The new monetary framework.
Jordan, Jerry L.
Do the policy actions of monetary authorities actually affect
economic activity? We know that time and other resources are expended,
but what can we observe about the results of such efforts?
In answering this question, it is helpful to begin with an account
of how monetary authorities in discretionary, fiat currency regimes are
traditionally thought to influence economic activity. Here, every
college course in intermediate monetary theory tells essentially the
same story. A nation's money supply comprises two distinct
components: paper currency and deposits at banking organizations. The
former was the largest component in earlier times, but the latter has
come to dominate in recent decades--at least in most countries. The
deposits in banks are subject to minimum reserve requirements, and the
total deposit liabilities of banks constitute some multiple of reserve
balances (that is, vault cash plus deposits at the central bank). The
banking system as a whole is thus "reserve constrained," which
means that, unless the central bank provides more reserves, there is an
upper limit to the total deposits that may be held by individuals and
businesses. By extension, if currency outstanding increases, and the
central bank fails to add to the total supply of reserves available to
private banks, then there has to be a corresponding contraction of
deposit money. These reserve constraints have historically meant that,
for better or worse, monetary authorities have the power to control the
nation's money supply, and, in so doing, affect economic activity.
However, this traditional account no longer holds true. The
commercial banking system has ceased to be reserve constrained, and this
means that monetary authority actions to change the size of the central
bank balance sheet do not affect the nation's money supply. Now,
instead of being constrained by the amount of reserves supplied by
central banks, banking companies are constrained by the supply of
earning assets that are available to them. And it is the supply of these
earning assets that, subject to capital constraints, determines
banks' aggregate deposit liabilities.
What implications does this shift have? Brunner and Meltzer (1972:
973) suggested that while it was possible for inflation or deflation to
occur without changes in the monetary base, most inflations were, in
practice, the result of base money expansion. That conclusion reflected
the fact that the banking system was reserve constrained, so that
increases in the stock of money were limited in the absence of expansion
of the central bank balance sheet. However, in today's world of
massive excess reserves in the banking system, the same model used by
Brunner and Meltzer suggests that money creation has become a function
of loan demand and the securities on offer to banks.
The new college textbook for intermediate monetary theory
explaining all this has not yet been written, but when it is, it will
not say that the monetary authorities control the "supply of
money" and estimate the "demand for money," the objective
being to prevent either an excess supply (which would cause inflation),
or an excess demand (which would trigger a recession). That theoretical
framework is broken--at least for now--in such a way that the monetary
authorities can no longer formulate policy actions intended to influence
aggregate economic activity by expanding or contracting the central bank
balance sheet.
Interest Rates and Monetary Stimulus
The intermediate college course on monetary theory also offers an
alternative theoretical avenue for influencing the economy--the level of
nominal market interest rates. The basic idea is that when interest
rates are lower, people borrow more to consume and invest, and when
interest rates are higher, people will borrow less for consumption and
investment. The big economic debate--and empirical contest--has been
about the degree to which people understand the inflation premium in
nominal interest rates, as well as the before- and after-tax interest
expense they will bear. The economic argument is that if people think in
terms of interest rates that are adjusted for anticipated inflation
and/or taxation, observed market interest rates are higher than the
"real" interest that affects consumer and investor decisions.
One hypothesis is that central bank
"zero-interest-rate-policy" (ZIRP) works by pushing down bond
yields so that investors are driven into equities in search of higher
returns. Consequently higher valuations in equity markets then create a
"wealth effect," wherein stockholders decide to increase
consumption spending. Presumably, greater consumption demand will, in
turn, give potential investors more confidence to forge ahead with
capacity expansions and new projects.
However, this model only makes sense in a closed economy. In an
open, global economic system, there is no reason to expect that
increased investment and output will be domestic--even if aggregate
consumer spending does respond to stock prices. This is especially so in
a context of tax and regulatory policies hostile to capital formation.
And surely no policymaker would argue that the best way to promote
prosperity via monetary policy is to drive the trade deficit ever higher
as imports outpace export growth.
