What Stiglitz and Stockman have in common.
Holcombe, Randall G.
The role of government in the economy has been a major public
policy issue for more than two centuries. Critics of capitalism, at
least since Karl Marx, have argued that the system is skewed to benefit
the political and economic elite at the expense of the masses: the
proletariat over the bourgeoisie, as Marx put it, or the 1 percent over
the 99 percent, as the Occupy Movement that began in 2011 put it. Two
recent books have looked at these issues, one from the vantage point of
the political left and the other from the political right. Joseph
Stiglitz, a Nobel laureate economist and frequent commentator on the
political left, discusses the way the system is skewed to support the 1
percent over the 99 percent in his book The Price of Inequality (2012),
while conservative writer and former Michigan congressman and budget
director in the Reagan administration David Stockman addresses these
same issues from the political right in The Great Deformation (2013).
Considering their political leanings, it is worth emphasizing how much
their books have in common when describing the causes of the major
economic and political problems they perceive in the United States.
Both Stiglitz and Stockman argue that corruption of the U.S.
political system is damaging both the economic system and democracy.
This article documents the commonality of ideas in their two books while
recognizing the significant differences in their policy recommendations.
Views on Crony Capitalism, Rent Seeking, the Fed, and Democracy
In Chapter 1 Stiglitz outlines the problem he sees, which, as the
title suggests, is inequality, and he offers some data to back up his
claims. (1) Chapter 2, titled "Rent Seeking and the Making of an
Unequal Society," places much of the blame for inequality on
government policy. Stiglitz (2012: 39-40) argues: "We have a
political system that gives inordinate power to those at the top, and
they have used that power not only to limit the extent of redistribution
but also to shape the rules of the game in their favor." Stockman
(2013: 169) agrees, saying that public policies to try to regulate the
market "fail to recognize that the state bears an inherent flaw
that dwarfs the imperfections purported to afflict the free market;
namely, that policies undertaken in the name of the public good
inexorably become captured by special interests and crony capitalists
who appropriate resources from society's commons for their own
private ends."
Discussing the lawyers and accountants hired by the elite, Stiglitz
(p. 53) says, "They help write the complex tax laws in which
loopholes are put, so their clients can avoid taxes, and they then
design the complex deals to take advantage of these loopholes." (2)
Regarding the market power that the elite use to enhance its income,
Stiglitz (p. 54) writes, "The simplest way to a sustainable
monopoly is getting the government to give you one." Stockman (p.
181) says, "Like in all instances of crony capitalism, economic
outcomes are as much a gift of the state as they are the fruits of
capitalist virtue." Stiglitz (p. 40) agrees, saying capitalists
write the rules in their favor "to extract from the public what can
only be called large 'gifts.'"
Stiglitz (p. 59) argues that the rules are being written by the 1
percent for their benefit. "It's one thing to win a
'fair' game. It's quite another to be able to write the
rules of the game--and to write them in ways that enhance one's
prospects of winning. And it's even worse if you can choose your
own referees." Discussing government regulation in various sectors
of the economy, Stiglitz contends, "The problem is that leaders in
these sectors use their political influence to get people appointed to
the regulatory agencies who are sympathetic to their perspectives."
(3)
Stiglitz (p. 62) says, "It doesn't have to be this way,
but powerful interests ensure that it is." Stockman (p. 560)
agrees, saying, "We have a rigged system--a regime of crony
capitalism--where the tax code heavily favors debt and capital gains,
and the central bank purposefully enables rampant speculation by
propping up the price of financial assets and battering down the cost of
leveraged finance." Stockman's (p. 606) dismal view is that
"In truth, the historic boundary between the free market and the
state has been eradicated, and therefore anything that can be peddled by
crony capitalists ... is fair game."
Stiglitz (pp. 104-T5) argues that "When one interest group
holds too much power, it succeeds in getting policies that benefit
itself, rather than policies that would benefit society as a whole. When
the wealthiest use their political power to benefit excessively the
corporations they control, much-needed revenues are diverted into the
pockets of a few instead of benefiting society at large." Why does
this happen? Stiglitz tells us that interest groups hold too much power
and use it to get policies that benefit the wealthiest.
