A century of central banking: what have we learned?
Jordan, Jerry L.
All of us who are interested in the century-long experience of
central banking in the United States owe a great debt to Allan Meltzer.
His several-years-long efforts gave us over 2,000 pages of careful
documentation of decisionmaking in the Federal Reserve for the first 75
years (Meltzer 2003, 2010a, 2010b). The first score of years transformed
a lender-of-last-resort, payments processor, and issuer of uniform
national currency into a full-fledged central bank with discretionary
authority to manage a flat currency.
Even in the mid-1930s, then Senator Carter Glass declared that we
did not have a central bank in the United States. However, legislation
in 1933 and 1935 had institutionalized tire Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC), which had previously been an informal coordinating
committee.
In an interview several years before his death, Milton Friedman was
asked about any regrets in his long career. He replied that he wished he
had paid more attention early on to what Jim Buchanan had been saying
about the behavior of politicians and bureaucrats (Friedman 2003). Any
discussion about any institution of government can be fruitful only in
the context of the public-choice elements of decisionmaking by
individuals who occupy policymaking positions. For the past century, the
economic theories of prominent personalities in the central bank's
policymaking bodies have been the dominant factors giving us the very
mixed results we have witnessed.
Dead-End Debates
In 60-plus years since the Accord in 1951, the U.S. central bank
has gone full-circle from being a de facto bureau of the U.S. Treasury,
to an "independent" monetary authority, and back to a bureau
of die Treasury. Of course, the long period of "even-keeling"
demonstrated that the Fed's independence was always more in
rhetoric than reality (Cargill and O'Driscoll 2013). The debates
about free reserves versus net-borrowed reserves, targets versus
indicators, monetary versus fiscal policy, the Phillips Curve, monetary
aggregate targeting, and econometric modeling have come and gone within
a decade or two. The emergence and demise of those debates over the past
several decades--about how to reform and improve the formulation and
execution of monetary policies by committee--have left us after 100
years questioning the concept of central banking and monopoly monetary
authorities. In this article, I address a series of issues about central
banking.
Moral Hazard
The existence of central banks with discretionary powers in a fiat
currency world creates moral hazard in the financial system. Because of
tire explicit and implicit "safety net" offered by the
existence of central banks, private financial institutions cannot be
observed behaving as they would in absence of moral hazard. Because of
moral hazard in the financial system--privatization of gains from risky
decisions and socialization of the losses--the trend has been toward
evermore regulations and calls for closer supervision of financial
companies. The resulting "permission-and-denial" regime opens
ever wider the door to cronyism in the financial system.
For many years it has been recognized that "too big to
fail" is a large and growing problem. In more recent years, more
people are also beginning to understand that "too politically
well-connected and powerful to effectively supervise" has become a
major obstacle to meaningful financial system reforms. For the biggest
banks, the political action committees are more important than the
credit policy committees.
Moral hazard also emerges in other institutions of government as a
result of the presence of central banks with discretionary powers. It is
evident in a lessening of political pressures on tax and regulatory
authorities of government to undertake the difficult decisions and
actions that would enhance the "magic of the marketplace" and
foster growth. Even when most observers recognize that the "sand in
the gears" preventing more robust economic prosperity arises from
the regulatory and tax policies of government, the mistaken belief that
monetary actions can overcome those obstacles results in an adverse mix
of policies by government. Economists should understand that monetary
authorities cannot correct the mistakes of the rest of government. But,
as we have seen, politicians have strong incentives to blame the central
bank when the economy is not doing well, but take all the credit when
employment is high and inflation is low.
The Myth of Central Bank Independence
Central banks and ministries of finance are not able to resist the
political pressures to alter the stance of policies in response to
crises. Who would want to be the secretary of the Treasury or chairman
of the Fed that is blamed for another Great Depression? Moreover, once
central banks make the mistake of engaging in quasi-fiscal actions in
futile attempts to correct mistakes of the rest of government, there is
no feasible exit strategy that does not involve collateral damage. When
economic activity is constrained or adversely impacted by
government's anti-supply-side taxation and regulatory actions,
central banks come under great pressure to engage in demand-side
monetary actions as a counter measure. That mistake cannot be reversed
without negative consequences. "Soft-landing" is a myth.
