Behavioral economics and Fed policymaking.
Calabria, Mark A.
For every bias identified for individuals, there is an accompanying
bias in the public sphere.
--Cass Sunstein (2014:102)
Behavioral economics has continued to gain momentum in challenging
the standard rational actor model in economics. With a few exceptions,
the emphasis has been on the cognitive failure of individuals outside of
government. Niclas Berggren (2013: 200) estimates that 95.5 percent of
behavioral economics articles in the leading economics journals do not
contain an analysis of the cognitive ability of policymakers. In this
article, I offer a preliminary analysis of potential cognitive failures
in the Federal Reserve's conduct of monetary policy. Proposals to
"debias" monetary policymaking are offered, along with a
discussion of how the Fed's existing institutional structure
ameliorates or exasperates potential biases.
Behavioral Economics in Monetary Policy
Initial attempts to incorporate behavioral economics into monetary
policy focused on how policymakers might better account for the
behavioral biases of market participants, especially in the area of
price and wage setting (Rotemberg 2008: 34-36). Behavioral economics has
been used to provide a new rationale for reliance on a Phillips curve
framework, as well as to place greater weight on unemployment. As Janet
Yellen (2007: 15) has stated, "Behavioral macroeconomic models also
provide theoretical underpinnings for the view held by most policymakers
that, in the short run, monetaiy policy can and should strive to
stabilize the real economy." More recent scholars (e.g., Orphanides
2015) have attempted to explain the Federal Reserve's own actions
via the lens of behavioral economics. Those efforts are extended in this
article.
Are policymakers at the Fed likely to experience cognitive
failures? DellaVigna (2009: 364) has argued that politicians "are
experienced agents facing high-stake incentives and significant
competition" suggesting that at least some elements of the
political realm are less susceptible to cognitive failure than
households. Setting aside whether DellaVigna's characterization of
politicians is accurate, the question of competition and experience has
been demonstrated to reduce cognitive failure (List 2003, 2004).
However, while there may be some modest choice among currencies, the Fed
has few, if any, real equals. The level of competition facing the Fed
does not even approach that likely necessary to serve as an effective
feedback mechanism.
If competition is unlikely to exist in sufficient degree to
eliminate cognitive failures at the Fed, will experience suffice?
Members of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) are often
professional economists and usually quite advanced in their careers.
They serve long terms (in principle, at least). On the other hand,
economic crises are, thankfully, not a frequent occurrence. This means
that policymakers rarely have the opportunity to learn from them.
Federal Reserve Chair G. William Miller stated as much during an FOMC
meeting in December 1978 (quoted in Abolafia 2012: 99):
Boston Fed President Frank Morris: Mr. Chairman, I don't think
we understand what is really going on in the economy.
Chairman Miller: I'll go along with that.
President Morris: I think it's because we haven't had
enough experience judging the reaction of both the consumer and the
investor to an economy with a high rate of inflation.
Chairman Miller: That's right, we haven't had any
experience.
While Morris and Miller found themselves in an environment of
unusually high inflation, other periods have found policymakers
wondering how to maneuver in an environment of unusually low inflation
(Akerlof, Dickens, and Perry 1996: 50-52). I shall return to this point
in more detail below, but both statements from policymakers and the
broad economic trends suggest experience alone will be insufficient to
eliminate any behavioral biases among policymakers.
Potential Biases in Monetary Policy
Cognitive science has identified a number of potential
decisionmaking biases. Some are more robust than others. Below, I
discuss the following biases: availability bias, representativeness
bias, status quo bias, loss aversion, and overconfidence. I also offer
examples of how each of these may be present in monetary policymaking.
The discussion is in no way exhaustive, but rather focuses on the most
likely biases, as well as those for which we have some evidence. There
remains considerable room for additional research into these and other
cognitive biases and their related impact on monetary policy decisions.
