Fiscal contraction and economic expansion: the 2013 sequester and post-World War II spending cuts.
Taylor, Jason E. ; Klingler, Ronald L.
Proposals for government spending cuts are almost always
accompanied by doomsday predictions from Keynesian-influenced
economists. For example, Richard K. Vedder documents that when the
Second World War ended in 1945, Keynesians loudly declared that if
government spending declined, the economy would return to the
Depression-era conditions of the 1930s (Vedder and Gallaway 1991, 1998;
Taylor and Vedder 2010). In fact, the government's role in the U.S.
economy declined dramatically as government spending went from 41.8
percent of GDP in 1945 to only 17.9 percent in 1946. Furthermore, over 9
million military personnel returned to civilian economic life and
millions of civilian jobs related to the war effort disappeared. In
anticipation of these cuts, the consensus forecast was that the
unemployment rate would return to die double-digit numbers of the 1930s.
Yet, despite the large government contraction, unemployment was less
than 2.3 million, or a rate of 3.9 percent, in 1946, and 2.6 million, or
a rate of 4.4 percent, in 1947--achieving "full employment,"
as defined by economists. As Taylor and Vedder (2010: 6) note, "The
'Depression of 1946' may be one of the most widely predicted
events that never happened in American history."
A similar episode occurred in 2012 and 2013 when government
spending cuts associated with the Budget Control Act (BCA) of 2011 and
the sequester were implemented. It was widely predicted that if the
sequester's across-the-board cuts in federal spending were
executed, the economy would be thrown back into those conditions seen in
the Great Recession of 2007-09, or worse. Yet, as was the case in 1946,
significant cuts occurred despite these dire warnings. Nominal
government spending fell in both 2012 and 2013--the first time that
government spending had fallen two years in a row since the 1950s. Once
again the dire predictions did not come to pass. Monthly employment
numbers grew at a faster rate after the spending cuts than they had
prior to them, and GDP grew at around the same pace pre- and postcuts.
The "sequester-induced contraction of 2013," which was a major
part of the ominous sounding "fiscal cliff' over which the
country was supposedly going to topple, was--like the post-WWII
government contraction--another of the most widely predicted events in
U.S. history to never happen. This paper compares these two episodes and
looks for policy lessons.
World War II Spending Cuts: Fear of the Depression's Return
By the outbreak of war in Europe in late 1939, President Franklin
Roosevelt's New Deal economic programs had been in place for nearly
seven years with only limited success at ending the Great Depression.
While unemployment was lower than it was in 1933, many contemporaries
viewed this reduction as being the product of government relief jobs
rather than a bona fide, permanent recovery. Government employment via
Depression-era agencies like the Works Progress Administration, it
appeared to some, would have to remain part of the economic landscape
indefinitely. In fact, Bateman and Taylor (2003) show that this fear
caused long-term economic goals to continue to be a large part of the
objectives of New Deal "alphabet agencies" even after the
nation entered the Second World War.
Between 1942 and mid-1945, the United States was essentially a
command economy and unemployment practically disappeared. (1) The
Controlled Materials Flan, introduced in November 1942, was created and
operated inside the War Production Board to harness the production
capacity of the nation for military purposes. The Office of Price
Administration rationed or restricted consumer durables like automobiles
and office chairs with metal frames. Labor was also commandeered or
otherwise directed by the federal government into military purposes. The
Selective Service registered and drafted citizens into the military,
while the Employment Service and the War Manpower Commission used
incentives to mobilize and employ labor into jobs of highest military
priority. At its peak, the war effort supported 45 percent of the
nation's civilian labor supply, while another 12 million citizens,
representing around 18 percent of the total (military plus civilian)
labor force, were employed directly by the military (U.S. Bureau of the
Budget 1946). The unemployment rate fell below 2 percent as the United
States went from a dramatic labor surplus in the 1930s to a labor
shortage during the war.
In light of all this, it is easy to understand why policymakers so
feared that a rapid transition from the command-oriented economy
described above to a market-oriented one following the war would bring
back high unemployment. If the war ended the Depression, what would the
end of the war bring? As the war ended after the Japanese surrender in
mid-August 1945, the National Resource Planning Board predicted that
over the next year, unemployment would rise to between eight and nine
million, representing 12 to 14 percent of the labor force. John Snyder,
director of the Office of War Mobilization and Reconversion, submitted a
report in which he forecast that eight million people would be
unemployed by the spring of 1946 (U.S. Office of War Mobilization and
Reconversion 1945: 5). The press followed suit as the September 1, 1945,
issue of Business Week predicted that unemployment would peak
"closer to 9,000,000 than 8,000,000." (2) These predictions
were relatively optimistic compared to some others. Leo Cherne of the
Research Institute of America and Boris Shishkin, an economist for the
American Federation of Labor, predicted 19 and 20 million unemployed,
respectively, which would have translated to an unemployment rate around
35 percent (Ballard 1983: 17-18).
