What monetary policy can do.
Lacker, Jeffrey M.
Thank you for the opportunity to participate in this discussion on
monetary policy and what it can and can't do. In thinking about
this topic, it occurred to me that one side of the question--what it
can't do--generates a very long list. So for today's
discussion, I intend to focus on the positive and discuss the one thing
that I think we should be pretty certain monetary policy can indeed do,
and that is to determine the long-run path of the price level. Recent
experience has caused some to question whether monetary policy's
ability to achieve even this modest goal has diminished or been lost in
the years since the Great Recession. I will argue that a central
bank's ability to influence inflation and how it does so is
essentially unchanged. I also believe that monetary policy's
ability to affect inflation is essentially independent of its effects on
real economic activity, which I view as limited and temporary. My view
of what monetary policy can do is based on the (perhaps old-fashioned)
idea that money creation is at the heart of price level determination.
A Basic Framework
I take as my starting point that monetary policy is uniquely
capable of affecting the price level over the longer term. Indeed, in
the benchmark classical (or neoclassical) economic model without some
form of friction--in which money is neutral--the price level is all that
monetary policy will affect. The price level, after all, is simply the
rate of exchange between money and goods. So the quantity of money must
be related to how much of the latter each unit can buy. How to match the
quantity of money in a theoretical model to a particular empirical
measure of money is not always straightforward. But the ability of
monetary policy to affect the price level, or the rate of inflation,
over time is a natural starting point and one that is embedded in the
Federal Open Market Committee's statement concerning its long-term
goals (Board of Governors 2012/2015).
In contrast, monetary policy's ability to affect real economic
activity--when monetary policy is being reasonably well-executed--can be
quite limited and is almost always short lived (Friedman 1968). Real
activity is driven predominantly by factors beyond the control of
monetary policy--productivity and population growth, for example. In the
standard models used in policy analysis, monetary policy's real
effects generally derive from frictions that impede the rapid adjustment
of the overall level of the price. Such frictions are, almost always,
short-run phenomena that generate transitory deviations in real
activity, and their empirical significance is a matter of ongoing
research and debate. It is true that egregious monetary policy errors
can seriously damage the economy--for instance, by adding extraneous
volatility and reducing the informativeness of relative price signals.
But in typical circumstances, monetary policy that successfully
stabilizes inflation and inflation expectations will have only modest,
temporary effects on real activity.
The mechanism through which monetary policy has its ultimate effect
on the price level is through the process of money creation--that is,
the process by which central bank actions affect the distinct forms of
money, such as bank deposits, that people use in transactions for goods
and services. It is more common these days to think of monetary policy
as setting an interest rate target, rather than a money supply, in part
because money demand seems to fluctuate significantly (Goodfriend 1991).
Nonetheless, prior to 2008, the Fed achieved its target for the federal
funds rate--the price of overnight loan of reserves--by manipulating the
supply of bank reserves. Reductions in the Fed's interest rate
target necessitated increases in the supply of bank reserves. The
resulting money creation--by the central bank and the private banking
system--in turn drives price-level determination.
If frictions in goods or financial markets impede price adjustment,
then monetary policy may temporarily affect real economic activity along
with the price level. In particular, a low interest rate policy will
tend to stimulate real activity for a time. These effects can give rise
to an empirical correlation between the observed behavior of inflation
and real economic activity. Such correlations are often referred to as
the Phillips curve relationship--resource utilization or real activity
positively correlated with inflation.
It is important to note, however, that the standard framework for
understanding monetary policy transmission is inconsistent with a
popular interpretation of the Phillips curve, which is that a low
interest rate raises inflation because the stimulation of real activity
puts upward pressure on (real) resource costs. For example, one
sometimes hears that high rates of resource utilization lead to rising
inflation. Or that an empirical breakdown in the Phillips curve
relationship makes it harder for the Fed to bring inflation back toward
our 2 percent objective.
This reasoning is fundamentally flawed. Monetary policy does not
affect inflation through its effect on real activity. Monetary policy
affects inflation and real activity simultaneously. If the relevant
frictions are minimal, so that monetary policy has little effect on real
activity, inflation is still driven directly by monetary policy. So a
weak Phillips curve relationship does not imply that monetary policy has
any less influence over inflation.
Recent Experience
Reconciling the behavior of monetary measures with the behavior of
inflation has been more difficult since the crisis. The dramatic
increase in the Fed's monetary liabilities after 2008--from just
under $1 trillion to over $4 trillion now--has led to dire warnings from
some critics that surging inflation was imminent. That hasn't
happened. Inflation has not only failed to rise, but has been
persistently low relative to the FOMC's stated goal of 2 percent.