Availability Bias
When asked to consider the frequency of possible outcomes,
individuals often quickly go to what they can remember about similar
situations. Ask any New Yorker about terrorist attacks and 9/11 is
unlikely to be far from mind. Ask an economist about inflation and you
may well get a lecture on the Great Inflation of the 1970s. Ask about a
stock market bust, and you might get the answer "1929." Ask
about when allowing a large hedge fund to fail resulted in a collective
financial yawn and you might get a puzzled look (think "Amaranth
Advisors LLC"). Where an answer comes easily ("1929")
there is a tendency to overestimate the frequency of such events,
whereas when an answer requires some research or consideration
("Amaranth") the frequencies tend to be more accurately
estimated or even underestimated. This is the heart of availability bias
(Tversky and Kahneman 1973: 16.3-65.).
Monetaiy authorities must often make quick decisions. Should
institution X be saved before the markets open in Asia on Monday
morning? Will the smallest sign of deflation (or inflation) spiral
out-of-control? Will the large scale purchase of assets stimulate
lending and the economy? While there will be, of course, some analysis
conducted on these questions, it would not be too ungenerous to describe
some actions by the Fed as "spur of the moment." Witness the
ever-changing rationales given for denying assistance to Lehman
Brothers.
Given the handful of almost mythical events in the history of
monetary policy and financial crises, it is perhaps not surprising that
these same events dominate discussions of policy. Federal Reserve Chair
Ben Bernanke has occasionally been called the "perfect man"
for the 2008 crisis, because of his long study of the Great Depression.
But this assumes we were facing another Great Depression. As it's
impossible to know whether that was actually the case in 2008, it is not
a stretch to conclude that, given the actions ultimately taken, the
implied probabilities of another Great Depression were magnitudes higher
than the actual probability. There may be no bigger availability
heuristic in macroeconomics than the Great Depression. In all
likelihood, especially given their perceived failure to act
appropriately in the 1930s, the Fed is operating under a number of
availability biases.
Representativeness Bias
Financial and monetary policy decisions can be vulnerable to
generalizations. Once we conclude that entity X has characteristic Y,
and that entity X is a member of set Z, we may assume that all members
of Z have characteristic Y. A common example of this is the stereotype
that people who wear glasses are intelligent.
One possible example from Fed behavior is the belief that if bank A
is experiencing an outflow of deposits then all other banks must also be
experiencing an outflow of deposits (and therefore the broad provision
of liquidity is necessary). Yet this assumes a degree of homogeneity
across banks that may not be warranted. Without some investigation
(preferably with a large sample), one cannot know whether liquidity or
solvency pressures at a single institution (or a small handful of them)
represents a larger systemic problem. In some cases, such as the Savings
and Loan Crisis, individual problem institutions were largely
representative; in the recent crisis, on the other hand, there is good
reason to believe that troubled institutions were the exception rather
than the rule. If the Fed fails to accurately gauge representativeness,
it may unintentionally reduce the transfer of activity from poorly
managed institutions to better-run institutions.
Representativeness bias can also impact the conduct of monetary
policy. Is an increase in energy or home prices indicative of coming
broader price increases? Does a slowdown in manufacturing employment in
Cleveland portend a larger trend? These are the sorts of questions that
face the Fed on a constant basis. Of course there are attempts at
minimizing representativeness bias, such as focusing on consumer prices
excluding housing and energy, as well as looking at other price indexes
besides the consumer price index. Nevertheless, the finding that the
voting patterns of Federal Reserve governors are influenced by which
district they came from offers evidence consistent with
representativeness bias (Meade and Sheets 2005: 676). Such potential
bias can be offset by having a diversity of geographic backgrounds
represented on the Roard of Governors. However, geographic diversity
alone may not be sufficient to offset representativeness bias if Fed
governors and regional presidents travel in similar social circles.
Complaints about a perceived closeness to banks are in part a concern
about representativeness bias.
Status Quo Bias
Even when circumstances dramatically change, we sometimes maintain
the same course of action, discounting or even ignoring new information.