An argument can be made that the institutional setting of the
European Central Bank gives it more independence than any other central
bank because it does not have a single ministry of finance or single
parliament to answer to. National central banks are in the position that
former Fed chairman William McChesney Martin liked to describe as
"independent within government." Another former Fed chairman,
Arthur Bums, asserted on occasion, "We dare not exercise our
independence for fear of losing it." As the Fed celebrates its
centennial, politicians have come to view it as an activist instrument
of economic policymaking responsible for pursuing multiple objectives of
financial stability, employment, output, low interest rates, and
tolerable inflation--all with the single tool of the power to create
fiat currency.
Rules versus Discretion
The FOMC is institutionally designed to exercise discretion rather
than adopt and follow rules in the formulation of policy actions. A
schedule of committee meetings every six weeks to reconsider the stance
of policy causes deliberations to focus on recently reported data and
recently revised forecasts of future economic activity. The 1933 and
1935 legislations "fixing" the FOMC as a separate, legal,
government body--without budget, staff, buildings, or any other
identifiable characteristics of a government entity--created a
"monetary authority" to formulate and implement what has been
called "monetary policy." Not only was the U.S. currency not
defined in terms of specie--as had been the case in 1913--but it was
illegal for ordinary citizens to even own gold. Clearly, by the time the
central bank had passed its 20th birthday, the Congress intended that
our monetary system was one of a managed fiat currency.
Monetary Discipline
The ongoing dialogue in academic circles regarding "rules
versus discretion" has not found a satisfactory solution to the
issue of enforcement of adopted rules. The post-WWII Bretton Woods System--often referred to as a form of gold-exchange standard-- required
that the United States maintain a hard peg of its currency to gold, and
that other countries peg their currency to the dollar and be able to
exchange excess dollars for gold at the fixed U.S. dollar price. This
obligation on the part of the United States to redeem the dollar for
gold was intended to provide essential discipline on the world's
reserve currency.
However, by the 1960s the United States began to abuse the
"exorbitant privilege" of borrowing in its own currency.
Washington ran larger budget deficits, reflecting the Vietnam War and
the War on Poverty, and supplied more dollar-denominated bonds than the
world wanted to acquire. By mid-decade, emerging U.S. inflationary
pressures were eroding the real value of the growing stocks of
dollar-denominated bonds held by central banks and governments around
the world. One large holder, Germany, faced upward pressure on its
currency, yet refrained from seeking gold in exchange for surplus
dollars, but other countries challenged the Johnson administration to
honor the commitment to absorb the surplus dollars in exchange for gold.
The drain on the U.S. gold stock was supposed to impose monetary and
fiscal discipline, but that failed.
Rather than constrain the creation of excess dollar-denominated
bonds by reducing spending or raising taxes, the Johnson administration
chose capital controls, taxation of foreign travel by its citizens, and
subsidies to exporters as temporary measures to address the imbalance
between the supply and demand for dollars. First suspension, then ending
the London gold pool, followed in 1968 by ending the gold-backing of
Federal Reserve notes, prolonged (with the help of moral suasion on
foreign governments) the period that the U.S. dollar was notionally (but
not really) convertible into gold at $35/oz.
A brief lurch toward fiscal discipline in the final year of the
failing Johnson presidency, in the form of a 10 percent surtax on
personal and business incomes, helped stabilize the exchange regime and
was aided by revaluation of the German currency. However, the mild U.S.
recession of 1970 precipitated "pedal to the metal" monetary
policy, and as 1971 got under way die world was once again flooded with
excess dollars.
By mid-1971, U.S. policymakers faced a dilemma: (1) continue with
highly expansionary monetary and fiscal policies and face continued
international pressures to convert surplus foreign-held dollars into a
dwindling gold supply as well as accelerating inflation in the following
presidential election year, or (2) curtail monetary growth and fiscal
deficits and risk a return to recession during the election cycle. They
chose instead the "magic wand" of floating the currency and
imposing wage and price controls that allowed them to open further the
monetary and fiscal spigots. The post-election result was accelerating
inflation, a falling dollar, collapse of the Bretton Woods system, and
then another lurch toward restraint and a worse recession.
