils into larger local government entities in the belief that the
average costs service provision would fall due inter alia to economies
of scale contingent on bigger councils. In the implementation of these
mergers initiatives, policy makers invariably conflate population size
with service provision in the design of new local government areas on
grounds that population size accurately proxies the magnitude of local
goods and services delivered. This sequence of afactual presumption and
policy formulation is clearly illustrated in the work of the Queensland
Local Government Reform Commission and its Final Report entitled Report
of the Local Government Reform Commission (State of Queensland: Local
Government Reform Commission) (2007).
In this paper, we have argued that there are neither theoretical
foundations nor empirical evidence to support the view that substantial
scale economies exist in Australian local government service provision.
Indeed, since different production processes are used to generate
different services, there is a strong a priori presumption that that no
uniform pattern of economies of scale will exist across the broad range
of services offered.
In addition, we have argued that it is fallacious to employ
population size as a measure of service output. Three broad reasons were
advanced in support of this argument: Variations in the
'non-discretionary' environments of different councils;
differences in service quality; and variations in content of local
service provision by local councils. For these reasons, population size
cannot accurately proxy either physical service output or the costs of
service provision and therefore cannot correlate perfectly with the
costs of service provision.
From a policy perspective, the major implication of this paper is
that population size should not be employed as the basis for the
amalgamation of small councils into larger single entities. At a broader
level, structural reform in local government should aim at regional
service provision for this municipal services marked by substantial
scale economies carried out through regional organizations of councils,
alliances of geographical adjacent councils, and other similar models of
council cooperation, but leave those services without economies of scale
at the local level (Dollery, Crase and Johnson, 2006).
REFERENCES
Boyne, G. A. (1995) Population Size and Economies of Scale in Local
Government. Policy and Politics, 23(3), pp. 213-222.
Byrnes, J. D. and Dollery, B. E. (2002) Do Economies of Scale Exist
in Australian Local Government? A Review of the Research Evidence. Urban
Policy and Research, 20(4), pp. 391-414.
Department of Local Government, Planning, Sport and Recreation
(DLGPS&R) (2007) Local Government Reform: A New Chapter for Local
Government in Queensland, DLGPS&R: Brisbane.
Deller, S. C, Chicoine, D. L. and Walzer, N. (1988) Economies of
Size and Scope in Rural Low-volume Roads. Review of Economics and
Statistics, 70(2), pp. 459-465.
Dollery, B. E., Byrnes, J. D. and Crase, L. (2007) Too Tough A Nut:
Determining Financial Sustainability in Australian Local Government.
Australasian Journal of Regional Studies, 13(2), pp. 110-132.
Dollery, B. E., Byrnes, J. and Crase, L (2008) A Note on Structural
Reform in Australian Local Government. Australian Journal of Political
Science (forthcoming).
Dollery, B. E., Crase, L. and Johnson, A. (2006) Australian Local
Government Economics. UNSW Press: Sydney.
Dollery, B. E. and Fleming, E. (2006). A Conceptual Note on Scale
Economies, Size Economies and Scope Economies in Australian Local
Government. Urban Policy and Research, 24(2), pp. 271-282.
Dollery, B. E. and Soul, S. (2000) An Analysis of the Criteria Used
by Australian Local Government Amalgamation Inquiries Between 1960 and
1992. Regional Policy and Practice, 9(2), pp. 41-52.
Dollery, B. E., Wallis, J. L. and Allan, P. (2006) The Debate That
Had to Happen But Never Did: The Changing Role of Australian Local
Government. Australian Journal of Political Science, 41(4), pp. 553-567.
Ferguson, C. E. (1969) The Neoclassical Theory of Production and
Distribution. Cambridge University Press: London.
Oates, W. E. (1972) Fiscal Federalism. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich:
New York.
Sancton, A. (2000) Merger Mania. McGill-Queens University Press:
Montreal.
Soul, S. (2000) Population Size and Economic and Political
Performance of Local Government Jurisdiction. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis,
Southern Cross University: Lismore.
State of Queensland (Local Government Reform Commission) (2007)
Report of the Local Government Reform Commission. State of Queensland:
Brisbane.
Varian, H. (1992) Microeconomic Analysis. Norton: New York.
Worthington, A. C. and Dollery, B. E. (2001) Diversity in
Australian Local Government: The Case Against the Imposition of National
Uniform Standards. International Review of Public Administration, 6(1),
pp. 49-58.
Worthington, A. C. and Dollery, B. E. (2002) Incorporating
Contextual Information in Public Sector Efficiency Analyses: A
Comparative Study of NSW Local Government. Applied Economics, 34(1), pp.
453-464.
(1) The authors thank two anonymous referees for helpful comments
on an earlier draft of the paper. Brian Dollery would like to
acknowledge the financial support provided by Australian Research
Council Discovery Grant DP070520.
(2) Dollery and Soul (2000) have shown that the notion that
substantial scale economies exist in local government economies has been
used by numerous state-based inquiries into local government
amalgamation dating back at least to 1960 and thus predating the
Victorian, South Australian, New South Wales and Queensland episodes.
(3) Furthermore, the costs associated with diseconomies of scale
were simply not acknowledged by the authors.
(4) Boyne (1995) has advanced analogous arguments against the use
of population size as a proxy for British local government. Given the
substantial institutional differences between the Australian and British
local government systems, some of his observations cannot be directly
applied to the Australian case.
Brian Dollery
Centre for Local Government, University of New England, Armidale
NSW 2351.
Joel Byrnes
Centre for Local Government, University of New England, Armidale
NSW 2351.
Lin Crase
School of Business, La Trobe University, Wodonga VIC 3689.