Kahneman and Tversky (1982) argue that individuals feel greater regret
for bad outcomes that result from new actions being taken than they do
for bad outcomes that result from inaction. Samuelson and Zeckhauser
(1988: 35-36) argue that status quo bias is consistent with loss
aversion, as well as sunk cost thinking. Relatedly, procrastination can
lead policymakers to delay taking important actions. Orphanides (2015:
183-86) suggests that procrastination may explain the Federal
Reserve's current "fear of liftoff'-- the reluctance to
normalize its policy stance despite considerable evidence it should do
so.
Loss Aversion
One of the strongest, if not the strongest, finding in experimental
behavioral economics is that individuals appear to weight potential
losses much higher than potential gains. One result of loss aversion is
that when gains and losses are symmetric or nearly so, risk aversion may
set in. Loss aversion is the general explanation for the "endowment
effect"--that is, the hypothesis that individuals value an object
more simply because they already own it.
Loss aversion can be found in multiple contexts in monetary policy.
The "hard fought" battle against the Great Inflation, for
instance, might cause a bias against policies that risk greater
inflation. On the other hand, moving to tighter policy late in a
recovery could be viewed as jeopardizing gains in employment or asset
values. Policy goals, especially when given numeric expression, may
serve as reference points from which gains and losses are measured. For
instance, there is nothing that is particularly special about an
inflation rate of 2 percent, yet policymakers' often expressed goal
of hitting a 2 percent inflation target frames deviations from that
rate, either below or above, as a loss. The same could hold with an
unemployment rate target, although deviations below a specific
unemployment target are rarely framed as losses. Witness, for example,
the abandonment of the so-called "Evans rule" once
unemployment broke its target of 6.5 percent (see Boesler 2014). To some
degree, debates over whether the Fed should "consult" a policy
rule and report deviations from it rests on an assumption that loss
aversion will bias the policymakers toward following the rule even when
deviations would be optimal.
Overconfidence
Another common finding in behavioral studies is that individuals
regularly offer estimates of their own ability, competence, or judgement
that far exceed an objective assessment. One example of overconfidence
is the bias of illusionary superiority, sometimes called the "Lake
Wobegon effect" (in which all children are above average).
Overconfidence is not limited to the layperson, but has also been
repeatedly found among experts. Most relevant for monetary policy is the
finding that even economists are subject to overconfidence. (1)
Policymakers at the Fed may fall victim to overconfidence in managing
the macroeconomy in terms of timing, magnitude, and even the qualitative
impact of interventions. Overconfidence can result in Fed actions that
are at times "too little" but at other times "too
much." Too little intervention can result when policymakers believe
their actions will have larger effects than objective analysis would
indicate. Overconfidence can, for instance, cause problems when relying
on interest rates to gauge the stance of monetary policy: low rates
might mean that policy is easy, but they could also signal a weak
economy. In addition, policymakers may also overestimate their ability
to unwind an aggressive policy stance.
The presence of overconfidence may not offer conclusive guidance on
which particular policies to follow, but it should suggest a greater
degree of modesty in forecasting the impacts of those policies, as well
as our ability to reverse them.
Can Expertise Overcome Bias?
Despite the possibility of widespread cognitive failures, modern
American society largely manages to function. Arguably, it does so
relatively well. One avenue for overcoming bias is to rely on those with
expertise and experience in a particular field. Although experts suffer
from biases like the rest of us, they also have greater opportunities
for learning and adjusting to their biases. Some evidence suggests that
in the presence of appropriate incentives, such learning does occur
(Camerer and Hogarth 1999: 12-13). What is the likelihood that expertise
can overcome bias in the realm of Federal Reserve monetary policymaking?