Just a few years later excess monetary creation produced
reacceleration of inflation and the rest of the world again challenged
the United States to restore fiscal and monetary discipline during the
failing presidency of Jimmy Carter. This time the "exorbitant
privilege" to borrow in its own currency was revoked when foreign
governments and central banks demanded that the United States issue
"Carter bonds" denominated in German and Swiss currencies. For
the first time in decades the ability of the United States to service
additional foreign-held debt would not be based on tax collections or on
creation of additional liabilities of its central bank, but on the
earnings from exports and proceeds from foreign inflows.
This externally imposed discipline ushered in the "Great
Moderation," which was characterized by falling budget deficits
(and even occasional surpluses), falling inflation, and rapid economic
growth. The essential point is that U.S. policymakers were not
disciplined by institutional arrangements within the central bank or by
pressures from elsewhere within the U.S. government.
We now have a century of experience that congressional oversight of
a national monetary authority is not effective. The few occasions of
discipline emerging from competition with other, more effectively
managed, foreign currencies suggest that opening the door to domestic
alternatives to Fed-issued notes would offer the potential for greater
monetary stability than a monopoly currency.
Transparency
Deliberations by central bank policymakers in the formulation of
discretionary policy actions must be conducted in secret, especially
when operating under a dual mandate involving short-run tradeoffs.
Debates about possible discretionary responses to certain contingencies,
if broadcast live on C-SPAN, would cause private market participants to
alter their behavior. Because central bank actions and operations are
conducted within the national and international financial systems, the
actions and reactions of other participants in financial markets will
influence the transmission of monetary actions to the real economy.
Generally, policymakers know that if their preference is to target a
price-axis variable--such as an overnight interbank rate or an exchange
rate--such targets cannot be preannounced. That is, policymakers cannot
announce that they plan to raise short-term interest rates gradually by
some incremental amounts over an announced time horizon. "Forward
guidance" with regard to policy targets is possible only with
horizontal-axis magnitudes--such as bank reserves, central bank money,
or monetary aggregates.
The "exit strategy" for the FOMC under Chairman Paul
Volcker in 1979 was to announce a target of total reserve growth and let
markets set interest rates. That lesson was forgotten--or never
learned--by current policymakers. Exiting the current zero interest rate
regime has proven to be quite messy because there simply is no way to be
transparent about the end without creating considerable turbulence in
financial markets.
Open-Mouth Policies
There was a time not long ago when the FOMC directive would give a
form of forward guidance by announcing that although the decision at a
meeting was to leave the fed funds rate unchanged, a majority of the
committee had a "bias to raise" or a "bias to lower"
the rate at a subsequent meeting. The idea was that such announcements
would alter private market participants' behavior in predictable
ways and achieve some desired effect without actually having to do
anything.
However, because there is always more public and political pressure
to lower rates than to raise rates, it goes without saying that there is
a permanent institutional bias toward lower rates. The unique status of
the U.S. central bank as a "creature of Congress"--rather than
a part of the executive branch--reinforced the natural bias toward lower
interest rates.
The effect of the institutional bias was that the committee of 19
policymakers was always quicker to reach a consensus that the target
rate should be lowered, versus overcoming the reluctance to take the
heat for raising rates. Rare has been the member of Congress or the
executive branch that complained that the monetary authorities were
maintaining interest rates at too low a level--until very recently.
Neutral Monetary Policy
There was a time not long ago when the FOMC would attempt to
determine at what level of the fed funds rate the stance of monetary
policy was "neutral"--neither expansionary nor contractionary
with respect to economic activity. This notion of a "neutral"
fed funds rate (either nominal or real) was different from a
"natural" rate in the Wicksellian sense. On occasion, changes
in an estimated real rate and a perceived natural rate give opposite
signals about the stance of policy. Elsewhere I have argued that such
was the case in the late 1990s during the favorable "productivity
surprise" (Jordan 2006). Now, we have the mirror image of that
experience. Conventional real rate analysis holds that if the central
bank (perhaps reinforced by debt and deficits in the fiscal policies)
can generate expectations of higher inflation, the real interest rate
will be lower and thus stimulative. A natural rate analysis suggests the
opposite. To the extent that expectations of higher inflation cause
nominal bond yields to be higher while there are other reasons to
believe the natural rate is low, the stance of policy is more
restrictive than if the expectations of higher inflation were not
increasing market rates.