Whatever the theoretical arguments, and regardless of the evidence
of most of the past century, the near-zero interest rates we have seen
in recent years have shown no correlation with domestically produced
consumption by households, or with domestic investment activity in the
private sector. In fact, an argument can be made that the low interest
rate environment has reduced the demand for bank credit while increasing
the demand for earning assets by non-bank lenders such as mutual funds,
pension funds, and insurance companies (Jordan 2014). Hence, the
liabilities of banks (i.e., demand deposits) have grown more slowly than
they otherwise might have. In other words, the "low interest rates
are expansionary" view conflicts with the "slow money growth
is contractionary" view of the channels by which monetary
authorities influence the economy.
Central Banks and Economic Growth
Another contribution to this debate about the influence of monetary
authorities on the economy comes from the "market
monetarists," who argue that central banks should focus their
policy actions on achieving a target growth rate for nominal GDP that is
consistent with their objectives for inflation and real economic growth.
This claim, however, is the "assume we have a can opener"
approach to economics. Monetary authorities once had several tools in
their policy bag--reserve requirements, discount rates, interest
ceilings, open market purchases and sales--that might be employed to
achieve any objective they chose. But what tools do they have today to
influence the pace of nominal GDP growth? What instructions can the
monetary authorities give to their trading desk to achieve a faster or
slower growth of nominal GDP? None!
The notions behind monetary and fiscal stimulus are, first, that
that economic growth comes from getting consumers to spend or businesses
to invest, and, second, that this can be brought about by government
actions designed to "stimulate demand." But that is not how
growth happens. A couple of hundred years ago, Adam Smith would have
laughed at the idea that consumers' wants are satiated and must be
"stimulated" by government, or that investors don't
foresee opportunities to enhance profit without the government hyping
demand for something--and rightly so.
In fact, growth (i.e., rising standards of living) happens when
there are opportunities for real cost reductions. Put simply, when
innovations cause the information and transactions costs of doing
something to decline, people do more of the now-lower-priced thing. The
demand was always there. It was never necessary for either monetary or
fiscal authorities of government to "promote demand" for
something. Wants are insatiable. If the cost of a weekend
fly-around-Mars drops dramatically, the amount demanded will rise. The
notion that government can or should do something to stimulate demand
is, at best, obsolete.
Monetary Policy and the Politics of Wealth Sharing
Economic progress comes from reducing the sand in the gears. Often
that sand is natural--information and transaction costs, for example. In
modern societies, however, many such costs are artificial, created by
collusive behavior between private interests, who want to protect their
turf, and government officials, who want campaign contributions.
Erecting and maintaining barriers to entry from potential competitors
generates more political contributions than do promises to reduce such
barriers. During the last half of the 20th century, burgeoning licensing
and certification requirements created new obstacles to competition, so
that innovations, new business startups, and real cost reductions slowed
in many industries and sectors.
Meanwhile, political parties competed to build coalitions of voters
by promising to transfer to them part of someone else's
paychecks--either now or in the future. Eventually, even highly
efficient and effective tax systems are no longer able to generate the
collections necessary to fulfill all such promises, and political
choices become unavoidable. In this dynamic, modern central banks have
been part of the problem, not part of any lasting solution.
In the United States in the 1960s, promises made to individuals and
households, together with rising government expenditures for the
military, began to outrun tax revenues at an accelerating rate. Instead
of reining in spending, the Johnson administration and then the Nixon
administration cut the U.S. central bank loose from its specie anchor in
three steps. First, the "London Gold Pool" was suspended; then
the "gold window" was closed while the "gold cover"
of U.S. currency was removed by Congress; finally, the commitment to
redeem foreign-held dollars for gold was eliminated in 1973. These steps
freed the central bank from any institutionalized discipline in the
creation of new currency and bank reserves, and in turn removed any need
for fiscal discipline. The result was accelerating inflation--the form
of taxation favored by politicians for at least a couple of thousand
years.