The last reading of 2 percent or greater for the 12-month change in the
personal consumption price index was in April 2012, and since 2013, the
core index has fluctuated between 1.2 and 1.6 percent.
In fact, some argue that the zero lower bound on interest rates has
been interfering with the Fed's ability to keep inflation from
falling. This is based on the idea, widely attributed to Swedish
economist Knut Wicksell, that keeping inflation close to our objective
requires that the real short-term interest rate should track the
economy's underlying "natural" real rate of interest
(Woodford 2003, Wicksell 1936). Because the Fed's nominal interest
rate target has been constrained by zero, policy might be
disinflationary if the natural real rate has fallen significantly.
This hypothesis is more difficult to assess, because the natural
real interest rate is not directly observable, and so independent
measurements naturally depend on auxiliary assumptions and theories. At
this point, there is a fair amount of uncertainty around common
estimates, but most estimates of the natural rate of interest in the
United States have clustered at or just above zero, well above the
actual real funds rate, which has been running below negative 1 (Lubik
and Matthes 2015, Laubach and Williams 2003). So at this point, a
Wicksellian perspective does not suggest that the zero lower bound is
impeding the Fed's ability to attain its 2 percent inflation
objective. In fact, this perspective bolsters the case for raising the
federal funds rate target now.
Moreover, the actual behavior of inflation in recent years does not
warrant such pessimism. Statistically speaking, inflation appears to
have some slow-moving components, which allow it to stray sometimes for
extended periods from its longer-run trend. In other words, inflation
does not seem to behave as if each year's result is a roll of the
dice, unconnected from last year's experience. Given the historical
behavior of inflation in recent decades--a period of time when the Fed
is widely considered to have achieved stability of inflation and
inflation expectations--an extended, one-sided deviation like the one we
are currently experiencing turns out to be not unlikely (Hornstein,
Johnson, and Rhodes 2015). So I don't think the recent behavior of
inflation implies a more permanent departure from our target.
The persistent part of inflation has been modeled by some as a
random walk component, which would seem to imply a process that is not
well-anchored in the long run by the central bank's objective. That
is, it would seem to imply that inflation can drift permanently away
from the central bank's objective. But this specification is hard
to distinguish statistically from one in which inflation does move,
perhaps slowly, toward a better anchored long-run expectation (Faust and
Leeper 2015, Faust and Wright 2013). While a description like this pins
down the longer-run behavior of inflation, it leaves inflation at higher
frequencies to move around, perhaps in response to a variety of relative
price shocks.
With this statistical behavior, monetary policy's ability to
control inflation rests, in part, on its ability to stabilize longer-run
inflation expectations. The Fed established credibility for long-term
inflation, in the sense of stabilizing expectations, in the 1990s--the
culmination of a process that began with the Volcker disinflation in the
early 1980s. And our available measures suggest that expectations have
remained well-anchored for most of the period since the recession.
While it is conceivable that the central bank could anchor
expectations and the long-run behavior of inflation simply by stating a
goal, it is more likely that the credibility of the goal depends on the
public's belief that the central bank has and will use the tools
necessary to make inflation return to its goal, should that become
necessary. So we should look again to the mechanism through which
central bank actions affect money creation and ultimately the price
level, taking into account how the monetary policy toolkit has changed
since the financial crisis.
The New Monetary Policy Environment
The second reason I am not pessimistic about the ability of
monetary policy to ultimately control inflation has to do with the
mechanics of monetary policy. Allow me to explain. In the standard
model, monetary policy operations were premised on the actual
arrangements in place prior to the financial crisis. The Federal Reserve
controlled the quantity of its monetary liabilities, consisting of
currency and bank reserves. Both were noninterest bearing. The quantity
demanded for each was a downward-sloping function of the short-term
nominal interest rate. The Federal Reserve controlled the overall supply
of its liabilities through open market operations in order to achieve a
target level for the short-term interest rate, set by the Federal Open
Market Committee. To lower rates, for example, the supply of monetary
liabilities would be increased, making bank reserves less scarce.
This picture changed as a result of the crisis. Reserve account
balances now earn explicit interest at a rate set by the Federal
Reserve, and, as I noted earlier, the supply of bank reserves has
increased dramatically. So the mechanics of monetary policy are
necessarily different from what they were in the decades before the
Great Recession.