As Daniel Kahneman (2011) has observed, experts suffer from all
sorts of biases that result in bad decisions and outcomes. Building upon
the work of Paul Meehl (1954), Kahneman argues that experts are inferior
to simple algorithms (like a Taylor Rule) because experts "try to
be clever, think outside the box, and consider complex combinations of
features in making their predictions" (Kahneman 2011: 224). In the
studies reviewed and sometimes conducted by Kahneman, experts are always
looking for that one additional data point that suggests a different
course of action. We see that today, with the Fed claiming its decisions
will be "data dependent," but not telling us what data they
will be dependent upon, or how different data will be weighted. Kahneman
also notes that experts are inconsistent, giving different answers to
the same (or similar) question. This characteristic may be especially
damaging in relaying to market participants the direction of monetary
policy. Kahneman (2011: 225) summarized his research with a
"surprising" conclusion: "To maximize predictive
accuracy, final decisions should be left to formulas, especially in
low-validity environments."
Kahneman and psychologist Gary Klein have investigated which
conditions are conducive to relying on the discretion of experts and
which are not. It is not surprising that the Fed often characterizes
itself as a "firefighter." Scholars have indeed found that
seasoned firefighters have good intuition about things like when the
floor of a burning building is about to collapse (Klein 2003).
Kahneman's research, however, finds that these expert skills are
built up over time. Novice firefighters do not display the same skills
as veterans. This could be one justification for the long terms (14
years) allowed for Fed governors. But most Fed governors do not serve
anywhere near that long. The average number of years of experience for
FOMC members is just over six years (Woolley and Gardner 2009: 10). As
financial crises and turning points in the economy happen less often
than that--close to every 13 years in the United States for crises,
according to Reinhart and Rogoff (2011)--the fact is that few Fed
governors will operate in more than one or two crises. Nor are they even
likely to operate in more than one or two inflections in the
macroeconomy.
Monetary policy is also inherently subject to unpredictability. As
Milton Friedman (1961: 447) observed, monetary policy operates with
"long and variable lags." This is one reason why the Fed often
ends up promising specific outcomes that subsequently fail to
materialize. The very complexity and unpredictability of monetary policy
suggests that the Fed would be more accountable if it were rule-bound.
To summarize these findings, experts can be relied upon when (1)
they operate in a regular, predictable environment, and (2) there is an
opportunity for learning via repeated practice. Neither of these
conditions characterize monetary policy. Behavioral economics has
sometimes been presented as an avenue to justify government intervention
to correct the failing of ordinary people. Yet the same literature
reminds us that policymakers, even experts, also suffer from a variety
of biases. Just as default rules may be useful in minimizing consumer
errors, they are also likely to be useful in minimizing monetary errors.
Mechanisms to Remove Bias
Although the quantitative impact of cognitive biases on monetary
policy is difficult to measure with any precision, the historical
record, including statements from FOMC members, suggests that cognitive
biases may have a substantial influence on the conduct of monetary
policy. Given this possibility, coupled with the importance of monetary
policy to macroeconomic stability, I suggest below a number of avenues
for reducing the impact of cognitive biases.
Rules-Bound Monetary Policy
The "rules versus discretion" debate in monetary
economics has traditionally focused upon the time inconsistency of
policymaking. The problem is that in the short run "surprise"
inflations by a central bank may produce increases in employment and
output. Over time, however, market participants come to anticipate this
inflation with employment and output reverting to baseline. The result
is higher inflation but no long-run improvement in either employment or
output. Rules-based policy that limited the choices of policymakers
could resolve this time inconsistency.
Given the stagflation of the 1970s, it is not surprising that era
also witnessed a rebirth in the economic debates over rules versus
discretion in monetary policy, most associated with the work of Calvo
(1978), Kydland and Prescott (1979), Barro and Gordon (1983a, 1983b),
McCallum (1984), and Taylor (1985). This body of work largely assumes
that policymakers are rational and that errors are the result of
misaligned incentives. (2)
Orphanides (2015: 184-88) has suggested that cognitive biases among
policymakers provide an argument for monetary rules. Kahneman (2011), as
discussed above, specifies die conditions under which rules are
preferred to expert discretion. These conditions would appear to
characterize monetary policymaking. Accordingly, requiring an explicit
monetary rule, or that deviations from rules be explained, offers
considerable potential to minimize the impact of cognitive biases among
FOMC members. Further research is warranted on whether different rules
are more or less susceptible to inducing their own biases and reducing
preexisting biases.