Even in the face of these dire warnings, within six weeks of the
Japanese surrender, the Controlled Materials Plan was, with a few
exceptions, ended so that resource allocation was once again left to die
private sector. Furthermore, Ballard (1983:135) notes that by the end of
1945, 80 percent of all war contracts had been settled. Despite the
massive decrease in government production and the discharge of over 10
million men and women, who had been employed directly by the military
either as soldiers or civilian workers, into the private sector, the
postwar unemployment problem did not materialize. Table 1, which
provides key labor force and employment data for 1939 to 1950, shows
that as the government withdrew, the private sector grew. Vedder and
Callaway (1993: 171) refer to this as a "classic case of
'reverse crowding out.'" The smooth transition of labor
resources from government-directed to market-directed production was
viewed as a miraculous event. Vedder and Gallaway (1993: 158) write,
"We know of no other episode in American economic history tiiat
more clearly illustrates several neoclassical and Austrian economic
insights than" the postwar transition.
The Post-Great Recession Era and the Government Spending Sequester
In 2008, the federal government began to take extraordinary steps
in an effort to combat the "Great Recession." President George
W. Bush signed the Keynesian-oriented, $152 billion Economic Stimulus
Act of 2008, which sent checks to U.S. households in hopes that the
country could spend its way out of the downturn. In 2009, President
Barack Obama outdid the Bush stimulus by more than a factor of five with
the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act--an $831 billion stimulus
consisting of tax rebate checks, infrastructure spending, and smaller
amounts of spending on health, education, and renewable energy, among
other categories. The Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization
and Job Creation Act of 2010 brought another $916.8 billion in stimulus
by prolonging the Bush tax cuts, cutting payroll taxes, and extending
unemployment coverage. The Middle Class Tax Relief and Job Creation Act
of 2012 extended the payroll tax cut provisions, which was said to
create another $167.6 billion in stimulus. Of course, it could be argued
that extending tax reductions already in place is not true stimulus so
much as an avoidance of contractionary policy. All told, however, the
major and minor stimulus legislation from 2008 to 2012 amounted to over
$2 trillion in new federal spending and tax rates below what they would
otherwise have been (Firey 2012).
In light of these actions, the federal budget deficit averaged
nearly $1.3 trillion between 2009 and 2012, adding over $5 trillion to
the national debt in just four years (U.S. Office of Management and
Budget 2014a). Given this quick buildup, the government had to raise its
authorized debt ceiling or face default. As it happens, the government
actually hit this ceiling in May 2011, but die Treasury was able to
employ some extraordinary measures to avoid an immediate crunch. The
stated deadline at which die United States would default on its debt
payments unless Congress raised the debt ceiling was August 2, 2011.
Republicans, who had won control of the House of Representatives in
2010, insisted that any increase in the debt ceiling be accompanied by
spending cuts. Representative William Shuster declared, "We are in
a spending-driven debt crisis. Washington is spending money it
doesn't have, and it's leaving the American people, our
children and our grandchildren, with the tab." (3) After a long
standoff, on August 2, the Budget Control Act of 2011 was passed. The
BCA granted an immediate increase of the debt ceiling by $400 billion,
and another $500 billion would be added to the debt ceiling in September
unless it was explicitly disapproved by Congress. The president could
further request the debt ceiling be raised another $1.2-$1.5 trillion in
2012. In exchange for the $900 billion increase in the debt ceiling,
federal spending had to be cut by $917 billion over the next decade, and
the first installment of these cuts had to begin in the 2012 fiscal
year. Furthermore, a new committee, the Joint Select Committee on
Deficit Reduction, better known as the "supercommittee," would
be created with the task of identifying and proposing $1.5 trillion in
deficit reduction measures by November 23, 2011. The committee's
recommendation would go to Congress, without any amendments, for an
up-or-down vote no later than December 23, 2011.
Importantly, Congress was strongly incentivized to vote in favor of
the committee's proposed deficit reduction measures because a
"trigger" mechanism was included in the BCA, which stated that
if the $1.5 trillion in deficit reduction was not passed by December 23,
2011, $1.2 trillion in automatic, largely across-the-board spending cuts
would go into effect, in exchange for an additional $1.2 trillion
increase in the debt ceiling. This so-called "sequestration"
would apply to any nonexempt account of the federal government and would
be split evenly between defense and nondefense discretionary spending.