Today, however, the overnight interbank rate has become meaningless
as a policy instrument. The volume of transactions in the fed funds
market had largely dried up by the middle of 2011. Announcing a target
level of the fed funds rate has no meaning if there are no transactions
and the operations desk of the central bank does not need to make
outright purchases or stiles of securities or repurchase agreements to
maintain the rate. For now, the rate is as meaningless as the official
price of gold--a price at which there are neither purchases nor sales.
Despite occasional stories in the financial press about the Fed
"raising short-term interest rates," the operations desk has
no tools available for influencing the overnight interbank rate. Because
the Fed does not own any short-term Treasury bills, the desk cannot
intervene in the overnight market to affect the fed funds rate. However,
as of this writing (December 2013) the New York Fed has announced a
program to develop a new tool--reverse repurchase agreements of Treasury
securities and mortgage-backed securities--for setting short-term
interest rates.
Aggregate Demand Management
Prior to the era of quantitative easing (QE), the notion that
monetary actions can and should be employed so as to influence total
nominal spending in the national economy remained the dominant
framework. This was in spite of the increasing globalization of commerce
and worldwide use of the U.S. currency in pricing goods and assets and
in conducting transactions. If an analytical framework exists that
relates the several rounds of QE and the massive increase in excess
reserves to any measure of economic activity, it is a remarkably
well-kept secret.
Nevertheless, a small network of bloggers that fly the banner of
"market monetarists" have aggressively promoted the notion
that the central bank should somehow target a growth rate of nominal
GDP. Whatever the theoretical merits of that objective, the only
suggestion for a possible directive the FOMC could adopt to instruct the
trading desk is Scott Sumner's idea of a type of "futures
market" of GDP forecasts that might serve as an indicator variable
signaling the need for more expansionary or restrictive policies.
Monetary Targeting
The success in the 1970s and 1980s of targeting various monetary
aggregates with a view to influence nominal spending in the economy
depended on unique institutional arrangements. The empirical
relationships between the monetary base and monetary aggregates (money
multipliers), and between the monetary aggregates and nominal GDP (money
velocity) were altered as a result of legislation and regulation,
financial innovations (e.g., hypothecation, credit default swaps, and
collateralized debt obligations), and globalization of commerce. Now,
under the QEs, the link between central bank monetary base and
commercial bank liabilities is completely broken.
Deflation
Unlike a gold standard under which the purchasing power of money
could increase, a central bank managed fiat currency can only decline in
purchasing power. There is no support in central banks for the idea of
"virtuous deflation"--a rise in the purchasing power of money
resulting from increased productivity and technological innovations. The
concept of a "productivity norm" (as suggested by Selgin 1990)
for measures of output prices is never considered. The fears of the
consequences of deflation in the banking system are so pervasive that
there is an institutional bias in favor of more rapid debasement of the
currency, rather than tolerate the risk of accidently permitting a rise
in purchasing power. Moreover, there is no consideration of asset prices
in assessing the trends in the purchasing power of money. Instead, asset
prices are viewed as an instrument in achieving objectives of employment
and output.
The Duel Mandate
The notion that a monetary authority has responsibility for both
the purchasing power of money and the rate of unemployment
institutionalizes the Phillips Curve tradeoff in the formulation of
policy actions. Because the lags of policy actions are not only
uncertain but also different with respect to real and nominal
magnitudes, there is a committee bias to focus on short-run effects.
Ironically, even during the Great Moderation of the 1990s--when
unemployment trended well below the assumed "natural unemployment
rate" and inflation did not accelerate--policymakers gave even
greater attention to the Phillips Curve analysis.
At the July 1995 meeting of the FOMC there was an extended
discussion of the longer-run objectives of the policymakers. One leader
of the initial debate was Fed Governor Janet Yellen, who stated:
The key question is how much permanent unemployment rises as
inflation falls, and here the methodology used to assess the
consequences does matter. These authors [George Akerlof, Bill Dickens,
and George Perry] used general equilibrium methodology and here is what
they find: The natural rate rises above its assumed 5.8 percent minimum
to 6.1 percent as measured inflation falls from 4 down to 2 percent; the
natural rate rises to 6.5 percent at 1 percent inflation, and then to
7.6 percent at zero percent inflation [Jordan 2012: 23].