Decisionmaking within Committees
The primary focus of behavioral economics has been on individual
decisionmaking, yet monetary policy is often, although far from
exclusively, conducted by committee. Blinder and Morgan (2005: 800-1)
suggest that, in the context of monetary policy, group decisions are
superior to individual decisions. Bainbridge (2002) provides an
extensive overview of the behavioral arguments in favor of board
decisionmaking relative to individual decisionmaking. For a skeptical
view see Sunstein and Hastie (2008).
The difference in these findings may be explained by the structure
and composition of the board in question. If a board is constituted of
like-minded individuals with similar backgrounds and experiences, then
groupthink and confirmation bias become significant risks (see
Schulz-Hardt et al. 2000: 666-67). The modern dominance of central banks
by economists, for instance, has likely narrowed the range of
deliberation and may have contributed to the observed decline in time
spent on deliberation (Woolley and Gardner 2009: 1.5-18). That FOMC
members increasingly come from the same geographic areas could also be
contributing to a reduction in deliberation and an increase in
groupthink. Sunstein (2002: 5) has suggested that "social pressures
are likely to lead groups of like-minded people to extreme
positions."
Following Sunstein (2002: 5), if we are to expect committees to be
effective at reducing cognitive biases in monetary policy, there must be
sufficient encouragement for dissent. The Federal Reserve, in contrast,
is well known for its history of discouraging formal dissent. Former
Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank President Narayana Kocherlakota (2016)
recently argued that "consensus creates a strong status quo bias
that reduces the sensitivity of monetary policy to incoming data."
At a minimum, the FOMC should transition to a norm that encourages
greater dissent.
Increased diversity--in terms of views represented on the FOMC--may
require legislation. Specifically, the requirements of Section 10 of the
Federal Reserve Act should be updated to increase geographic, as well as
occupational, diversity (Calabria 2016).
Overall, the behavioral literature provides some support for
concluding that committees can potentially reduce cognitive biases.
However, the same literature offers sufficient reason to question
whether that finding is robust to committee structure and composition.
Adversarial Review of Monetary Policy
A number of scholars have suggested that adversarial review, either
judicial or congressional, can reduce behavioral biases in agency
decisionmaking (see Seidenfeld 2002; Babcock, Lowenstein, and
Issacharoff 1997). If policymakers know ex ante that they will later
have to defend their choices, increased deliberation may occur. Third
party review could also help in the sense that biases may be more
transparent to others than to die biased decisionmakers. If the third
party is a nonexpert, policymakers may be forced to more thoroughly
examine their own choices in order to explain them satisfactorily.
The perceived reduction in deliberation among monetary policymakers
may be related to the increased dominance of the Federal Reserve by
economists. Economists deliberating among themselves will generally take
for granted a number of assumptions which noneconomists will not. If
these assumptions are in error and critical to the deliberations, the
lack of scrutiny could greatly undermine the quality of monetary
policymaking.
Most agency decisions are and should be subject to judicial review.
Monetary policy is notably one that is not. Nor, indeed, is it likely to
be. Whether it should be is an interesting question, but one which falls
outside the scope of this article. The lack of judicial review does
suggest, however, that monetary policy is subject to fewer checks than
other agency actions. There is congressional review, which has generally
been seen as rather ineffective. A potential avenue for reform is die
proposal to subject monetary policy decisions to review by the
Government Accountability Office (GAO). Having to regularly explain
their actions to the GAO may well reduce cognitive bias among members of
the FOMC, and so increase the quality of deliberations. A GAO audit
could also increase die quality of deliberations at die biannual
congressional monetary oversight hearings.