In this respect, the U.S. experience in the 1960s and 1970s was no
different from that of other developed and developing countries with
central banks and a monopoly national currency. Political promises of
other people's money eventually added up to more than the tax
system could generate, central banks were called upon to make up the
difference with additional new money creation, and the ensuing inflation
resulted in devaluation or depreciation of the currency. In the end,
voters had been suckered into accepting nominal money units in exchange
for their votes, but found the money they received did not buy as much
as it had previously. They were the victims of an unholy alliance
between fiscal and monetary authorities under the sway of politicians.
The recent experience of Greece is instructive. Even with a booming
economy in the 1950s and 1960s, the Greek tax system did not collect
enough revenue to fund all the promises politicians were making to
voters. So the country's national currency was devalued in the
early 1970s and depreciated continuously for a couple more decades until
the drachma was replaced by the euro. Once Greek politicians realized
they could sell euro-denominated bonds to foreign investors in order to
fund the promises they had made to voters, a frenzy of vote buying led
to a national debt much larger than any tax system could service.
Because inflation and devaluation were not possible once the Greek
central bank was deprived of its power to create new money, default on
the foreign-owned Greek government bonds became unavoidable.
Ironically, the absence of a national currency--and a central bank
able to create more of it--had in Greece's case allowed politicians
to dig a debt hole much larger than had previously been possible. This
was because foreign buyers of Greek euro bonds knew that the creator of
euros--the European Central Bank (ECB)--would be pressured by
governments of lender countries in the eurozone to create the additional
euros needed by the Greek treasury to make the interest payments to the
non-Greek banks and other lenders that owned the Greek debt.
Of course, the holders of Greek government bonds do not care
whether the euros necessary to pay them back with interest come from the
ECB or loans from other governments to the Greek government. However,
some of those other countries have very large debts of their own, so
issuing even more bonds in order to finance loans (or gifts) to the
Greek government was a nonstarter. The moral of this story is that
effective discipline in the fiscal decisions made by politicians cannot
and will not be achieved as long as there are central banks empowered to
create more of the money that politicians have promised to deliver.
All bonds issued by governments and all "entitlement"
promises made by governments to voters are claims on future tax
collections. Historical experience has been that such government-created
claims on the tax system will always grow to exceed potential future tax
receipts. Yet this experience of central banking and monopoly currency
appears to have had no lasting effect on the propensities of politicians
to promise potential voters that, if elected/reelected, he/she will vote
to transfer other taxpayers' money to his/her supporters. In almost
all democracies, the "politics of wealth sharing" has come to
dominate the "politics of wealth creation." The reason is
simple. No single elected representative or group of elected
representatives has much, if any, influence over the pace at which an
economy creates wealth. Any promise that newly created national wealth
will benefit any one voter or even group of voters is simply not
credible. However, even a single elected representative can facilitate a
transfer of existing wealth to particular voters or constituents. A
group of politicians, organized as a coalition or political party, can
arrange this transfer of wealth on a much larger scale.
When it inevitably turns out that the aggregate of such promises
exceeds the amount available for redistribution, no recipient group will
voluntarily forgo their claims to other people's money. There are,
of course, those rare politicians who campaign on promises to reduce
some beneficiary groups' payments from government, but they are
rarely elected (or reelected). And even in office, they often find
themselves powerless to actually carry out their agenda.
All of this was understood very well by James Madison as he drafted
the U.S. Constitution to replace the failed Articles of Confederation.
The decision that the country's money should be backed by gold and
silver was deliberately intended to impose fiscal discipline; since the
amount of money in circulation was limited by available precious metals
to back the currency, current expenditures of government, and promises
of payments in the future, had to be limited to tax collections. Even
when the Federal Reserve banks were created in 1914, the currency issued
by these new "bankers' banks" was defined in terms of a
weight of gold. There was no provision in the Federal Reserve Act for
discretionary monetary policy.