Echoing Stiglitz's message, Stockman (p. 672) says our
government "is no longer a system of democratic choice and
governance: it is a tyranny of incumbency and money politics." He
argues (p. 692) that "the gangs of crony capitalism will fight
tooth and nail to preserve their slice of an imperiled pie, thereby
disenfranchising even further ordinary taxpayers and citizens who have
no voice in the Washington policy auctions."
In Chapter 9, titled "A Macroeconomic Policy and a Central
Bank By and For the 1 Percent," Stiglitz finds fault with the
Federal Reserve for monetary policies that subsidized banks and boosted
the stock market, aiding the elite at the expense of the masses. He
criticizes the bank bailouts, saying (pp. 307, 309), "More broadly,
the bailout strategy put the interests of the banks (and especially the
large banks) and bankers ahead of the rest of our economy.... The big
banks can thus prosper not because they are more efficient or provide
better service but because they are in effect subsidized by the
taxpayers." Stockman (p. 22) discussing the bailouts during the
financial crisis, offers a similar message: "The Washington
bailouts rescued the perpetrators, not the victims."
Stockman (pp. 658-59) agrees with Stiglitz on Fed policy:
The Bernanke Fed has showered speculators with windfalls again and
again in the various risk asset classes, yet the problem is not
merely the unfairness of these massive unearned rents and the
resulting further skew of societal wealth to the top 1 percent. In
truth, the Fed's radical financial repression policies cause vast
economic deformations, even as they generate gratuitous upward
redistributions of the wealth.... Never before had so much cash
been hauled home by speculators--literally hundreds of
billions--for so little value added.
Chapter 5 is titled "A Democracy in Peril." Stiglitz (pp.
148-49) argues:
Politics is the battleground for fights over how we divide the
nation's economic pie. It is a battleground that the 1 percent have
been winning.... In earlier chapters we saw how markets are shaped
by politics: politics determines the rules of the economic game,
and the playing field is slanted in favor of the 1 percent. At
least part of the reason is that the rules of the political game,
too, are shaped by the 1 percent.
Stockman (p. 52) agrees: "Trying to improve capitalism, modern
economic policy has thus fatally overloaded the state with missions and
mandates far beyond its capacity to fulfill. The result is crony
capitalism--a freakish deformation that fatally corrupts free markets
and democracy."
Stiglitz (p. 225) thinks Warren Buffett was correct when he stated:
"There has been class warfare going on for the last 20 years and my
class has won." In Stiglitz's opinion (p. 102), rising
inequality, to a large extent, "is the result of government
policies."
Stockman is not optimistic that the increasing cronyism he sees can
be reversed. One might think that the Republican Party would be the
political party that could reverse the trends he sees, but Stockman (p.
551) emphasizes that "there is no conservative party left in
America--at least not one that is willing or able to defend sound money,
free markets, and fiscal rectitude. So the drift into the crony
capitalist end game will now accelerate, suffocating what remains of
free market prosperity and honest political democracy." Agreeing
with Stiglitz's message in Chapter 5, "A Democracy in
Peril," Stockman (p. 614) concludes;
A government which is responsible for every bob and weave
of the entire national economy will quickly succumb to pure
crony capitalism, a regime which cannot avoid eventual fiscal
insolvency and the destruction of any semblance of a free
market economy.... Most importantly, it means a fatal corruption
of political democracy.
In sum, Stiglitz and Stockman see a system of cronyism, where
government policies are designed by the economic and political elite to
benefit themselves at the expense of the masses. Both use the language
of the Occupy Movement to describe how the 1 percent rigs the system to
increase their power and wealth. And both show how crony capitalism,
rent seeking, and Fed bailouts have damaged the market economy and
democratic government.
Other Critics of Cronyism and Special Interest Politics
Stiglitz and Stockman offer good examples of the similarity in the
way the left and right perceive the causes of problems that face the
economic and political systems, but a substantial literature shows that
they are not unique in describing a political and economic system
characterized by cronyism and skewed to promote the interests of the
political and economic elite. Holcombe and Castillo (2013) look at
cronyism outside the United States dating back to the early 20th
century, and Holcombe (2013) discusses a strong foundation for this line
of reasoning in the economics literature.