Conclusion
Members of the FOMC are human. Along with that humanity come a
number of cognitive biases and limitations that can affect the conduct
of monetary policy. Whether such biases have indeed affected policy
remains an open empirical question, but anecdotal evidence, as well as
actual comments from FOMC members, suggests that cognitive biases do
impact FOMC decisions. I have attempted here a preliminary sketch of
some of these potential biases, along with proposed institutional
changes that could reduce their impact. The policy that offers the
greatest potential for reducing biases is a move toward greater reliance
on rules-based decisionmaking. It should also be recognized, based on
the extensive work of Gerd Gigerenzer and others (e.g., Gigerenzer and
Gaissmaier 2011), that heuristic decisionmaking can deliver better
results than extensive deliberation. However, for the reasons presented
above, its usefulness may be less applicable to monetary policy.
References
Abolafia, M. Y. (2012) "Central Banking and the Triumph of
Technical Rationality." In K. K. Cetina and A. Preda (eds.), The
Oxford Handbook of the Sociology of Finance, 94-112. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Akerlof, G.; Dickens, W.; and Perry, G. (1996) "The
Macroeconomics of Low Inflation." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity (1): 1-72.
Alesina, A.; Stella, A.; Friedman, B.; and Woodford, M. (2011)
"The Politics of Monetary Policy." Handbook of Monetary
Economics, 1000-54. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Angner, E. (2006) "Economists as Experts: Overconfidence in
Theory and Practice." Journal of Economic Methodology 13 (1): 1-24.
Babcock, L.; Loewenstein, G.; and Issacharoff, S. (1997) "Creating
Convergence: Debiasing Biased Litigants." Law and Social Inquiry 22
(4): 913-25.
Bainbridge, S. (2002) "Wlly a Board? Group Decisionmaking in
Corporate Governance." Vanderbilt Law Review 55 (1): 1-55. Barro,
R., and Gordon, D. (1983a) "Rules, Discretion, and Reputation in a
Model of Monetary Policy." Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (1):
101-21
--(1983b) "A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a
Natural-Rate Model." Journal of Political Economy 91 (4): 589-610.
Berggren, N. (2013) "Time for Behavioral Political Economy? An
Analysis of Articles in Behavioral Economics." Review of Austrian
Economics 25 (3): 199-221.
Blinder, A., and Morgan, J. (2005) "Are Two Heads Better Than
One? Monetary Poliey by Committee." Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking 37 (5): 789-811.
Boesler, M. (2014) "Fed Ditches Evans Rule." Business
Insider (March 19). Available at
www.businessinsider.com/march-fomcstatement-2014-3.
Calabria, M. A. (2016) "Yes, the Federal Reserve Has a
Diversity Problem." Alt-M (June 23).
Calvo, G. (1978) "On the Time Consistency of Optimal Policy in
a Monetary Economy." Econometrica 46 (6): 1411-28.
Camerer, C., and Hogarth, R. (1999) "The Effects of Financial
Incentives in Experiments: A Review and Capital-Labor-Production
Framework." Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 19 (1): 7-42.
Choi, S. J., and Pritchard, A. C. (2003) "Behavioral Economics
and the SEC." Michigan Law and Economics Research Paper No. 03-002.
Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan.
DellaVigna, S. (2009) "Psychology and Economics: Evidence from
the Field." Journal of Economic Literature 47 (2): 315-72.
Friedman, M. (1961) "The Lag in Effect of Monetary
Policy." Journal of Political Economy 69 (5): 447-66.
Gigerenzer, G., and Gaissmaier, W. (2011) "Heuristic Decision
Making." Annual Review of Psychology 62: 451-82.
Hetzel, R. (1985) "The Rules versus Discretion Debate Over
Monetary Policy in the 1920s." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Review (November/December): 3-14.
Kahneman, D. (2011) Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar,
Straus and Giroux.
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A. (1972) "Subjective Probability:
A Judgment of Representativeness." Cognitive Psychology 3 (3):
430-54.
--(1982) "The Psychology of Preference." Scientific
American 246: 160-73.
Klein, G. (2003) Intuition at Work: Why Developing Your Gut
Imtincts Will Make You Better at What You Do. New York: Random House.