The legislation went on to list the various caps in new spending that
would be allowed for different government accounts. If caps were
exceeded, sequestration would occur to bring spending down to the cap.
The trigger was not set to go off until January 2013--conveniently after
the fall 2012 elections--at which point $110 billion of automatic
spending cuts would be implemented.
The supercommittee, which consisted of six Democrats and six
Republicans and was co-chaired by Republican Jeb Hensarling and Democrat
Patty Murray, announced on November 21, 2011, that "After months of
hard work and intense deliberations, we have come to the conclusion
today that it will not be possible to make any bipartisan agreement
available to the public before the committee's deadline"
(Joint Select Committee on Deficit Reduction 2011). With no
recommendation for Congress to vote upon, the automatic cuts of the
sequester would be enacted starting January 2, 2013.
The sequester's start date happened to coincide with several
other "contractionary" fiscal policy measures. Among them was
the scheduled expiration of the marginal tax rate cuts put in place in
2001 and 2003 under Bush. While these were initially to expire in 2010,
they were temporarily extended by Obama's aforementioned 2010
stimulus. Additionally, a 2 percent reduction in the payroll (Social
Security) tax was set to expire on January 1, 2013, as were extended
unemployment benefits. The Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT) was also
scheduled to revert back to its 2000 tax year levels. The simultaneous
timing of all these tax increases and spending cuts became known as the
"fiscal cliff'--this ominous name coming from Ben Bernanke,
then chairman of the Federal Reserve (Kurtz 2012).
In early June 2012, Representative Gerry Connolly, a Democrat,
shamed the Republicans for not working with his party, saying that
failure to act would bring "economic calamity [and] will send
America back into a recession." (4) The lack of a plan to tackle
the spending cuts gained prominence as the 2012 presidential election
neared. In response to President Obama's declaration that he would
veto any measures that would avoid sequestration and the fiscal cliff
that were not to his liking, Republican presidential nominee Mitt Romney
said Obama's "approach would let our economy sink into
recession for the sake of pursuing job-killing tax increases"
(Politi 2012).
Obama won re-election in November 2012, at which point less than
two months remained before the nation was due to plunge over the fiscal
cliff. Bernanke urged Congress to make progress in solving the looming
crises, saying, "It will be critical that fiscal policy makers come
together soon to achieve longer-term fiscal sustainability, without
adopting policies that could derail the ongoing recovery" (Bernanke
2012). The parameters of the debate were simple. Republicans wanted
deficit reduction through spending cuts while Obama and the Democrats
wanted to achieve deficit reduction by raising taxes on the wealthiest 2
percent of taxpayers. When Obama delivered his opening offer to the
Republicans in the negotiations over avoiding the fiscal cliff--an offer
that included $1.6 trillion of tax increases on the rich and very little
in the way of spending cuts--Republican Speaker of the House John
Boehner said, "Listen, this is not a game. Jobs are on the line.
The American economy is on the line" (Burlij and Polantz 2012).
Republican Congressman Joe Wilson insisted that Democrats and
Republicans had to negotiate a settlement to avoid the sequester:
"This important issue must be addressed [before it] devastates
national security and destroys 700,000 jobs." (5) Democratic
Senator Bill Nelson of Florida insisted that all that needed to be done
was to "recognize that the President won [the election], produce
revenue with the upper 2 percent paying a little more, and eliminate
sequestration." (6)
The Senate and the House passed the American Taxpayer Relief Act
(ATRA) of 2012 on January 1,2013, and President Obama signed die bill
into law die next day, dius averting at least some of the fiscal cliff.
The two primary issues addressed in the legislation were the expiration
of the Bush tax cuts and the coming sequestration. The ATRA made the
marginal income tax cuts of 2001 and 2003 permanent for all but the top
2 percent of taxpayers, who saw their marginal rate rise from 35 to 39.6
percent. Second, ATRA delayed the implementation of the sequester until
March 1, 2013, in hopes that an agreement might be reached that could
replace the blunt, across-the-board approach of the sequester with a
program of more targeted cuts. Congressional Budget Office (CBO)
Director Rudolph Penner noted that ATRA had "reduced the
probability of recession quite a bit," but that Congress and the
White House "gave us a New Year's Eve present of another cliff
in two months" (Sahadi 2013).
Predictions of Doom if Sequester Deal Not Reached
In the first few weeks of 2013, estimates of the impact of the
sequester varied, though most of them were highly negative in outlook.