Sadly, the United States' on-again/off-again efforts to anchor
the value of the dollar to a specified weight of gold came to an end as
the first six decades of U.S. central banking drew to a close. The next
phase included efforts to achieve monetary discipline within the
decisionmaking bodies of the monetary authority, sometimes under
pressure from congressional oversight.
Learning and Unlearning from Experience
The past four decades of discretionary monetary management have
been mixed, to say the least. The first decade saw soaring inflation and
simultaneous increases in unemployment--contrary to widespread economic
opinion at that time, there was no apparent tradeoff to exploit. With
politicians and central bankers mugged by this unfortunate reality,
cold-turkey monetary policy was accompanied by tax reductions and
regulatory reforms, which in turn unleashed unexploited supply-side
opportunities. Prosperity flourished without monetary actions to
stimulate consumption and investment demand.
The second and third of the past four decades supported the view
that monetary discipline was a necessary condition--and perhaps even a
sufficient condition--for fiscal discipline. The era of the
"bond-market vigilantes" dissuaded politicians from incurring
budgetary deficits to fund their promises to voters, and the alternative
of raising tax rates was constrained by the political process.
Meanwhile, the explosion of e-commerce and the surprisingly large
productivity increases throughout the economy in the 1990s helped to
continuously drive the measured unemployment rate below the level at
which trade-off theorists claimed that inflation would begin to surface.
Instead of questioning the validity of their model, these theorists
simply kept revising down where they thought the noninflationary rate of
unemployment might be encountered. The puncturing of the dot-com bubble
cut short this experiment, so the model was not successfully rejected by
actual experience.
By the fourth decade of managing a purely fiat currency,
politicians were gaining experience in the use of mandates and
government guarantees to compete for voter support. There were few
dissents from the view that it was the government's job to promote
home ownership. The credit standards for obtaining mortgages and other
qualifications for purchasing houses were lowered, and government
agencies guaranteed that investors in securities backed by home
mortgages would not face losses. In that episode, the stated objectives
included promoting home ownership as a good thing in itself, with any
wealth effects caused by rising house prices a secondary objective.
Nevertheless, the phenomenon of "mortgage equity
withdrawals"--refinancing as house prices rose--generated a few
trillion dollars for households to spend on consumption, driving the
consumption-spending share of national output to historic record levels.
The ensuing collapse of house prices would ordinarily have been
accompanied by an associated drop in the consumption share of GDP.
However, the political process kicked in, and government issued massive
amounts of debt in an effort to sustain aggregate demand at the
"bubblenomics" levels. Any notion of fiscal discipline was
abandoned quite quickly, and with little political objection. Decades of
shrinking the outstanding national debt relative to the productive
potential of the economy were reversed in just a few years of political
panic. The decoupling of fiscal actions from the monetary regime raised
concerns that the "fiscal dominance hypothesis"--namely, that
monetary policy is ultimately a fiscal instrument in a world of
unanchored fiat currency--had reemerged.
Given the inability of the political process to rapidly reestablish
fiscal discipline and begin to reverse the excesses of 2008-09, the
widely held view was that it was only a matter of when the subordination
of monetary to fiscal policy would show up in the form of taxation by
way of inflation. For their part, monetary managers began to publicly
lament that the inflation rates in the United States and other major
economies were too low, and that policy should aim to create higher
inflation. Two decades earlier, no central banker or minister of finance
would have dared to suggest that inflation rates were too low and needed
to be nudged higher. However, the bond market vigilantes of the 1990s
were, by now, nowhere in sight. As the first decade of the new
millennium drew to a close, monetary authorities around the world vowed
to take strong actions in pursuit of the faster erosion of their
currencies. It wasn't just fiscal discipline that had been
abandoned; ideas and theories about monetary discipline were shoved into
a corner too.
