Europe and the United States: on the fiscal brink?
Gokhale, Jagadeesh ; Partin, Erin
What are the implications of Europe's economic troubles for
America? Several EU economies now face deep private and sovereign debt
overhangs--a situation not unlike that in the United States, which also
faces its own challenges with fiscal policy. How do the economic
conditions in America and the EU compare in the short and longer terms?
This article provides an overview of key indicators that summarize and
help to project the two regions' economic prospects. It should be
noted at the outset, however, that economic conditions and policies in
the two regions differ in substantive ways. As in the United States,
most European economies--members of the European Monetary Union
(EMU)--now participate in a single currency (euro) system operated by
the European Central Bank the counterpart of the U.S. Federal Reserve
System. However, the EU lacks a single central fiscal authority that
operates a significant cross-nation transfer system. Having surrendered
authority over monetary policy and, by the definition of a single
currency, exchange rate policy, EMU member nations must depend on
national fiscal policies to exert stewardship over their economies.
Many analysts predicted that such a system would display increasing
fiscal deficits in response to cyclical downturns--deficits that would
be difficult to reverse because of the incentives that such a system
creates: Short-term economic (and political) benefits of expansionary fiscal policies occur domestically, but long-term costs are spread
throughout the single-currency area through higher interest rates on
sovereign debt (Feldstein 2005: 1-2).
Since the advent of the euro, all EMU countries have had to
navigate through two key transitions: (1) an aging population and (2)
intensifying competition in global labor markets, especially for
low-skilled workers. Those trends imply increasing demands for social
protection--particularly retirement and health care benefits--for a
bulging retiree cohort and welfare support for low-skilled workers
facing stagnant wages, greater job-market volatility from business
outsourcing, and a progressively shortening skill-obsolescence cycle.
But both the U.S. and EMU regions already face large debt
overhangs. For EMU countries, different domestic economic pressures
imply different capacities to adhere to the Stability and Growth Pacts
statutory fiscal limits on national debt and annual deficits. In the
United States, massive global defense commitments compete with other
spending priorities in discretionary spending. And the discretionary
component of the U.S. federal budget competes with growing spending
projected for mandatory (entitlement and welfare) programs--a clash that
is likely to intensify during the next few years.
Social Protection Spending in Europe and the United States
Figure 1 shows expenditure components within general government
"social protection" programs in the United States and EMU
nations that include central government public retirement and
disability, health, and housing and welfare programs. Figure 1 shows
that while both economic blocs spend similar shares of their social
protection expenditures on housing and welfare programs, the United
States spends a much larger fraction of its "social protection
dollar" on health care expenditures (43 percent) than EMU nations
collectively spend out of their "social protection euro" (30
percent). It turns out that the ratio of the higher health-spending
share in the United States compared to EMU nations (1.45) is identical
to the ratio of the higher share of Social Security (old age and
disability insurance) expenditures of EMU nations (53 percent) compared
to the United States (37 percent).
Figure 2 shows that U.S. social protection expenditures are much
smaller as a share of total government spending (42 percent), compared
to EMU countries (58 percent). In addition, U.S. general government
expenditures are also smaller as a share of GDP (36 percent) compared to
EMU nations (51 percent). These two relative expenditure shares imply
that U.S. social protection expenditures are a much smaller fraction of
U.S. GDP (15 percent) compared to EMU nations' social protection
expenditures as a share of EMU GDP (30 percent).
It is noteworthy that across all government function
classifications, the United States expends larger shares of its GDP on
defense expenditures (international and domestic) than EU-27 nations as
a whole. But EU-27 nations spend more out of GDP on each and every other
government function category, with the largest spending-share difference
occurring in social protection services. It may be that U.S.
expenditures on defending Europe is inducing greater spending by EU
nations on social welfare and other expenditures. But prospects for EU
nations' future economic and budget outlook will depend on how well
they can consolidate budget expenditures to live within their means.
Ultimately, however, Europe's economic and fiscal sustainability
prospects depend on the evolution of fundamental economic factors,
namely, file growth of its population and productivity.
Population and Employment
As for population growth, three factors--immigration, mortality,
and fertility--will determine the age structure of the population, which
is crucial for the sustainability of age-related expenditure programs
such as Social Security and health care. For short and medium terms,
however, demographic factors are predetermined and the population's
age structure cannot be altered except through very substantial changes
in European net international immigration policies, which appear
unlikely. What economic policies could target, however, is the share of
the population that is employed. This could be achievable through the
adoption of pro-work economic policies. Such policies will determine
whether the direction of causality will be from demographics to social
protection spending to consumption and ultimately to (low) growth in
economic output or, alternatively, from policy-induced increases in
labor supply and output to additional resources in support of the
growing pool of retirees and workers who suffer economic setbacks.