Third Way published projections that claimed that by the end of 2014,
"the U.S. economy will provide 1.9 million fewer jobs ... the pain
will reach all states and all sectors, most deeply affecting public
investments" (Brown 2013). CBO said that assuming the sequester
occurs, "economic activity will expand slowly this year [2013],
with real GDP growing by just 1.4 percent." The fourth quarter
unemployment rate in 2013 was predicted by tire CBO to rise to 8
percent, from its level of 7.5 percent at the time (Congressional Budget
Office 2013). On February 13, 2013, the day the CBO report was released,
Director Douglas Elmendorf testified before Congress that real GDP
growth "would increase 1.5 percentage points faster were it not for
fiscal tightening" (Elmendorf 2013). Janet Yellen, then
vice-chairwoman of the Federal Reserve, also expressed displeasure with
the fiscal tightening: "Discretionary fiscal policy hasn't
been much of a tailwind during this recovery [but instead] has actually
acted to restrain the recovery.... I expect that discretionary fiscal
policy will continue to be a headwind for the recovery for some
time" (Yellen 2013). Paul Knigman highlighted studies predicting
that the economy would lose 700,000 jobs in 2013 due to the sequester,
prompting him to argue that "we should be spending more, not less,
until we're close to full employment; the sequester is exactly what
the doctor didn't order" (Krugman 2013).
Still, not all commentary on the coming sequester was grave. Reason
magazine editor-in-chief Matt Welch wrote that "taxpayers
shouldn't be fearing the forced spending cuts, they should be
fearing that the cuts don't go nearly far enough" (Welch
2013). The Wall Street Journal (2013) published an opinion piece
claiming: "The sequester will help the economy by leaving more
capital for private investment.... From 1992-2000 Democrat Bill Clinton
and (after 1994) a Republican Congress oversaw budgets that cut federal
outlays to 18.2 percent from 22.1 percent of GDP. These were years of
rapid growth in production and incomes."
In the political sphere, the rhetoric surrounding the sequester
drowned out almost every other issue of the day. President Obama
characterized the cuts as being particularly harmful to the middle
class, and in one of his weekly YouTube addresses said, "It's
important to understand that, while not everyone will feel the pain of
these cuts right away, the pain will be real.... Economists estimate
they could eventually cost us more than 750,000 jobs and slow our
economy by over one-half of one percent" (White House 2013). Those
dire claims were echoed by Congress as well. Representative Dan Kildee
lambasted Republicans, saying that they were "willing to pink-slip
750,000 American workers just to protect billions of dollars in handouts
for ... five big oil companies."' One week later, Democratic
Senator Barbara Boxer wondered how we arrived at "a place where we
are having mindless, across-the-board cuts in spending with absolutely
no thought." (8) Many Republicans also expressed disgust with the
nontargeted nature of the sequester. Speaker John Boehner called the
sequester "an ugly and dangerous way" to achieve the necessary
spending cuts (Boehner 2013).
This time there was no 11th hour agreement. On March 1, 2013, $85
billion of federal spending was sequestered. The Office of Management
and Budget (OMB) estimated that sequestration would require a 7.8
percent cut in nonexempt defense spending; a 5 percent cut in nonexempt,
nondefense funding; and a 2 percent cut in Medicare. Furthermore,
because these cuts had to be achieved in just seven months (prior to the
close of the fiscal year on September 30), the effective reduction was
approximately 13 percent for defense and 9 percent for nondefense
programs. In his cover letter to the speaker of the house announcing
sequestration, OMB Deputy Director Jeffrey Zients chastised Republicans
for creating such a doomsday device and not having the foresight to
avoid its activation, writing that "sequestration is a blunt and
indiscriminant instrument. It was never intended to be implemented and
does not represent a responsible way for our Nation to achieve deficit
reduction" (U.S. Office of Management and Budget 2014b).
Postsequester Data
Were the dire predictions of economic Armageddon correct? As noted
earlier, federal spending fell in nominal terms in both 2012 and
2013--the first time since the end of the Korean War that spending fell
two years in a row. Spending did rise a bit in fiscal year 2014. For the
purposes of this study, we will focus on the movement of key economic
variables in the 18 months either side of the sequester's
implementation.
In October 2014, the unemployment rate was 5.9 percent compared to
a level of 7.5 percent in April 2013 when the sequester was implemented.
The decline of 1.6 percentage points in 18 months is actually larger
than the decline during the prior 18 months-- November 2011 to April
2013--when it fell from 8.6 to 7.5 percent. In comparison with the
CBO's projections of a rate of 8 percent at die end of 2013,
unemployment actually ended 2013 at 6.7 percent. Figure 1 shows the
unemployment rate between 2008 and 2014, highlighting the dates of the
passage of the Budget Control Act and the implementation of the
sequester.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Examinations of quarterly GDP growth also show no signs of a
sequester-induced slowdown. The economy grew at only 0.1 percent in the
fourth quarter of 2012--the final quarter before the sequester took
effect. Growth was 1.1 percent in the first quarter of 2013--the
sequester took effect two-thirds of the way through this quarter. Growth
then accelerated in the immediate postsequester quarters to 2.5, 4.1,
and 2.6 percent--and real GDP growth for 2013 was 1.9 percent, about
half a percentage point higher than what the CBO had predicted it would
be in light of the sequester.