Two lines of thinking drove this rush to monetary pump priming. The
first was that the Great Depression of the 1930s could have been
prevented if only the central bank had expanded its balance sheet
sufficiently. Contemporary monetary- authorities vowed not to make that
mistake again. Second, the idea that there was a tradeoff between
inflation and employment, which could be exploited by policymakers,
reemerged. While such notions had been badly damaged by the experience
of the 1990s, they returned as the dominant view among policymakers only
a decade later. "Pedal-to-the-metal" monetary actions were
defended on the grounds that there would be plenty of time to ease off
of monetary stimulus as the rate of unemployment moved down toward the
nonaccelerating-inflation threshold.
An unanticipated development was that while the unemployment rate
did in fact decline, this was not because of stronger labor demand and
rising employment, but rather because of an unprecedented decline in the
labor force participation rate. Even adherents to the trade-off model
struggled to explain how they would know when a low reported
unemployment rate would trigger higher inflation, given that any
increase in the demand for labor could be met by several million people
returning to the labor market. Clearly, the tradeoff theory holds that
if labor force participation rates were already high, and monetary
stimulus promoted even more demand for labor, wages would rise more
rapidly, and that would be one component of faster inflation. However,
with the labor force participation rate falling to a 38-year low, even
if monetary actions succeeded in promoting greater labor demand,
wouldn't the response simply be increases in labor supply? How can
rising "wage-push" be expected to emerge and help produce
higher consumer inflation if there is no excess demand for labor?
Ultimately, the tradeoff model proved to be unreliable when the labor
force participation rate was high; why should policymakers rely on it
when the participation rate is severely depressed?
A companion theory about economic slack as a factor in assessing
potential inflationary pressures suffers similar weaknesses. The idea is
that an economy has a long-run sustainable potential output that derives
from working age population, labor productivity, the pace of
technological innovation, and other factors. If current actual output is
below the estimated potential, according to this theory, inflationary
price and wage pressures are expected to be minimal. It is therefore
safe for policymakers to stimulate consumption and investment demand so
as to drive actual output closer to potential. Of course, the actual
pursuit of such a strategy raises all kinds of knowledge problems, even
in the best of circumstances. Moreover, in a global economy, the notion
that there can be economy-wide capacity constraints does not fit
reality. Except for some nontradable goods and services, sourcing of
both final goods and inputs to production occurs in a global
marketplace. Any estimate of domestic capacity is therefore useless in
assessing potential price pressures.
Monetary Decoupling
One thing central banks can control is the size of their balance
sheets. However, as we have already seen, recent efforts to increase the
pace of consumer inflation have not been successful. Some, no doubt,
will argue that an even larger bond-buying program is called for in
order to get the job done. An alternative conjecture is that the central
bank balance sheet is simply unconnected to economic activity in the
national economy. Quite obviously, the various measures of the
nation's money supply have not responded to the enormous increase
in the volume of central bank money. Moreover, the prevailing
(worldwide) low interest rates can be explained by factors other than
central bank bond buying (Walker 2016).
Superficially, it seems that central bank purchases of large
quantities of any asset ought to bid up the price and (in the case of
bonds) lower the current yield. However, a central bank is not like
other portfolio managers. Central banks acquire additional financial
assets by creating liabilities (more fundamentally, by creating money
out of thin air)--not by selling other assets. In an important sense,
large-scale asset purchases (LSAP) by central banks involve a form of
liability swap within consolidated government accounts--the duration, or
maturity structure, of outstanding government liabilities is shortened
by LSAP.
It is important to be clear that central bank purchases of
government bonds have different effects than purchases of private assets
such as mortgage-backed securities. While both reduce the outstanding
stock of earning assets available to commercial banks and other
investors, only the acquisition of private assets shifts potential
default risk to taxpayers. Central bank acquisition of Treasury bonds
can be thought of as merely "early retirement" of one form of
outstanding national debt. Suppose, by way of illustration, that U.S.
Treasury bonds were "callable," as many corporate bonds are.
Let's assume that the Treasury chose to issue $1 trillion of very
short-term securities at near zero interest rates and then
"called" for early redemption a corresponding amount of
long-term debt. While total debt would remain unchanged, both the
duration and the interest burden of the debt would be altered;
lower-cost, short-term liabilities were issued in order to redeem
higher-cost, longer-term debt.