Gabriel Kolko, a left-leaning historian, sees government as an
organization that provides regulatory advantages to the economic elite.
He discusses this in the content of Progressive Era policies that are
often viewed as favoring the general public over moneyed interests
(Kolko 1977).
Peter Schweizer (2013) discusses in detail the negative effects of
cronyism, but differs from Stiglitz and Stockman by arguing that the
special interest political activity that often appears as
bribery-interest groups bribing legislatures for favorable outcomes--is
more accurately described as extortion. In this respect, he follows the
lead of McChesney (1987, 1997): Legislators threaten businesses and
other interests with harmful legislation, or threaten to hold up
legislation they desire, until those interests make payments to the
politicians. Still, Schweizer describes a system of cronyism that works
for the benefit of the elite but imposes costs on the masses.
John Allison (2013), like Stockman, is a strong supporter of free
markets and sees the Fed as a major contributor to the 2008 financial
crisis, along with various government policies like deposit insurance
and the taxpayer subsidy inherent in Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac as
government sponsored enterprises. While he focuses more narrowly on the
financial crisis, Alison sees the problems with intervention in a manner
similar to Stockman.
While Schweizer and Allison write from the vantage point of the
political right--or, more accurately, from a libertarian
perspective-there is a substantial literature on the political left
making similar points about cronyism. Larry Bartels (2008) calls the
political privilege the elite enjoy at the expense of the masses the
"New Gilded Age," noting how the political process is skewed
to benefit the 1 percent. Hacker and Pierson (2010) and Gilens (2012)
argue along with Stiglitz that the growing privilege of the 1 percent is
not due to market forces but to the political power of those at the top.
Finally, Gilens and Page (forthcoming) offer a persuasive empirical
analysis which concludes that government policy conforms to the
preferences of the elites, and goes in the direction average citizens
prefer only when their preferences correspond with those of the elites.
Different Policy Recommendations
As far as specific solutions to the problems they perceive, both
Stiglitz and Stockman come up with a list of desirable reforms. Their
lists are different because Stiglitz sees inequality as the major
problem while Stockman sees the major problem as the undermining of a
free-market economy. Overall, Stiglitz calls for more government
oversight and involvement in the economy while Stockman calls for less.
Stiglitz lists more than 20 policy reforms he recommends to address
the problems he and Stockman agree plague the economic and political
system. His recommendations are not specific policies but rather policy
goals. For example, under the heading of "curbing the financial
sector," he offers six reforms designed to curb excessive risk
taking, make banks more transparent, increase the competitiveness of
banks and credit card companies, make it more difficult for banks to
engage in predatory lending, curb bonuses that encourage excessive risk
taking, and close down offshore banking centers. Yet, Stiglitz does not
offer any specific policies that would achieve those ends.
Stiglitz wants stronger competition laws, better corporate
governance, an end to government giveaways and corporate welfare, a more
progressive tax system, a more effective estate tax, better access to
education, universal health care, and stronger social protection
programs. Again, he does not recommend specific policies, but rather
provides a list of what he views as desirable policy outcomes. Those
outcomes are left-leaning: They would produce higher taxes, more
government spending, and more government oversight of the economy.
The inconsistency between Stiglitz's diagnosis of the problem
and his recommended reforms is that he believes the problems are caused
by government policy, yet he recommends more government as the solution.
If government is the problem, the obvious solution would be less
government, not more.
Stockman offers a list of 13 "crucial steps" he says are
needed, including reforming the Fed, abolishing deposit insurance,
developing a "super Glass Steagall" to separate commercial
banking from investment banking, abolishing incumbency, requiring a
balanced federal budget, separating the state from the free market,
abolishing social insurance, ending bailouts and subsidies, eliminating
10 federal agencies and departments, establishing a cash-based
means-tested safety net, abolishing the minimum wage, eliminating health
insurance, imposing a 30 percent wealth tax to pay down the national
debt, and repealing the Sixteenth Amendment.
