Reflections on the current state of political economy.
Veddder, Richard K.
Like most economics professors, I have spent my academic lifetime
examining the economic and public policy effects of issues involving the
production, distribution, and consumption of goods and
services--political economy, if you will. There is, however, a
"political economy" to die very act of producing and
disseminating economic knowledge and examining public policies. And that
political economy and my assessment of it has changed over a career
spanning more than half a century. In this brief article, I will confine
my attention mostly to the research dimension and look at five issues,
most relating to the political economy of the study of political
economy.
Diminishing Returns to Research
I have long been bemused by economists who profess to understand
the principle of scarcity and the importance of opportunity costs, yet
write so much trivia of little interest to anyone. They do so because of
the nonmarket nature of most academic endeavors and the utter lack of
incentives to be efficient. The fifteenth paper on a topic is not very
likely to add as much to our stock of knowledge as the first or second.
I think the nation as a whole has probably overinvested in higher
education because of vast governmental subsidies (an argument best made
by retired professors like me whose potential acquisition of economic
rents by extolling higher education is minimal). That manifests itself
in such phenomena as the overeducated Starbucks barista or in the more
than 115,000 janitors with bachelor s degrees. It also means roughly
1,000 academic papers are being written on William Shakespeare
annually--three per day (Bauerlein 2009: 6). Who reads them? How much
does a typical paper add at the margin to the insights that Shakespeare
gave us 400 years ago?
The problem extends to the inputs as the well as the outputs of
higher education, and too many professors are writing too many words
(and equations) that, to borrow from the Bard (Shakespeare to college
graduates after 1990), "signify nothing." What if professors
wrote only one-third or one-half the number of papers they currently
write, but taught one more class per year? My guess is that the net
effects would be at least mildly positive, maybe even leading to smaller
tuition increases and delaying a bit the demise of die current medieval
way we do business. Belated to all that, the U.S. Department of
Education can probably tell you how many anthropology professors of
Hispanic origin there are in South Dakota, but cannot tell you what the
average teaching load of American professors is. But I am pretty sure it
is minimally 25 percent less than it was when I began fulltime teaching
in tire year the Higher Education Act passed, 1965. Doing less
(teaching) with more describes modern higher education.
Pseudo-Science and Ideology
Modern economics may be less ideologically driven dian, say,
sociology, but the notion that economists are scientists who objectively
observe phenomenon and derive conclusions solely on the basis of
empirical evidence is largely a myth, despite pretenses to the contrary.
Nobel Prize winners like Paul Krugman and Joseph Stiglitz sometimes
morph into almost pure ideologues, doing little or no truly serious work
after receiving superstar academic recognition. And, as is oft-observed,
the predominant ideological orientation is leftish, despite overwhelming
evidence that many leftish policy prescriptions are failures or at least
highly inefficient. Leftish intellectuals helped created the European
welfare state that has been accompanied by declining growth rates for
six decades, from around 5 percent annually in the 1950s to under 2
percent today. Yet, only a minority of economists uses this overwhelming
evidence to suggest the nonmarket statist solutions of the welfare state
are highly flawed.
Why is this? I think a big reason for this is that modern academic
economics is funded predominantly by the state, even at so-called
private schools like Harvard. Academics are wards of the state, so it is
in their self-interest to have the state large and taxes high. It is
ideological bias driven by rent seeking. Even conservative/libertarian
scholars like the late George Stigler or Gary Becker often favored and
even lobbied for governmental academic support. I once informally
debated Becker, arguing that the alleged positive externalities of
higher education were largely fiction, a view Milton Friedman was coming
around to shortly before his death (Vedder 2004: 127). Becker kept
saying college graduates committed fewer crimes, smoked less, and
volunteered more, but made no rigorous attempt to relate these
attributes to collegiate attendance as opposed to other character
traits.
Why did most economists apparently vote for Obama in both 2008 and
2012, when by any objective measure Obama's policies have led to a
severely underperforming economy? Why do economists support those
politicians who promote policies that lead to less creation of goods and
services, more inefficiency and, often, even greater poverty and income
inequality? Measured income inequality is greater under President Obama
than under, say, either George W. Bush or Ronald Reagan. Again, insights
from the theory of public choice are in order: don't underestimate
the importance of rent seeking--the government has bought off many
academics. (1)
The Rise of the Nonuniversity Research Centers
One thing students learn early in their first course in economics
is that monopoly is inefficient and costly, and competition is good. As
university faculty show their disdain for the power of markets and
promote solutions shown to be inefficient and often poverty inducing,
new intellectual competition has arisen, some via privately funded
support for university teaching and research but also by independent
research centers--think tanks. When I started in academia in tire 1960s,
we had the National Bureau of Economic Research, the Hoover Institution,
the Brookings Institution, and a nascent American Enterprise Institute.