Some economists have argued that in the current regime, bank
reserves are perfect substitutes for short-term Treasury securities, and
that as a result, monetary policy may be relatively impotent (Cochrane
2014). Open market purchases of U.S. Treasury securities are just
exchanges of one liquid government liability for another. Financial
institutions will simply hold fewer Treasury securities and more bank
reserves, leaving economic activity unaffected.
This neglects a key characteristic of bank reserves, however. While
Treasury securities can be held by any financial entity, bank reserves
can only be held by banks. (1) The banking system can shed other assets
in order to accommodate larger reserve account balances, but there is an
upper limit to this process. At some point, banks would have to raise
more capital in order to accommodate higher reserve account balances.
This would force broader changes in portfolios that would inevitably
affect economic outcomes, including the price level.
Richmond Fed economist Huberto Ennis (2014) has provided an
explicit model that captures this logic. The intuition is that when the
quantity of bank reserves is small enough and interest rates are above
the interest rate the central bank pays on excess reserves, then price
level determination works the usual way. When the quantity of bank
reserves is large enough, bank balance sheets are forced to adjust, and
again, the quantity of central bank liabilities directly affects the
price level. In between, however, there is a broad zone in which the
quantity of bank reserves can vary without affecting the price level.
This basic story seems consistent with the difficulty of finding
conclusive evidence of economic effects from the Fed's large-scale
asset purchases. It seems plausible that successive rounds of
quantitative easing have had little or no tangible effect, apart from
signaling regarding the FOMC's outlook for future economic growth
and policy settings. At the same time, this framework implies that large
enough asset purchases would compel changes in bank balance sheets that
would in turn affect economic outcomes. This analysis bolsters my
confidence that the intuition of the standard approach remains relevant
and monetary policy still has the capacity to determine inflation and
the price level over time.
Conclusion
Therefore, I continue to hold the view, as expressed in the
FOMC's statement of long-term goals, that monetary policy has the
unique ability to determine inflation over time. That ability is
independent of whether or not there is a reliable Phillips curve
correlation. Moreover, it remains true in a world with interest on
reserves and large bank reserve account balances. The effect of monetary
policy on real activity, on the other hand, is likely to be transitory,
which suggests caution in trying to use monetary policy to have
significant real effects over the medium term. Even more caution should
apply, given the state of our understanding, to the notion that monetary
policy should respond to signals of incipient financial instability, an
idea that has received considerable attention since the crisis.
Conducting monetary policy to achieve low and stable inflation over
time, without doing damage to real activity, is hard enough.
References
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2012/2015)
"Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy."
Adopted January 24, 2012, amended January 27, 2015.
Cochrane, J. (2014) "A Few Things the Fed Has Done
Right." Wall Street Journal (21 August).
Ennis, H. (2014) "A Simple General Equilibrium Model of Large
Excess Reserves." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper
No. 14-14 (July).
Faust, J., and Leeper, E. M. (2015) "The Myth of Normal: The
Bumpy Story of Inflation and Monetary Policy." Paper presented at
the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City's Jackson Hole Symposium
(August).
Faust, J., and Wright, J. (2013) "Forecasting Inflation."
In G. Elliott and A. Timmerman (eds.) Handbook of Economic Forecasting.
Vol. 2A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Friedman, M. (1968) "The Role of Monetary Policy."
American Economic Review 58 (1): 1-17.
Goodfriend, M. (1991) "Interest Rates and the Conduct of
Monetary Policy." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public
Policy 34 (Spring): 7-30.
Hornstein, A.; Johnson, J.; and Rhodes, K. (2015) "Inflation
Targeting: Could Bad Luck Explain Persistent One-Sided Misses?"
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Brief No. 15-09 (September).
Laubach, T., and Williams, J. C. (2003) "Measuring the Natural
Rate of Interest." Review of Economics and Statistics 85 (4):
1063-70.
Lubik, T. A., and Matthes, C. (2015) "Calculating the Natural
Rate of Interest: A Comparison of Two Alternative Approaches."
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Brief No. 15-10 (October).
Wicksell, K. ([1898] 1936) Interest and Prices: A Study of the
Causes Regulating the Value of Money. London: Macmillan.
Woodford, M. (2003) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of
Monetary Policy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
(1) Basically, only depository institutions, government agencies,
and government-sponsored enterprises can hold accounts at Federal
Reserve banks.
Jeffrey M. Lacker is President and CEO of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond and serves on the Federal Open Market Committee. This
article is based on his remarks at the Cato Institute's 33rd Annual
Monetary Conference, Rethinking Monetary Policy," November 12,
2015. The views presented here are the author's and do not
necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve System or any other
members of the FOMC.