Because (net) interest income earned by Federal Reserve Banks on
their holdings of securities is returned to the Treasury, the effect of
central bank purchases of Treasury bonds--matched by interest-bearing
liabilities (that is, interest paid on reserve deposits)--is not
different, analytically, from what would happen if a bureau of the
Treasury financed the purchase of long-term bonds by issuing short-term
bills. (1) Consolidation of the Treasury and central bank's balance
sheets would cancel out the bonds held as assets by Federal Reserve
Banks, while the interest-bearing liabilities of the Federal Reserve
Banks would show up as part of the government's outstanding debt.
The composition of government debt is altered in exactly the same way as
would be the case if the longer-term bonds had been retired via issuance
of short-term bills.
This transformation is important in modern financial markets, which
use "riskless" government debt as collateral for many types of
transactions. When the availability of securities that can be used for
collateral declines, there is a "tightening" of conditions in
the greater financial intermediary system. In other words, LSAP by a
central bank emits a contractionary impulse through the financial
system. (2)
Williamson (2015) argues that the use of high-quality
"riskless" securities as collateral in financial markets
declined for several reasons following the financial crisis of 2008.
Prior to that time, U.S. government and European sovereign debt were
viewed as riskless, as were the obligations of U.S. government-sponsored
enterprises (GSEs) such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Some privately
issued mortgage-backed securities (MBS) were also considered safe enough
to use as collateral. Of course, it turned out that the GSEs failed and
had to be nationalized, that the MBS market seized up, and that some
European countries found themselves on the brink of default. Those
developments resulted in a sharp decline in the stock of assets deemed
to be of sufficiently high quality to serve as collateral in financial
transactions. Taken in combination with these developments, the
large-scale purchase of U.S. Treasury securities by the central bank,
while intended to inject a form of monetary stimulus, had the unintended
effect of further tightening the functioning of capital markets. For
this reason alone, quantitative easing (QE) was a mistake.
Unfortunately, reversing QE at this point would also have adverse
effects. So what can the Federal Reserve do? For one thing, the current
portfolio of mortgage-backed securities can be held to maturity and not
replaced. That would gradually shrink the central bank balance sheet by
over $1.7 trillion. This would still leave a very large quantity of
excess reserve balances on which the depositors are earning interest,
but much more needs to be understood about the demand for such
interest-bearing deposits before we conclude that they should shrink
back to pre-crisis levels.
Much attention has been paid to the size and composition of the
Federal Reserve's $4.5 trillion of assets--and with good reason.
But not nearly enough focus has been placed on the liabilities. In
recent years, the cash assets of foreign banks have exceeded the cash
assets of large domestic banks. By some estimates, approximately half of
the interest-bearing reserve balances at Federal Reserve banks are held
by foreign banking entities (including branches and subsidiaries)
operating in the United States. These cash assets have constituted as
much as half of the total dollar assets of these foreign companies. The
current large amount of foreign-owned, dollar-denominated deposits held
by banking companies may partly reflect foreign governments'
supervisory requirements for liquidity. To some extent, they also
reflect the very large increase in these foreign companies' dollar
liabilities. Compared with 2007, for example, the deposits of foreign
banking companies operating in the United States were up by almost 50
percent in 2014.
It is important to note that increased demand for Federal Reserve
deposits does not appear to reflect the availability of interest on
reserves (IOR). After an initial jump in deposits during the crisis
period of 2008-09, dollar deposits in 2011 were not much different than
they had been in 2007. What's more, we know that the foreign owners
of U.S. currency--the other major liability of the U.S. central bank--do
not receive interest. It is estimated that more than half of the $1.3
trillion of Federal Reserve notes outstanding are foreign held. That
means that a majority of each of the two major categories of Federal
Reserve Bank liabilities--deposits and currency--are owned by
foreigners. These estimates do not count foreign individual and business
holdings of dollar-denominated deposits at commercial banks and money
market funds, and of course do not count other holdings of
dollar-denominated financial assets and real properties. Nevertheless,
the fact that foreign banks' U.S. currency holdings, as well as
deposits at Federal Reserve Banks, total almost $2 trillion reveals an
enormous global demand for high-quality money.