Today, in the nation's capital alone there are at least half a
dozen relatively important centers where economic research is conducted
at some level: Brookings and AEI, but also the Cato Institute, Heritage
Foundation, Competitive Enterprise Institute, and the Urban Institute. A
majority, although by no means all, of them support and encourage
research and writings pointing out tire failures of big government and
the unintended consequences of many public policies.
Equally important has been the proliferation of regional think
tanks, such as the Mackinac Center in Michigan, the Texas Public Policy
Foundation, the Manhattan Institute, the Commonwealth Institute in
Pennsylvania, and the Pacific Research Institute in California.
Important non-Washington-based nationally oriented think tanks like the
Heartland Institute, National Center for Policy Analysis, and the
Independent Institute have importantly contributed to the creation and
dissemination of important economic research, almost all of it far less
celebratory of the accomplishments of nonmarket political solutions than
that found in the universities. (2) Some private philanthropists (e.g.,
the Charles Koch Foundation, Searle Freedom Trust, and Bradley
Foundation) have supported academic work and even centers within the
university environment. I sense, however, that the "market
share" of universities in the world of ideas is in decline, and
that decline will continue as extreme collegiate inefficiency and
contempt for the real world will lead to declining governmental and
possible private support. Without massive subsidies, the universities
decline. Massive public overinvestment has already led to huge
underemployment of graduates. The declining return on public investment
in higher education is becoming obvious to politicians and voters, if
not to the professors who are major beneficiaries of third-party
largess. Adding to the woes of universities, sharply declining economic
growth and rapidly rising unfunded liabilities are reducing the capacity
of governments and private donors to fund operations.
The Disconnect between Economic Reality and Public Policy
In my academic lifetime, three important conclusions have come
about as a result of empirical observations and theoretical advances in
economics. First, the Keynesian approach to stimulate economies through
monetary and fiscal policy almost always results in failure. This was
manifested empirically in the stagflation of the 1970s (despite
continuous budget deficits and fiscal and monetary stimulus), as well as
by theoretical advances by Milton Friedman, Edmund Phelps, and the
rational expectations school (Robert Lucas, Thomas Sargent, and others).
The Phillips Curve, all the rage in principles of economics courses in
the 1960s, has been largely discredited.
Second, centrally planned economies without substantial private
property rights are extremely inefficient and ultimately unsustainable.
As late as the mid-1980s, Nobel laureate Paul Samuelson in his iconic
textbook proclaimed that the Soviet planning system was a powerful
engine for economic growth (Samuelson and Nordhaus 1985). That idea has
been thoroughly discredited. The greatest empirical economic event of
the 20th century, the fall of the Soviet Union (without a shot being
fired), is the primary evidence. Similarly, the easing of central
planning and tire establishment of private property rights in China set
off an economic growth of unprecedented proportions. The new
institutional economics and tire emphasis on the importance of property
rights and business organization by economists like Ronald Coase, Armen
Alehian, Harold Demestz, Oliver Williamson, Douglass North, and a host
of others, enhances our understanding of the Chinese economic
revolution. Indeed, as early as 1920, the great Austrian economist
Ludwig von Mises ([1920] 1990) warned that efficient central planning
was impossible, a point picked up empirically by several writers from
1950 to 1990, notably Soviet expert G. Warren Nutter (1968).
Third, even economies that blended private property rights and some
protection of market activity with a huge income redistributionist
welfare state have been shown to have troubles sustaining material
advances. The much-hyped eurozone has been mired for at least a
generation in stagnation, most prevalent in tire areas where fiscal
insanity and redistributionist schemes were the greatest--countries like
Greece and Spain. From 2010 through 2014, 25 of 36 European nations I
examined had average annual growth rates below 2 percent, and the
high-growth (2.7 percent a year or more) nations were the Baltic
Republics, Poland, Turkey, and Moldova, former Communist countries that
have eschewed excessive welfare state policies or, in the case of
Turkey, a non-EU nation that never has had a vast welfare state with
high tax levels, The supply-side revolution of the 1980s established
that "taxes matter," and economic incentives influenced by
public policy are important in the efficient and plentiful provision of
resources for economic growth.
While theoretical advances and empirical work demonstrated clearly
that market-oriented, competitive economies outperformed heavily statist
ones with much centralized direction, why did much of the world
seemingly ignore that advice, moving to ever-larger governmental command
over the economy? In part, the answer lies in that both the scholarly
and popular media are still dominated by people on the left. It also
reflects, however, a public choice insight: special interest groups,
concentrated minorities of the population, can often overcome the
interests of the majority--concentrated benefits (the special interests)
win over the disbursed costs incurred by the general public, which
lobbies less because individually they have less at stake (although not
collectively).