This astonishing invocation of the "natural rate of
unemployment" was actually quite common in such meetings even
though there was (is?) no theoretical or empirical support for it. Even
though the economy at die end of the last century was on a track to
achieve under 4 percent unemployment and at the same time continue to
experience less than 2 percent inflation, the Phillips Curve had
resurfaced in policy discussions in new clothing, using Friedman's
language, but ignoring everything he had said about the notion of some
"tradeoff' that could, or should, be exploited by
policymakers.
Gap Analysis
Closely associated with the Phillips Curve approach, "gap
analysis" incentivizes policymakers to give considerable weight to
estimates and forecasts of "aggregate supply" (potential
output) and formulate policies with a view to "manage aggregate
demand" in order to influence inflation rates and unemployment
rates. This, of course, requires considerable confidence in forecasts of
productivity, employment (including labor force participation rates),
and die impact of various "supply shocks." It also assumes
there is some dependable linkage between actions taken, and
"aggregate demand" somehow measured.
Quantity Easing
Advocacy of expansion of the central bank's balance sheet in
the face of a "lower bound" of controllable interest rates
first arose in the context of the classical "inside money/outside
money" paradigm. That is, the controllable "outside
money" (monetary base) represented by the Fed's balance sheet
in a fiat money world is assumed to have a direct and predictable effect
on the "inside money" represented by commercial bank deposit
liabilities. The linkage depends on the actions of commercial banks to
minimize surplus reserve balances by making loans or acquiring financial
securities. However, the emergence of "shadow banking"
channels for transmitting credit have caused the link between outside
money and economic activity to become highly unreliable. Furthermore,
there is no theoretical model or empirical evidence explaining the
parameters of banks' demand for "excess" reserve
balances.
The Mix between Monetary and Fiscal Policy
When monetary policy becomes fiscal policy, the mix is complete.
There once was a notion that monetary actions could be restrictive and
fiscal policy expansionary, or the other way around. That became
nonsense when monetary actions in QE mode morphed into fiscal actions
carried out by the central bank. Of course, recent debates--especially
in Europe--about whether "fiscal austerity" is contractionary
have muddied the dialogue. The massive deficits and national debts of
some countries have caused some policymakers to argue that long-term,
sustainable prosperity can be achieved only by reducing government
spending and/or raising more tax revenue--the opposite of conventional
arguments about fiscal policies. But the real issue is whether actions
of central banks are actually fiscal, or at least quasifiscal, in
nature. That is, if the actions of reserve banks could (and maybe
should) be conducted by a bureau of the ministry of finance/treasury, is
it still useful to make a distinction between monetary and fiscal
policies?
Once open market operations mean nothing more than monetizing
government bonds and acquiring a large portfolio of private debt
instruments such as mortgage-backed securities, or attempting to
"twist" the yield curve by altering the term-structure of
publically held government debt, traditional views of monetary policies
and actions are no longer useful. The massive open market operations
under QE have broken the link between outside money and inside money
(the money multipliers), have rendered the targeting of the overnight
bank lending rate impossible, and have distorted the income-velocity of
money that once was a prominent feature of monetary analyses.
It is reasonable to question whether QE actions by the monetary
authority are properly viewed as expansionary. While it is common to see
massive portfolio purchases by reserve banks as "easy" money
policies, there is another way to think about it. First, there is a view
that low nominal interest rates are a product of QE, low interest rates
are expansionary, and thus QE is expansionary. An alternative view is
that the low nominal interest rates are not at all the product of QE,
but a reflection of the tax and regulatory regime that discourages
private investment--and are also a product of the shifting of
demographics toward a rapidly aging population. There is a conjecture by
policymakers that QE means rising asset prices, so a "wealth
effect" will eventually produce rising aggregate demand and a
return to prosperity. That hasn't worked out well so far, and now
the fears that future implementation of an exit strategy from QE will be
contractionary raises cautions about long-term investments and other
commitments. One doesn't have to understand Ricardo to understand
why households in several QE countries are cautious about their
financial future.
Potentially a bigger problem with the view that QE is expansionary
is the other traditional channel of monetary policy--the effects of the
Fed's balance sheet on the consolidated balance sheets of
commercial banks. The central bank's balance sheet (outside money)
was historically connected to the balance sheets of banks via fairly
predictable money multipliers. The monetary base created by the central
bank led to the expansion of bank balance sheets, and the greater
deposits created inside these commercial banks constituted the bulk of
the nation's money supply and could be reliably transmitted to the
economy at large via money velocity.