In contrast to Stiglitz, Stockman recommends actual policies rather
than the results he hopes to see from policies, and his recommendations
in most cases call for smaller government rather than bigger government.
Both authors want to end corporate welfare, but Stiglitz wants to
enhance the welfare state's support of individuals while Stockman
wants to abolish that system and replace it with means-tested cash
transfers. Stiglitz wants to increase the progressivity of the income
tax; Stockman wants to eliminate the income tax. Both are pessimistic
that the system that is controlled by the 1 percent can be turned
around.
The Road Ahead: The War of Ideas
Stockman sees no hope. He says (p. 672), "Alas, none of these
solutions are even remotely possible within our now fully corrupted
constitutional framework. The latter is no longer a system of democratic
choice and governance; it is a tyranny of incumbency and money
politics." Stiglitz is slightly more optimistic. He notes the
importance of ideas, saying (p. 183), "The fact that the 1 percent
has so successfully shaped public perception testifies to the
malleability of beliefs. When others engage in it, we call it
'brainwashing' and 'propaganda.'" But the 1
percent controls the media and controls people's perceptions.
Regarding the present state of affairs, Stiglitz says (p. 186), "I
show how the 1 percent has used these advances to alter perceptions and
achieve its aims--to make our inequality seem less than it is and more
acceptable than it should be." He continues (p. 233),
"We've seen how the powerful manipulate public perception by
appeals to fairness and efficiency, while the real outcomes benefit only
them." The way out, then, is to win the war of ideas.
Dani Rodrik (2014) says the same thing, echoing Keynes's
(1936: 383) famous statement that "the ideas of economists and
political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are
wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the world
is ruled by little else." Academics reading this article will be
sympathetic to the notion that ideas trump interests, but therein lies
the big tension between Stiglitz and Stockman. They identify the same
problems, attribute those problems to the same causes, and agree on the
same pernicious results. But they offer very different solutions.
Stiglitz argues for bigger government and more government oversight of
the economy to address the problems caused by faulty government policy,
whereas Stockman argues, in the main, for the opposite.
Public policy recommendations, however, should take account of the
incentives of policymakers and the information available to them to make
informed public policies (Holcombe 2012). Both Stiglitz and Stockman do
this when diagnosing the problems, and they should extend this
methodology to designing policies to address those problems.
Conclusion
This article has demonstrated the similarity of the ideas of the
political left and right on the causes of contemporary
political-economic problems and their consequences, using Stiglitz as
the spokesman on the left and Stockman on the right. A brief reference
to other scholars on the left and right shows that their ideas are
representative across the political spectrum. (4) There is substantial
agreement that faulty U.S. government policy that systematically favors
the elite over the masses is damaging the market system and democracy.
Stiglitz and Stockman both believe their policy recommendations
represent the interests of average Americans, and neither believes that
the policies they recommend favor the 1 percent over the 99 percent.
Yet, the fact that their recommendations are so different points to the
political challenges working against reform.
It would be easy to argue that Stiglitz and Stockman both overstate
the degree to which ordinary Americans are harmed by government policies
that favor the 1 percent. Gilens and Page (forthcoming) offer a more
optimistic view. After undertaking an empirical study that shows the
influence of the preferences of elites and impotence of the preferences
of ordinary citizens, they find that "this does not mean that
ordinary citizens always lose out; they fairly often get the policies
they favor, but only because those policies happen also to be preferred
by the economically elite citizens who wield the actual influence."
(5)
The degree to which the elite control the political process is
certainly open to question. The highest income earners face a marginal
income tax rate of 40 percent or more when considering federal and state
taxes while the bottom half of the population pays almost no income
taxes. The U.S. corporate income tax rate is the highest in the world,
while more than half of government spending goes to transfer payments.
But set aside the question of whether Stiglitz and Stockman and others
have exaggerated the influence of the elite. Their agreement that
government is the cause of the problems they cite makes a powerful
argument for limiting the scope and power of government. The fact that
there is agreement on the left and the right on these problems and their
causes is worth noting. That points to the policy question of what
should be done to address those problems.