GDP tumbled 2.1 percent in the first quarter of 2014, despite the
fact that labor force participation was up from the previous quarter,
while the average monthly unemployment rate was lower. Clearly the
decline was not caused by fiscal contraction, as federal spending
actually rose 0.6 percent during the quarter after falling by an average
of 6.1 percent during the prior four quarters. Many have blamed that low
GDP growth number on a very harsh winter. The drop could also have been
caused in part by the Federal Reserve announcement in December 2013 that
it was going to reduce the size of its asset purchases, and the
subsequent 1,000 point drop in the Dow Jones Industrial Average over the
following month. Still, the second and third quarters of 2014
experienced impressive growth rates of 4.6 and 3.5 percent,
respectively, so that die notion that the first quarter contraction was
caused by die sequester does not seem viable.
Industrial production, shown in Figure 2, also continued to climb
unabated by the sequester. In die 18 months prior to the sequester, from
September 2011 until March 2013, the industrial production index grew by
5.5 percent; in the following 18 months, from the sequester until
September 2014, it grew by 5.6 percent.
In the months leading up to the implementation of the sequester, it
was suggested that hundreds of thousands, or even millions of government
workers would lose their livelihood. In fact, according to the
Government Accountability Office, only one government employee, who was
employed by the Department of Justice, lost his job as a result of the
sequester (U.S. Government Accountability Office 2014). There were, of
course, furloughs of around 770,000 employees from various government
agencies. But while many predicted that these could go on for weeks,
none of the furloughs actually lasted more than six days.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
By mid-2013, the media began to report how wrong politicians'
predictions just a few months earlier had been. Washington Post
reporters Fahrenthold and Rein (2013) listed 48 dire predictions about
the sequester's impact, such as long waits in airport security and
border crossings and 600,000 low-income Americans being denied federal
food aid. Less than a quarter of these predictions came to pass. In most
cases, agencies found ways to make things work with less by moving
resources around. For example, the authors note that the U.S. Geological
Survey said that the sequester would require them to shut off 350 gauges
used to predict impending floods. In fact, only 90 were shut off as the
agency cut other budget items like conference expenses; it sent only 350
of its scientists to conferences in 2013 as opposed to the 469 it had
sent the year prior. Similarly, Fahrenthold and Rein note that the U.S.
Park Police said all of its officers would have to be furloughed for 12
days should the sequester occur. In fact, the National Park Service
found $4 million in savings in its budget, so that only three furlough
days were required. Fahrenthold and Rein's article can be summed up
by a quote from their interview with Robert Bixby of the Concord
Coalition: "The dog barked. But it didn't bite."
President Obama's 2014 budget contained enough cuts that
federal spending would fall under die caps on both defense and
nondefense discretionary spending. Thus the Office of Management and
Budget determined that sequestration was not needed for the 2014 fiscal
year (Clark 2014). Furthermore, projections regarding the nation's
economy and budget in coming years are generally positive. In a June
2014 press conference, Federal Reserve Chairwoman Janet Yellen displayed
projections showing 2015 real GDP growth above 3 percent, and
unemployment falling below 6 percent by the end of 2015--despite budget
cuts (Yellen 2014). In fact, unemployment fell below 6 percent in
October 2014, and stood at 5.1 percent, right around the natural rate of
unemployment, as this issue went to press.
Likewise, the CBO's January 2015 projections for GDP growth
were generally optimistic, suggesting that the economy would grow at a
"solid pace in 2015 and for the next few years," while the gap
between actual and potential output would be closed by 2017
(Congressional Budget Office 2015).
Federal Spending and die Economy
This article has documented two cases in which it was widely
predicted that a contraction of government spending would bring economic
ruin. In neither case did this prediction come to pass. It has been
argued that one of the reasons a major downturn was avoided in the
post-WWII era was because of pent-up demand--after several years of
rationing of private sector goods during the war, people were ready, and
had the means, to spend. To the extent that this is true, the
postsequester period offers a more difficult test of the market's
ability to flourish in an era of government contraction. On the other
hand, it could be argued that the Federal Reserve's aggressive
monetary policy in the years after the Great Recession created tailwinds
that helped the economy avoid a sequester-induced downturn. But the
world rarely provides policy experiments in a perfect vacuum. In any
case, numerous econometric studies, which attempt to hold other factors
constant, have found that fiscal policy shocks have little or no effect
on output and employment, and sometimes even have a perverse effect (see
Landau 1983, Conte and Darrat 1988, Grier and Tullock 1989, Rao 1989,
Barro 1991, Christopoulos and Tsionas 2002, Afonso and Furceri 2010, and
Wang and Abrams 2011).