The War on Work
Let me turn to my own areas of scholarly interest. A large portion
of my own work, especially with Lowell Gallaway, relates to labor
markets. I think modern economists have understated the importance of
labor, which by most measures accounts for nearly two-thirds of
production. I will go to my death believing the single most important
factor in causing the Great Depression was discoordination in labor
markets (too high wages) caused in large part by government policies
such as the Hoover-Roosevelt "high-wage" policy (Vedder and
Gallaway 1997). And probably the centerpiece of the Great Slowdown after
2000 has been what could be called a government-led War on Work. From
1960 to 2000, the proportion of Americans working increased, but that
was entirely the result of greater female labor participation. Edward
Prescott (2004) has shown how American economic supremacy over Europe
grew in the 1980s and 1990s simply because Americans worked more, and
work effort in Europe was in significant decline. Since 2000, however,
the European Disease has come to America, and the proportion of
Americans working has fallen sharply. Not coincidentally, the American
natural rate of economic growth (to perhaps coin a term) has gone from
above 3 percent to about 2 percent a year, with tragic consequences for
future generations.
Why? Again, this is the unintended consequences of the welfare
state. Disability insurance claims have roughly tripled in the last
generation (despite greater inherent safety in the workplace because of
the declining relative importance of manufacturing and mining);
government-subsidized student loans and grants have lured younger
Americans away from working; extended unemployment benefits prolonged
unemployment; and food stamps now go to nearly 30 million more Americans
than 15 years ago (Vedder 2013). The government has provided much more
income that is only available if people do not work. So fewer do.
The Decline in Historical Consciousness
As George Santayana (1905) told us over a century ago, "Those
who cannot remember the past are condemned to repeat it." Modern
economists shower themselves with lots of mathematics and use ever-more
sophisticated econometric techniques to analyze economic phenomena. But
they are increasingly abysmally ignorant of the past. That leads
economists to overconfidence (thinking everything important was
discovered recently, and past generations were therefore ignorant),
further leads them to ignore the context that past events provide in
shaping the present, and, therefore, sometimes leads us to repeat
mistakes made in the past. The ahistorical nature of modern economists
is demonstrated by the near disappearance of courses on the history of
economic thought, as well as the sharp decline in the study of economic
history (the evolution of modern economies). Why did 19th-century
America surpass Britain and other heretofore larger and more powerful
European economies to become the richest nation in the world? Why did we
go from 4 percent growth in the 1920s to 0 percent growth in the 1930s,
in the process leading to a peaceful political revolution that shapes
America to this day? How are the "Black Lives Matter" movement
and related phenomena partially related to slavery that ended 150 years
earlier? How did our current understanding of "value" come
about, and why did economists for centuries puzzle over things like the
difference between "value in use" and "value in
exchange"? Economic history and the history of economic thought
give insights into these and many other questions. A little dose of that
would do all serious students of economics some good.
Conclusion
If economics is on the decline, why do I continue to teach and do
research after more than 50 years? The answer is I like doing my bit to
correct the wrongs discussed in this article. Above all, I live for
seeing the results of my labors a decade or even several decades later,
in terms of opening the minds of young men and women to the logic of the
price system and the importance of private property and other
institutions for freedom and prosperity. Helping my students understand
the unintended consequences of public policies and seeing those students
become successful teachers and scholars is itself rewarding.
References
Bauerlein, M. (2009) "Literary Research: Costs and
Impact." Washington: Center for College Affordability and
Productivity.
Buchanan, J. M.; Tollison, R. D.; and Tullock, G. (eds.) (1980)
Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. College Station, Tex.:
Texas A&M Press.
Niskanen, W. A. (1971) Bureaucracy and Representative Government.
Chicago: Aldine Atherton.
Nutter, G. W. (1968) "Markets without Property: A Grand
Illusion." In N. Beadles and A. Drewry (eds.) Money, the Market and
the State, 137-45. Athens, Ga.: University of Georgia Press.
Prescott, E. C. (2004) "Why Do Americans Work so Much More
than Europeans?" Cambridge, Mass.: NBER Working Paper No. 10316.
Samuelson, P., and Nordhaus, W. (1985) Economics. 12th ed. New
York: McGraw-Hill.
Santayana, G. (1905) The Life of Reason. Vol. 1. New York: Charles
Scribner's Sons.
Vedder, R. K. (2004) Going Broke By Degree: Why College Costs Too
Much. Washington: AEI Press.
--(2013) "The Wages of Unemployment." Wall Street Journal
(16 January).
Vedder, R. K., and Callaway, L. E. (1997) Out of Work: Government
and Unemployment in Twentieth-Century America. New York: New York
University Press.
Von Mises, L. ([1920] 1990) Economic Calculation in the Socialist
Commonwealth. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
(1) On insights from public choice theory, see Buchanan, Tollison,
and Tullock (1980) and Niskanen (1971).
(2) I have lectured, written, and advised for more than 30 of these
organizations over my career.
Richard K. Vedder is Distinguished Professor of Economics Emeritus
at Ohio University, Director of the Center for College Affordability and
Productivity, Adjunct Scholar at the American Enterprise Institute, and
Senior Fellow at the Independent Institute.