Koeherlakota, N. (2016) "5 to 4." Kocherlakota 009 Blog
(January 29). Available at
sites.google.com/site/kocherlakota009/home/policy/thoughts-on-policy/1-29-16.
Kydland, F., and Prescott, E. (1977) "Rules Rather Than
Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans." Journal of
Political Economy 85 (3): 473-90.
List, J. A. (2003) "Does Market Experience Eliminate Market
Anomalies?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (1): 41-71.
--(2004) "Neoclassical Theory Versus Prospect Theory: Evidence
from the Marketplace." Econometrica 72 (2): 615-26.
McCallum, R. (1984) "Monetarist Rules in the Light of Recent
Experience." American Economic Review 74 (2): 388-91.
Meade, E., and Sheets, D. (2005) "Regional Influences on FOMC
Voting Patterns." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 37 (4):
661-77.
Meehl, P. E. (1954) Clinical vs. Statistical Prediction: A
Theoretical Analysis and a Review of the Evidence. St. Paul, Minn.:
University of Minnesota.
Orphanides, A. (2015) "Fear of Liftoff: Uncertainty',
Rules, and Discretion in Monetary Policy Normalization." Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 97 (3): 173-96.
Reinhart, C., and Rogoff, K. (2011) This Time Is Different: Eight
Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton, N.}.: Princeton University
Press.
Rotemberg, J. J. (2008) "Behavioral Aspects of Price Setting
and Their Policy Implications." NBER Working Paper No. 13754.
Samuelson, W., and Zeckhauser, R. J. (1988) "Status Quo Bias
in Decision Making." Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 1 (1): 7-59.
Schulz-Hardt, S.; Frey, D.; Liithgens, C.; and Moscovici, S. (2000)
"Biased Information Search in Group Decision Making." Journal
of Personality and Social Psychology 78 (4): 655-69.
Seidenfeld, M. (2002) "Cognitive Loafing, Social Conformity,
and Judicial Review of Agency Rulemaking." Cornell Law Review 87:
486-548.
Sunstein, C. R. (2002) "Conformity and Dissent." Chicago
Public Law and Legal Theory Working Paper No. 34. Chicago: University of
Chicago.
--(2014) Why Nudge? The Politics of Libertarian Paternalism. New
Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Sunstein, C. R., and Hastie, R. (2008) "Four Failures of
Deliberating Groups." Chicago John M. Olin Law and Economics
Working Paper No. 401; Chicago Public Law Working Paper No. 215.
Chicago: University of Chicago.
Tavlas, G. (2014) "In Old Chicago: Simons, Friedman, and the
Development of Monetary-Policy Rules." Becker Friedman Institute
Working Paper No. 2014-02. Chicago: University of Chicago.
Taylor, J. (1985) "What Would Nominal GNP Targeting Do to the
Business Cycle?" Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public
Policy 22: 61-84.
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1973) "Availability: A
Heuristic for Judging Frequency and Probability." Cognitive
Psychology 5 (2): 207-32.
Walsh, C. E. (2010) Monetary Theory and Policy, 3rd ed. Cambridge,
Mass.: MIT Press.
Woolley, J., and Gardner, J. (2009) "Does Sunshine Reduce the
Quality of Deliberation? The Case of the Federal Open Market
Committee." APSA Toronto Meeting Paper. Washington: American
Political Science Association.
Yellen, f. (2007) "Implications of Behavioral Economics for
Monetary Policy." Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston Conference on "Implications of Behavioral Economics for
Economic Policy" (September 28). Available at
www.frbsf.org/our-district/files/0928.pdf.
(1) See, for example, Erik Angner's (2006) study of economic
policymaking in the transition from Soviet planning toward
privatization.
(2) For an overview of this literature, see Walsh (2010: chap. 7),
as well as Alesina et al. (2011). Hetzel (1985) and Tavlas (2014)
provide an overview of the earlier debates.
Mark Calabria is Director of Financial Regulation Studies at the
Cato Institute.