Political Bubbles: Financial Crises and the Failure of American Democracy.
Calabria, Mark A.
Political Bubbles: Financial Crises and the Failure of American
Democracy
Nolan McCarty, Keith Poole, and Howard Rosenthal
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2013, 368 pp.
The majority of books on the recent financial crisis tend to be
written either by economies/finance experts or by journalists. While the
journalistic accounts occasionally focus on political actors, it is
usually in the manner of "bad people doing bad things" rather
than with a theoretical framework. The economic accounts, with some
exception, rarely incorporate the polities of finance. It is this vacuum
that Political Bubbles attempts to fill.
The authors are three prominent political science professors whose
work will be familiar to many Cato Journal readers. Poole and
Rosenthal's previous joint works have made significant
contributions to the Public Choice literature on economic legislation.
All three authors can rightly be called pioneers in the modern academic
literature on ideology. Readers of Poole and Rosenthal's Congress:
A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting (1997) and Ideology and
Congress (2007) will recognize much of that work here. Chapters 2, 3,
and 4 of Political Bubbles are largely an introduction to the
authors' previous work. Those 'already familiar with this work
can either skim or skip these chapters.
The framework outlined in these early chapters focuses on what the
authors call the "Three I's": ideology, institutions, and
interests. That framework is used to explain the development of
"political bubbles," which are defined as "a set of
policy biases that foster and amplify the market behaviors that generate
financial crises." It should be clear from this definition that the
authors begin with the premise that financial crises are the result of
markets. By relying on this definition, the authors rule out the
possibility that government itself can be a generator of financial
crises. From this starting point, the authors ask which ideologies are
likely to constrain government from controlling financial markets. Not
surprisingly, the authors quickly conclude that free-market conservatism
is the "belief structure most conducive to supporting political
bubbles." The rest of the book is spent trying to show how Congress
became more free-market oriented and adopted deregulatory policies that
contributed to the recent bubble.
The foundation of the analysis is a spatial model of voting, which
the authors developed in previous works. Based on this model, members of
the House and Senate are assigned an "ideology score." The
scores are calculated upon actual roll call votes, where
"yeas" and "nays" represent different ends of a
two-dimensional scale. The authors impose these vote scores on the
traditional "liberal" and "conservative" positions.
The authors claim these scores are consistent predictors of voting
behavior. Positions that do not fit into this framework, such as a
libertarian one, are shoehorned by excluding noneconomic roll call
votes. False predictions that are out of the sample, such as Senator
Russ Feingold's vote against Dodd-Frank, are simply explained away
in an ad hoc fashion.
These scores were previously used in the three authors' 2006
book Polarized America. With a title like that you can perhaps guess
that the authors blame political gridlock for much of the cause and
"lack" of response to the crisis. As someone who spent the
years leading up to the crisis on the staff of the Senate Banking
Committee, I can certainly say that gridlock, or rather needing to reach
60 votes in the Senate, was a significant obstacle to reforming Fannie
Mac and Freddie Mac, as well as hampering attempts in 2006 to bring more
competition to the credit-rating agencies. The authors' thesis is
consistent with my experience but for different reasons than the authors
suggest, which I will return to. The remaining chapters essentially
apply the authors' previous work to the particulars of the recent
financial crisis.
Despite chapters on the role of interests and institutions, the
bulk of Political Bubbles is dedicated to ideology. A brief chapter only
illustrates that (1) campaign contributions from the financial services
industry have been increasing, and (2) a handful of members of Congress
have a concentration of financial services employment in their
districts. We are also shown that members of the relevant congressional
committees receive more contributions from finance than members not on
those committees. None of this is really new or shocking, and the
authors do not demonstrate the importance of these findings. As is often
the case, the mere suggestion of money is supposed to be damning. Those
requiring a higher level of proof will be left disappointed.
The discussion on institutions is only slightly more in-depth,
which is particularly surprising given this is a book by three political
scientists. After a very cursory overview of features such as the
filibuster, the presidential veto, and the review function of the
courts, the authors conclude that our system requires supermajorities
and that those supermajorities can shift dramatically with relatively
small changes in the makeup of Congress--what the authors label
"pivot points."
As an example of a pivot point, they cite the special election of
Massachusetts Senator Scott Brown. I agree with the authors that
Brown's election shifted the balance of ideology within the Senate.