One straightforward explanation of why steep declines in government
spending in both 1946 and 2013 did not result in economic disaster is
that that excessive government spending--as may be said to have occurred
in the lead-ups to both these episodes--does not stimulate the economy,
but rather crowds out private sector spending. Between 1942 and 1945,
government deficits were around 25 percent of GDP and total federal
outlays were around 42 percent of GDP. Between 2009 and 2012, deficits
were around 10 percent of GDP and total federal outlays were over 24
percent of GDP-- both of these measures were at their highest levels
since WWII.
Some government spending is certainly necessary in order for the
economy to reach its full potential, and during times of war, one would
expect government to play a larger role in the economy.
Vedder and Gallaway (1998: 2) note that "In a world without
government, there is no rule of law, and no protection of property
rights.... There is little incentive to save or invest because the
threat of expropriation is real and constant." But they claim that
government is subject to diminishing, and at some point, negative
returns. Vedder and Gallaway s (1998) empirical analysis estimates that
the optimal level of federal spending in the United States--in terms of
its impact on aggregate output--is around 17.5 percent of GDP. The
nation approached this value in the years around the turn of the 21st
century, when federal spending was just above 18 percent of GDP. When
spending as a percentage of GDP exceeds this level--as was the case
around 1945 and again in 2012--cuts in spending do not hurt, but rather
help the economy.
A second, and related, potential explanation for the economy's
resilience in the face of dramatic cuts in government spending after
both WWII and the sequester of 2013 comes from the theory of
"Expansionary Fiscal Contraction." Giavazzi and Pagano (1990)
were among the first to formally argue drat, under certain conditions,
government spending cuts could stimulate the economy. Sometimes called
the "German View," this theory relies heavily on expectations
and the effects that deficits can have on them. In particular, if agents
become concerned that large government deficits could lead to higher
interest rates or national default, they may cut back on current period
consumption and domestic investment. If cuts in government spending
boost confidence in economic actors, this could act as a stimulus.
Alesina and Ardagna (1998) and Ardagna (2004) provide empirical case
study evidence drat fiscal contraction can indeed be expansionary.
Figure 3 shows movements in the University of Michigan's Index
of Consumer Sentiment in the months around the sequester. (9) At the
passage of the Budget Control Act of 2011, consumer sentiment was at the
lowest it had been since November 2008--this was very likely related to
a fear of government default, which politicians kept highlighting.
Consumer sentiment rose quickly after passage of the BCA and it has
continued a slow, albeit uneven, rise since then. While sentiment has
risen, the budget deficit as a percentage of GDP has declined sharply.
Clearly, many other factors affect sentiment besides the deficit, but
Figure 3 offers some evidence consistent with the theory of expansionary
fiscal contraction.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Conclusion
In several different writings, Richard Vedder and his various
coauthors have highlighted the full employment post-World War II
transition as strong evidence that markets can respond well to fiscal
contraction--"No other episode more clearly supports the notion
that the best economic stimulus is for government to get out of the
way" (Taylor and Vedder 2010: 6). Still, when those government cuts
were taking place, Keynesians predicted an economic bloodbath. While
most mainstream predictions were for unemployment to jump to 14 percent
in 1946 should the government dramatically cut spending and hand over
resources to the private sector, some pundits had this measure rising to
around 30 percent. In fact, despite government spending falling from
around 42 percent of GDP in 1945 to under 25 percent in 1946 and under
15 percent in 1947, unemployment remained below 5 percent throughout the
period.
This article has explored parallels between the post-World War II
fiscal contraction and the fiscal contraction brought about by the
Budget Control Act of 2011 and one of its creations, the sequester,
which was implemented in March 2013. Like 1945, predictions by
politicians, government forecasters, and the media were for a
dramatically negative economic effect. The sequester was to cause GDP to
grow 1.5 percent slower than would otherwise be the case, unemployment
would rise to over 8 percent, and employment would fall by 1.9 million.
Despite these warnings, nominal federal spending fell in 2012 and
201.3--the first time the United States has seen two consecutive years
of declining government spending in nearly six decades. And yet it
turned out that GDP grew faster and the unemployment rate fell more
quickly in the 18 months after the sequester went into effect than it
did in die 18 months that preceded it. Once again, Keynesian predictions
of Armageddon when government spending falls back toward its optimal
level were shown to be wrong. The sequester episode provides further
support for Vedder's view that cuts in government spending toward
their optimal level--around 17.5 percent of GDP--do not harm, but
actually help, the economy.