High consumption stimulated by an aging population is likely to
require higher tax rates on the young. In addition, high consumption
means low saving and, therefore, financial constraints on investment. If
investment is not sustained, and higher taxes erode work incentives,
economic growth, which is already quite low, is likely to suffer during
the medium and long terms. The policy challenge that EU nations face is
to promote faster growth through enhanced work incentives. If such
policies are introduced and could successfully achieve higher employment
rates and faster output growth, they would help to accommodate future
social protection expenditure needs.
Figure 3 shows employment-to-population ratios in EU-27 nations,
selected individual EU nations, and the United States. EU-27 employment
rates were significantly below U.S. rates during the early 2000s.
Indeed, the explanation offered for the difference was higher taxes in
the EU for funding a generous social insurance state (Prescott 2004).
However, as Figure 3 shows, with booming housing and asset prices and
associated increases in employment and income during the mid-2000s, EU
employment had caught up with that of the United States by just before
the Great Recession of 2008-09. With the onset of that recession,
employment fell precipitously in Greece, Spain, and Ireland--countries
that were hardest hit by sovereign debt induced downturns or the
bursting of the house-price bubble. Employment rates declined more
sedately in France and the United Kingdom, whereas they increased in
Germany, which had adopted a "short-term-work" program of
employment subsidies.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Figure 4, which shows part-time employment rates in the same
countries as Figure 3, shows increases in employment rates. Presumably,
many former full-time employees were compelled to downshift to part-time
work 'after the recession began. As a result, total employment has
not declined as much as it would have otherwise. Figure 3 also reveals
differences among labor markets in EU nations--probably stemming from
differences in labor supply incentives, institutions, unionization, and
participation rates among women. For instance, pro-recession employment
rates in Italy, Greece, and Spain were much lower than in other EU
nations. Employment policies--such as statutory full retirement ages,
generosity of retirement benefits, unemployment support, and labor
market regulations on hiring and layoffs--across EU countries could be
better harmonized to increase employment rates in low-employment
countries. For the European monetary union to work better, EU
policymakers may need to broaden economic convergence criteria to
include such labor market metrics along with the EU Stability and Growth
Pact's convergence criteria in terms of overall deficit and debt
ratios. The harmonization must also emphasize the adoption of policies
consistent with stronger work incentives designed to raise employment
rates in nations with low rates rather than vice-versa. Doing so is
likely to be very challenging as it will require harmonizing many
politically sensitive tax, welfare, and retirement rules, many of which
provide benefits unrelated to engagement in the labor market and make
working less attractive. (1)
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Productivity
Figure 5 shows output per person during the 2000s in EU-27 and the
United States. Productivity increased more rapidly after the recession
onset in 2008 in hard-hit countries--Spain, Ireland, and Greece
(initially). One interpretation of this is that companies in these
countries responded to the downturn by increasing their production
efficiency. But a more straightforward explanation is that the more
rapid productivity growth observed in hard-hit countries is the artifact of higher layoffs in those countries of marginally productive workers.
Productivity growth in France and Germany (the largest EU nations) hews
closely to the EU-27 average, as expected (country details not shown).
Output per person also grew faster in the United States compared to
EU-27--probably an artifact of the greater absorption of workers into
part-time employment in the EU compared to the United States. Thus, the
situation in both the EU and the United States is one of a large pool of
underemployed and laid-off workers, some of the latter being at risk of
becoming permanently unemployed, and improving productivity growth
(measured as output per person) among those who remain employed in the
economy. The challenge, therefore, is to find ways to retrain and
assimilate the unemployed and underemployed workers back into full-time
employment--and to hasten the so-far rather tepid economic recovery. The
strategy for triggering an economic recovery depends upon the nature of
the unemployment in the United States and Europe. In the United States,
recent research shows that among two types of unemployment--cyclical and
structural--the former dominates in the aftermath of the Great Recession
(Lazaer and Spletzer 2012). (2) The implication of this finding for the
United States is that there is no severe skills mismatch among workers
and jobs in the United States and that the key solution is through
increasing aggregate demand (i.e., consumption plus investment). Europe,
however, continues to be plagued by labor market inflexibility in
adjusting to a new postrecession world with increasingly intense
international competition in product markets. This challenge requires
shifting the work force into higher value-added occupations and requires
revising labor market regulations to encourage greater worker mobility
across occupations, sectors, and regions within the EU.
Economic Growth Strategy: Transition from Stimulus to Debt
Reduction
What might be the best approach to rapidly return employment close
to its pre-recession high--and push the unemployment rate back toward
its pre-recession low?
The United States federal government implemented large fiscal and
monetary stimulus measures to support the economy during the recession.