I disagree about Brown's impact. Much is made of Brown's
objection to a prefunded resolution mechanism in Dodd-Frank's Title
II, which would have assessed an insurance fee on financial institutions
(something like a FDIC for nondeposit creditors). Senator Brown viewed
it as a tax, and in order to gain his support the fund was dropped.
Instead, Dodd-Frank has a postfunding mechanism. The authors paint this
as a huge ideology swing.
Which brings me to my biggest criticism of Political Bubbles:
relatively minor, even trivial, policy differences are presented as
massive ideological canyons. Because of the institutions not mentioned
by the authors, such as agenda control by the committees, Scott
Brown's election had a relatively minor impact on Dodd-Frank. That
Dodd-Frank does not fix the causes of the crisis has little to do with
Scott Brown and everything to do with the disinterest of the relevant
committee chairs in addressing those issues.
Unfortunately, the book is marred in several places by occasional
outright factual errors. For instance, the authors claim that Fannie Mac
and Freddie Mac were not allowed to acquire risky subprime mortgages (p.
131). As I've explained elsewhere (Cato Institute Briefing Paper
No. 120, March 7, 2011), this is false, as is clear from the both the
regulatory and statutory language governing their allowable purchases.
As I "also document, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac did purchase
subprime loans. The authors also claim that Fannie Mac is in
receivership, which is also incorrect (both are in conservatorship).
Finally, they also claim that the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA)
prohibited banks from redlining but did not require banks to make risky
loans. Again the authors simply have their facts wrong. There's no
prohibition on redlining in CRA, and the 1995 regulatory changes to CBA
implementation encouraged banks to lower underwriting standards. While
many academics have an allergic reaction to actually reading statutes
and regulations, that is no excuse for not at least consulting a legal
expert in this area. Such simple errors undermine confidence in the
authors' knowledge of financial regulation.
Beyond the handful of objective factual errors, the authors make a
number of assertions that are at least debatable (and in my opinion
outright false). For instance, they dismiss objections to the Dodd-Frank
Act as a "bailout bill" as "dubious." An objective
reading of Dodd-Frank would conclude otherwise, but there is little
evidence that the authors actually have read Dodd-Frank. Of greater
relevance to the authors' framework is their use of ideology in
describing individual politicians. For example, the former chair of the
House Financial Services Committee, Mike Oxley (of Sarbanes-Oxley fame),
is described as a "free market conservative advocate."
However, there is no credible definition of free-market advocate that
would include Oxley.
This is where Political Bubbles falls most flat. In constraining
their definition of "ideology" to a one-dimensional measure,
the authors cannot distinguish actual free-market advocates from crony
capitalists. In fact, they explicitly say they see little difference,
claiming that free-market advocates and crony capitalists have bonded
(p. 270). One could as easily take the case of Fannie Mac and claim that
progressives and crony capitalists bonded, but such would undermine the
authors" thesis that activist government is the solution.
Despite the brief chapter on interests, Political Bubbles downplays
the role of special interests in the financial services industry,
attributing the vast majority of legislative changes to
"ideology." In my seven years as a Senate staffer working on
these issues, I found that almost all of it is driven by interests with
very little role played by ideology.
Political Bubbles contains a number of policy recommendations. Some
of these are related to the arguments advanced by the authors, such as
filibuster reform; others, such as limiting bank activities, feel tacked
on. The financial rules they suggest mirror conventional wisdom and seem
to be included largely for that reason. Their more interesting
recommendations, such as set rules that account for political risk, are
useful considerations. Overall, the recommendations are a mixed
bag--something for everyone to agree with and object to, but little in
the way of convincing argument.
I've quipped in many presentations that one cause of the
financial crisis is that "democracy loves a bubble." By this I
mean that the people generally enjoy the appearance of expanding wealth
that accompanies a bubble. Few politicians can successfully lean against
the wind. With that in mind, I greatly looked forward to Political
Bubbles. I was sadly disappointed that the role of democracy is never
rely addressed, nor is the authors' theory really applicable beyond
the recent crisis. The authors are ill informed on issues of finance and
do not consider alternative theories, even within political science, as
an explanation of the crisis. Despite these flaws, Political Bubbles is
an important book. I would include it in any seminar on the crisis, as
it injects an analysis into the discussion that is all too often
missing. I would also hope that Political Bubbles spurs other scholars
to plow this field.
Mark A. Calabria
Cato Institute