References
Afonso, A., and Furceri, D. (2010) "Government Size,
Composition, Volatility and Economic Growth." European Journal of
Political Economy 26: 517-32.
Alesina, A., and Ardagna, S. (1998) "Tales of Fiscal
Adjustment." Economic Policy 13: 487-545.
Ardagna, S. (2004) "Fiscal Stabilizations, When Do They Work
and Why?" European Economic Review 48 (5): 1047-74
Ballard, J. S. (1983) The Shock of Peace. Washington: University
Press of America.
Barro, B. J. (1991) "Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of
Countries." Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 407-43.
Bateman, F., and Taylor, J. E. (2003) "The New Deal at War:
Alphabet Agencies' Expenditure Patterns, 1940-1945."
Explorations in Economic History 40: 251-77. Bernanke, B. S. (2012)
"Transcript of Chairman Bernanke's Press Conference" (12
December). Available at www.federalreserve
.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20121212.pdf.
Boehner, J. (2013) "The President Is Raging against a Budget
Crisis He Created." Wall Street Journal (20 February).
Brown, D. (2013) "Cheating the Future: The Price of Not Fixing
Entitlements." Washington: Third Way.
Burlij, T., and Polantz, K. (2012) "Republicans Unhappy with
Latest Fiscal Cliff Talks." PBS (www.pbs.org/newshour/rundown/
republicans-unhappy-with-latest-fiscal-cliff-talks).
Carter, S. B. (2006) "Labor Force, Employment, and
Unemployment: 1890-1990." In S. B. Carter et al. (eds.) Historical
Statistics of the United States, Table Ba470477. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Christopoulos, D. K., and Tsionas, E. G. (2002) "Unemployment
and Government Size: Is There Any Credible Causality?" Applied
Economic Letters 9: 797-800.
Clark, C. (2014) "CBO: Sequestration Cuts Are Unlikely This
Year." Government Executive (www.govexec.com/contracting/2014/08/
cbo-sequestration-cuts-are-unlikely-year/91574).
Congressional Budget Office (2013) "The Budget and Economic
Outlook: Fiscal Years 2013 to 2023." Available at www.cbo.gov/
publication/43907.
--(2015) "The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2015
to 2025." Available at www.cbo.gov/publication /49892.
Conte, M. A., and Darrat, A. F. (1988) "Economic Growth and
the Expanding Public Sector: A Reexamination." Review of Economics
and Statistics 70: 322-30.
Elmendorf, D. W. (2013) The Congressional Budget Office's
Budget and Economic Outlook: Hearing Before the House Committee on the
Budget, 113th Congress, 1st Session (statement of Douglas W. Elmendorf,
Director, Congressional Budget Office).
Fahrenthold, D. A., and Rein, L. (2013) "They Said the
Sequester Would Be Scary. Mostly, They Were Wrong." Washington Post
(30 June).
Firey, T. (2012) "$800 Billion Stimulus? I Wish." Cato at
Liberty (blog), Cato Institute. Available at
www.cato.org/blog/800-billionstimulus-i-wish.
Giavazzi, F., and Pagano, M. (1990) "Can Severe Fiscal
Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales of Two Small European
Countries." NBER Macroeconomics Annual 5: 7.5--122.
Grier, K. B., and G. Tullock (1989) "An Empirical Analysis of
Cross-National Economic Growth, 1951-1980." Journal of Monetary
Economics 24: 259-76.
Joint Select Committee on Deficit Reduction (2011) "Statement
from Co-Chairs of the Joint Select Committee on Deficit Reduction."
Available at www.deficitreduction.gov/public/index
.cfm/pressreleases?ID=fa0e02f6-2cc2-4aa6-b32a-3c7f6155806d.
Koistinen, P. A. C. (2004) Arsenal of World War II: The Political
Economy of American Warfare, 1940--45. Lawrence, Kan.: University Press
of Kansas.
Krugman, P. (2013) "Sequester of Fools." New York Times
(22 February).
Kurtz, A. (2012) "Who Started the Latest 'Fiscal Cliff
Buzz?" CNN Money
(economy.money.cnn.com/2012/11/09/fiscal-cliff-origins).
Landau, D. (1983) "Government Expenditure and Economic Growth:
A Cross-Country Study." Southern Economic Journal 49: 783-92.
Politi, J. (2012) "Fiscal Cliff Overshadows White House
Race." Financial Times (18 October).