At present, it would not be possible to assert the existence of
either an excess supply of, or an excess demand for, dollars. Of course,
dollar currency held by foreigners, like currency held by domestic
residents, constitutes an interest-free loan to the U.S. Treasury. Since
late 2008, the deposits held by foreign banks at the Federal Reserve
have been earning 25 basis points, so that "loan" is no longer
interest free. (3) However, because the assets acquired by the Federal
Reserve banks have all been longer term and higher yielding, the net
interest expense of the U.S. Treasury has gone down as a result of this
large amount of foreign-owned dollar deposits.
Some countries have formally "dollarized," but far more
people around the world have "spontaneously dollarized."
Clearly, where it is not effectively prohibited and punished, people
choose currency competition. They want high-confidence money, especially
during times of political turmoil. One conclusion has to be that the
United States has provided a public benefit to the rest of the world. At
the same time, U.S. taxpayers have benefited from very large foreign
holding of dollars--and here we are referring only to currency and to
dollar deposits of foreign banks at the Federal Reserve.
No Exit
Any analysis, however preliminary, suggesting that LSAP actually
had a contractionary effect during the period of quantitative easing
must be taken seriously. Certainly, the cessation of such transactions
was desirable; the principle of "do no harm" applies to
central banks as well as to doctors. Nevertheless, the problem of
formulating an "exit strategy" remains. Some believe that the
central bank balance sheet should shrink back to pre-QE levels, and drat
reserve requirements should once again become binding on commercial bank
deposit creation. But that is simply not going to happen. The past
practice of conducting daily open market operations in order to closely
control the overnight interbank lending rate--the federal funds rate--is
not going to resume. Central bank purchases and sales of securities in
the "open market" can no longer be policymakers' primary
tool.
Their new tools--administering the interest rate paid on reserve
deposits and auctioning "reverse repurchase agreements"
(RRP)--have not been tested in an accelerating inflation environment. No
matter how aggressively utilized, neither has any direct effect on money
creation. The former (IOR) can be viewed simply as central bank
borrowing from private banks, while the latter (RRP) is central bank
borrowing from GSEs and money market firms. In theory, market interest
rates would be influenced by the rate the central bank offers for such
borrowings. If higher rates paid by monetary authorities cause other
interest rates to be higher, businesses and households will curtail some
credit-financed purchases, aggregate demand for output will be
moderated, and inflationary pressures will be mitigated--or so the
theory goes.
This theory depends on several assumptions, however. Monetary
policymakers must have considerable knowledge about the impact of their
actions on other interest rates; about the lags involved before
businesses and households respond to rising rates; and about whether and
how much real interest rates--rather than just nominal rates--are
changing. As there is no historical experience employing these tools,
there is no basis for assessing their effectiveness. Central banks have
demonstrably failed to achieve their objective of higher inflation
during the past five years; their tools to contain any inflation that
emerges are untested.
The risk posed by the enormous central bank balance sheet is that
the willingness of commercial banks to hold idle balances (even those
earning some administered rate of interest) will decline. Of course,
while any individual commercial bank can take actions to reduce its
holdings of "excess" reserves, the banking system as a whole
cannot do so. Without a corresponding reduction in the securities held
by the central bank as assets, "excess" reserves can decline
only if they become "required" reserves. This suggests two
possibilities: either Congress can authorize a substantial increase in
administered reserve requirement ratios; or an extraordinary increase in
reservable deposit liabilities of commercial banks absorbs the excess.
The second option would certainly involve a hyperinflationary increase
in the money supply. What are the odds of that?