However, a part of the process of fiat money creation is bank
acquisition of earning assets (i.e., loans and securities). The supply
of earning assets to banks (sometimes called the "demand for bank
credit") is derived from the aggregate supply of claims to future
earning streams--bonds and borrowings of households and businesses to be
repaid out of future earnings. Banks compete for such earning assets
against numerous domestic and foreign institutional investors (e.g.,
pension funds, mutual funds, and life insurance companies). The appetite
of such nonbank institutional investors for earning assets is influenced
by factors such as demographic trends and target-income requirements. In
sum, the super-low interest rate environment (whether or not
attributable to the central bank) means larger stocks of earning assets
are necessary in order to generate the necessary earnings, leaving a
smaller supply offered to banks.
Because QE by monetary authorities reduces the stock of such
earning assets (other things the same), the supply offered to banks is
smaller yet. In other words, monetization of government obligations and
acquisition of mortgage-backed securities by a central bank shrinks the
floating supply of instruments that might otherwise be acquired by
banks. Furthermore, if business demands for bank loans are suppressed
because government taxation and regulation diminish the availability of
profitable investment opportunities, and household demands for bank
loans are restrained for a host of reasons including demographics, the
multiplication of central bank outside money into commercial bank inside
money does not occur with the previous reliability.
The result is that massive expansion of the Fed's balance
sheet under a program of QE may, in fact, operate perversely. Without QE
operations of the monetary authorities, commercial banks would have seen
a greater supply of earning assets (or demand for bank credit), and the
expansion of their own balance sheets would have increased the
nation's money supply by more than has occurred under QE.
Conclusion
When the reserve banks were incorporated and then opened for
business in late 1914, nothing they did would have been construed to be
what later came to be called monetary policy. Now, almost a century
later, the same can be said again.
In the beginning, the U.S. central bank was supposed to be a lender
of last resort. But even after almost 100 years there are no established
rules for providing such a safety net. No one can say who will and who
will not be bailed out in the future. Instead of lending only to inject
liquidity into financial markets, the Fed has also loaned to insolvent
institutions--including banks, nonbank financial companies, and even
nonfinancial companies. No one can say who is, and who is not, going to
receive loans in the future, for what amounts, and for what duration.
There are no effective rules governing central bank lending.
Congress delegated its constitutional authority to "coin money
and regulate the value thereof' to a central bank but has
consistently failed to provide effective oversight of the money-creation
process. Worse, Congress saddled the central bank with an unworkable
dual mandate and an institutional bias toward artificially low interest
rates. The central bank is now dominated by people who believe inflation
occurs as a result of a too-low unemployment rate, and that inflation is
not a risk so long as unemployment is above some threshold. Indeed,
monetary policymakers will not give greater weight to inflation until
they perceive that too many people are working, earning a paycheck, and
supporting their families.
The Fed's century-long track record includes the Great
Depression of the 1930s; the Great Inflation of the 1970s; episodes of
bubbles, panics, and crises; and an average inflation that left
today's dollar worth only a small fraction of the 1913 dollar. The
challenge is to establish institutional arrangements that prevent the
next hundred years from being simply more of the same.
References
Cargill, T. F., and O'Driscoll Jr., G. P. (2013) "Federal
Reserve Independence: Reality or Myth?" Cato Journal 33 (3):
417-35.
Friedman, M. (2003) "A Conversation with Milton
Friedman." Alamos Alliance X, Sonora, Mexico (1 March).
Jordan, J. L. (2006) "Money and Monetary Policy for the
Twenty-First Century." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review
(November/December): 48.5-510.
--(2012) "Friedman and the Phillips Curve." In Sound
Money: Why It Matters, How to Have It. Essays in Honour of Milton
Friedman's Contributions to Monetary Policy, 9-29. Ottawa:
Macdonald-Laurier Institute for Public Policy.
Meltzer, A. H. (2003) A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. 1:
1913-1951. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
--(2010a) A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. 2, Book
1:1951-1969. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
--(2010b) A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. 2, Book 2:
1970-1986. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Selgin, G. A. (1990) "Monetary Equilibrium and the
Productivity Norm of Price-Level Policy." Cato Journal 10 (1):
26.5-87.
Jerry L. Jordan is former President of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. He served on President Reagan's Council of Economic
Advisers and the U.S. Gold Commission.