Rao, V. V. Bhanoji (1989) "Government Size and Economic
Growth: A New Framework and Some Evidence from Cross-Section and
TimeSeries Data: Comment." American Economic Review 79: 272-80.
Sahadi, J. (2013) "Deficit Hawks: Fiscal Cliff Deal a Real
Downer." CNN Money
(money.enn.com/2013/01/03/news/economy/fiscalcliff-deficit).
Taylor, J. E., and Vedder R. K. (2010) "Stimulus by Spending
Cuts: Lessons from 1946." Cato Policy Report 32 (3).
U.S. Bureau of the Budget (1946) United States at War. Washington:
U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. Government Accountability Office (2014) "Sequestration
2013: Agencies Reduced Some Services and Investments, While Taking
Certain Actions to Mitigate Effects." Available at
www.gao.gov/assets/670/661444.pdf.
U.S. Office of Management and Budget (2014a) "Historical
Tables." Available at www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/historicals.
--(2014b) "Sequestration Reports to the President."
Available at www.whitehouse.gov/omb/legislative_reports /sequestration.
U.S. Office of War Mobilization and Reconversion (1945) Report to
the President, the Senate and the House of Representatives. Washington:
U.S. Government Printing Office.
Vatter, H. G. (1985) The U.S. Economy in World War II. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Vedder, R. K., and Gallaway, L. E. (1991) "The Great
Depression of 1946." Review of Austrian Economics 5 (2): 3--32.
--(1993) Out of Work: Unemployment and Government in
Twentieth-Century America. New York: Holmes and Meier.
--(1998) "Government Size and Economic Growth." Paper
prepared for foint Economic Committee, United States Congress.
Wall Street Journal (2013) "The Unscary Sequester." Wall
Street Journal (6 February).
Wang, S., and Abrams, B. A. (2011) "Government Outlays,
Economic Growth and Unemployment: A VAR Model." Unpublished
Manuscript.
Welch, M. (2013) "Cuts Too Deep? No, Not Deep Enough."
CNN (http://www.cnn.com/2013/02/26/opinion/welch-budget-cuts).
White House (2013) "Weekly Address: Congress Must Compromise
to Stop die Impact of the Sequester." YouTube.com (youtu.be/
L_efi36YL4s).
Yellen, J. L. (2013) "A Painfully Slow Recovery for
America's Workers: Causes, Implications, and the Federal
Reserve's Response." Available at
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/ speech/yellen20130211a.htm.
--(2014) "Transcript of Chair Yellen's Press Conference
June 18, 2014." Available at www.federalreserve.gov/media
center/flles/FOMCpresconf20140618.pdf.
(1) For a thorough discussion of the U.S. mobilization for WWII,
see Koistinen (2004) and Vatter (1985).
(2) Quoted in Vedder and Callaway (1993: 162).
(3) Rep. William Shuster (R-Pa.), Congressional Record 157 (110),
July 21, 2011.
(4) Rep. Gerry Connolly (D-Va.), Congressional Record 158 (86),
June 8, 2012.
(5) Rep. Joe Wilson (R-S.C.), Congressional Record 158 (164),
December 19, 2012.
(6) Sen. Bill Nelson (D-Fla.), Congressional Record 158 (160),
December 12, 2012.
Rep. Dan Kildee (D-Mich.), Congressional Record 159 (27), February
26, 2013.
(8) Sen. Barbara Boxer (D-Calif.), Congressional Record 159 (30),
March 4, 2013.
(9) The deficit is calculated as a percentage of GDP using annual
deficit data and quarterly GDP data.
Jason E. Taylor is Professor of Economics and Ronald L. Klingler is
a graduate student at Central Michigan University. The authors thank
Joshua Hall and anonymous reviewers for comments on earlier versions of
this article. Ronald Klingler is grateful for support from the Charles
Koch Foundation.
TABLE 1
CIVILIAN LABOR FORCE, EMPLOYMENT, AND
UNEMPLOYMENT (IN THOUSANDS),
1939-1950
Civilian Unemployment
Year Labor Force Employed Unemployed Percentage
1939 55,218 48,993 6,225 11.3%
1940 55,640 50,350 5,290 9.5%
1941 55,910 52,559 3,351 6.0%
1942 56,410 54,664 1,746 3.1%
1943 55,540 54,555 985 1.8%
1944 54,630 53,960 670 1.2%
1945 53,860 52,820 1,040 1.9%
1946 57,520 55,250 2,270 3.9%
1947 59,682 57,053 2,629 4.4%
1948 60,621 58,358 2,263 3.7%
1949 61,315 57,683 3,632 5.9%
1950 62,079 58,892 3,187 5.1%
SOURCE: Carter (2006).