A government run by an omniscient benevolent dictator could
implement the policy proposals that Stiglitz or Stockman recommend (but
not both, because many of their recommendations are in conflict). In
fact, government policies are created and implemented through a
political process in which people who have more political power are
naturally inclined to use it for their benefit. If these authors are
correct in diagnosing the problem as being created by the abuse of
government power, the only real solution is to constrain the the power
of government. To think that increasing the scope and power of
government will make government more benevolent is wishful thinking.
References
Allison, J. A. (2013) The Financial Crisis and the Free Market
Cure. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Bartels, L. M. (2008) Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of
the New Gilded Age. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Beard, C. A. (1913) An Economic Interpretation of the Constitution
of the United States. New York: Macmillan.
Gilens, M. (2012) Affluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and
Political Power in America. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Hacker, J. S., and Pierson, P. (2010) Winner-Take-All Politics: How
Washington Made the Rich Richer--and Turned Its Back on the Middle
Class. New York: Simon & Schuster.
Holcombe, R. G. (2012) "Make Economics Policy-Relevant: Depose
the Omniscient benevolent Dictator." The Independent Review 17 (2):
165-76.
--(2013) "Crony Capitalism: By-Product of Big
Government." The Independent Review 17 (4): 541-59.
Holcombe, R. G., and Castillo, A. M. (2013) Liberalism, and
Cronyism: Two Rival Political and Economic Systems. Arlington, Va:
Mercatus Center.
Keynes, J. M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest,
and Money. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Co.
Kolko, G. (1977) The Triumph of Conservatism: A Reinterpretation of
American History, 1900-1916. New York: The Free Press.
McChesney, F. S. (1987) "Rent Extraction and Rent Creation in
the Economic Theory of Regulation." Journal of Legal Studies 16
(1): 101-18.
--(1997) Money for Nothing: Politicians, Rent Extraction, and
Political Extortion. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Piketty, T. (2014) Capitalism in the Twenty-First Century.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Rodrik, D. (2014) "When Ideas Trump Interests: Preferences,
World Views, and Policy Innovations." Journal of Economic
Perspectives 28 (1): 189-208.
Schweizer, P. (2013) Extortion: How Politicians Extract Your Money,
Buy Votes, and Line Their Own Pockets. Boston: Houghton Mifflin
Harcourt.
Stigler, G. J. (1971) "The Theory of Economic
Regulation." Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2:
3-21.
Stiglitz, J. E. (2012) The Price of Inequality: How Today's
Divided Society Endangers the Future. New York: W.W. Norton.
Stockman, D. A. (2013) The Great Deformation: The Corruption of
Capitalism in America. New York: Public Affairs Press.
Randall G. Holcombe is DeVoe Moore Professor of Economics at
Florida State University. The author gratefully acknowledges helpful
comments from William Shughart, James Dom, and an anonymous referee.
(1) Piketty's (2014) best-selling book emphasizes inequality
also, but the big difference between Stiglitz's analysis and
Piketty's is that while Stiglitz argues that government policy is
the major cause, Piketty argues that growing inequality is an inherent
characteristic of capitalism. A review of additional literature below
suggests that Stiglitz's view is more widely held, at least among
U.S. economists.
(2) A more pessimistic view of this type of activity is presented
by Schweizer (2013:4), who states, "Hiring a lobbyist aligned with
a powerful politician is more important than hiring a lobbyist with a
certain expertise or experience. Hiring a former staff member or family
member is better still. It's the favor that matters."
(3) Economists will recognize that Stiglitz is referring to
Stigler's (1971) capture theory of regulation.
(4) A recent exception is Piketty (2014). While Stiglitz, Stockman,
and a number of other authors noted earlier focus on faulty government
policy as the problem, Piketty argues that the inequality he and
Stiglitz view as the primary problem is inherent in the nature of
capitalism. Like Stockman, Piketty argues for a wealth tax, although
Piketty's wealth tax would be an annual progressive tax whereas
Stockman's recommended tax would be a one-time tax at a much higher
rate.
(5) Note the similar conclusion drawn by Beard (1913), who offered
a similar message of elite opinion trumping the masses in the writing of
the U.S. Constitution.