Commercial bank deposit liabilities are now a function of the
supply of earning assets--both domestic and foreign--offered to
commercial banks. In other words, the quantity of "inside
money" created by the banking system depends on the demand for bank
loans and the aggregate supply of government bonds,
mortgage-backed-securities, and other suitable instruments available for
acquisition by banks. A forecast of deposit growth--and the money
supply--must be derived from a forecast of the supply of (and yields on)
earning assets offered to the banking system. That includes forecasts of
government budget deficits that must be financed, as well as the prices
of commercial and residential real estate against which mortgage
securities can be created. The knowledge necessary to make confident
forecasts cannot be obtained from historical experience.
Conclusion
For several years, major central banks have pronounced that the
objective of massive quantitative easing was to raise the inflation
rate. That objective has not been achieved despite the quadrupling (in
the case of the United States) of the central bank balance sheet.
Because commercial banks are no longer reserve constrained, the
historical linkage between the central bank balance sheet (the monetary
base) and the outstanding money supply has been broken. Changes in the
size and composition of the central bank's assets and liabilities
are thus unrelated to the amount of money in circulation. Without the
ability to influence the supply of money, central bank open market
operations have no influence on the rate of inflation. Announced changes
in the federal funds rate therefore have no implications for economic
activity, or the rate of inflation.
If inflation should emerge, central banks will have no tools for
countering the pace at which the purchasing power of money declines. In
the early stages of past periods of accelerating inflation, central
banks mistakenly expanded their balance sheets as they "leaned
against" the trend of rising nominal interest rates, failing to see
that an "inflation premium" was being incorporated by both
lenders and borrowers. In other words, monetary authorities' policy
actions were "accommodative" of rising prices. For the
foreseeable future, however, no such accommodation will be necessary.
Ballooning central bank balance sheets are more than sufficient to fuel
extreme rates of inflation without further debt monetization. This is
not a forecast that inflation will in fact occur. It simply is a
statement of the new reality: whether or not there is inflation is
unrelated to anything central banks do or do not do.
References
Brunner, K. and Meltzer, A. H. (1972) "Money, Debt, and
Economic Activity." Journal of Political Economy 80 (5): 951-77.
Jordan, J. L. (2014) "A Century of Central Banking: What Have
We Learned?" Cato Journal 34 (2): 213-27.
Walker, M. (2016) "Why Are Interest Rates So Low? A Framework
for Modeling Current Global Financial Developments." Vancouver
B.C.: Fraser Institute.
Williamson, S. D. (2015) "Current Federal Reserve Policy under
the Lens of Economic History: A Review Essay." Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis Working Paper No. 2015-015A. Available at
https://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2015/2015-015.pdf.
(1) A peculiarity of U.S. national income accounting is that in the
government's budget, the line for interest expense on the national
debt includes the amount paid to the Federal Reserve Banks as interest
on the bonds held in the central bank's portfolio. When the central
bank returns the net interest earned to the Treasury, it is reported as
part of "corporate profits." The reason is that the Federal
Reserve Banks are technically private corporations. The effect of these
accounting entries is to overstate the net interest expense on the
national debt and to overstate corporate profits. In 2014, the Federal
Reserve Banks' income (and the amount returned to the Treasury)
exceeded $100 billion.
(2) See Williamson (2015:10): "A Taylor-rule central banker
may be convinced that lowering the central bank's nominal interest
rate target will increase inflation. This can lead to a situation in
which the central banker becomes permanently trapped in ZIRP. With the
nominal interest rate at zero for a long period of time, inflation is
low, and the central banker reasons that maintaining ZIRP will
eventually increase the inflation rate. But this never happens and, as
long as the central banker adheres to a sufficiently aggressive Taylor
rule, ZIRP will continue forever, and the central bank will fall short
of its inflation target indefinitely. This idea seems to fit nicely with
the recent observed behavior of the world's central banks."
(3) In December 2016, the monetary authorities announced an
increase in the interest on reserve balances to 50 basis points.
Jerry L. Jordan is former President of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. He served on President Reagan's Council of Economic
Advisers and was a member of the U.S. Gold Commission.