In European countries with large government debt overhangs, however, the
response has been the opposite--to reduce government spending and lay
workers off in order to sustain financial market confidence and maintain
low borrowing rates. EU nations with critical limits on government
revenue-generating abilities have been awarded many billions of euros in
bailout funds from the EU, the European Central Bank, and international
lending institutions. Clearly, such initiatives have negative
consequences--moral hazard among private investors, government
officials, and policymakers charged with implementing budget
consolidations which means that they must eventually be curtailed or
reversed. As shown below, one key reason that bailouts cannot be
continued for long is that most EU nations, including the strongest ones
such as Germany and France, are facing large internal fiscal imbalances.
The short-term results of these deficit-Financed stimulus measures
can be seen in Figure 6. Gross (explicit) debt as a percentage of GDP in
both EU nations and in the United States increased significantly during
the recession as governments injected considerable amounts of stimulus
funds into stagnating economies.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
The increase in debt-financed government spending compensated for
reduced aggregate demand from a decline in private gross domestic
investment as shown in Figure 7. In the longer term, however, such heavy
reliance on government deficit-financed expenditures would be
unsustainable. The normal and natural process of economic recovery must
occur through a restoration of private-sector investment and consumption
demand to support job creation and sustainable economic growth. As
Figure 7 shows, the key shortfall is in private investment demand, which
declined precipitously during the Great Recession and has yet to return
to pre-recession levels. Unfortunately, the near-term outlook for a
resurgence of private investment demand appears to be poor. Pervasive
uncertainty caused by political dysfunction in the United States in
reducing large projected deficits and uncertainty over near-term public
spending and taxes continues to discourage investors and lenders from
risk taking. And recent electoral results in Italy cast doubt on the
ability of EU nations to sustain budget consolidation plans. Failure to
resolve policy uncertainty in both Europe and the United States means
that private investment demand is unlikely to surge anytime soon.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
A quick look at recent history on private final consumption demand
in Figure 8 (shown on the same vertical-axis scale as Figure 7) reveals
that in file EU as a whole, private final consumption expenditures were
growing through 2008 and have since remained flat. The overall
consumption time series for the EU is an average across significantly
different consumption-change patterns from strong pre-recession surges
giving way to significant declines in hard-hit countries such as Greece,
Spain, and Ireland, to countries where demand has simply stalled such as
the UK and Italy, and to countries with continued consumption growth
such as France and Germany. Note that despite the large size of France
and Germany, overall consumption growth in the EU as a whole has
remained flat 'after the recession because the declines in hard-hit
countries have been substantial. Notwithstanding cross-country
differences, however, consumption demand remains stable or positive in
the EU and is not the key reason for economic stagnation in Europe. In
the United States consumption growth has resumed after a short setback
during 2009.
The balance of trade in goods and services, suggests that the trade
balance is not large for the EU as a whole. The key reason for this is
that the vast majority of the goods and services trade of EU nations
occurs with other EU countries. The data (not shown) indicate that only
Ireland and Germany have been net exporters--benefitting from foreign
demand for their products. Most other EU nations (with the exception of
Spain, which appears headed for an export surplus in 2012) and the
United States are accruing annual trade deficits--implying a structural
imbalance in exchange rates, international uncompetitiveness in export
markets, and a siphoning, on net, of domestic demand to foreign shores.
This effect is especially large for the United States. However, that has
been the case since well before the recession. In particular, the
recession does not appear to have widened the gap between U.S. exports
and imports and, by implication, should not bear as high a
responsibility (as a target of policy measures) for boosting the
economic recovery.
The key shortfall in aggregate demand is, therefore, contributed by
private investment demand. For both the EU as a whole and the United
States, investment flows declined significantly during the recession and
have yet to recover. For EU-27, investment flows are still 15 percent
smaller than their pre-recession levels. For the United States, they are
running 17 percent slower. Since private investment is crucial for
sustaining employment growth in the short term and boosting productivity
in the long term, this shortfall, if sustained, is likely to visit
lasting damage on long-term labor market and output growth potentials in
both regions.
One symptom of low investment demand in the United States is
massive cash accumulation with businesses. The share of cash-equivalents
increased as the Great Recession commenced and has not returned to its
pre-recession share. The most likely reason for this is high continued
uncertainty about the future course of U.S. fiscal policy, especially
with regard to additional taxes that may be imposed on capital and
capital returns.
There are frequent references in the financial market literature
about the potential for capital flight in response to higher taxes on
capital returns. Many cite strong business incentives to transfer
capital and profits to low-tax countries, with such tax competition
penalizing countries with high corporate income taxes and investment
inflexibility created by high capital gains taxes. The first step in
preparing for capital flight from the United States would, naturally, be
to preserve capital in the form of liquid assets. Because of its
flexible labor and asset markets and the abundance of complementarities
with high-skilled workers, the United States is still considered to be a
highly desirable place to invest. But facing considerable uncertainty
about future tax policies that could affect business incomes negatively,
the observed corporate holdings of higher portions of financial assets in cash and cash equivalents may be intended to make it easier to
transfer assets to other shores with better opportunities and
returns--in case policy uncertainty persists for too long or is resolved
in an adverse manner.
Fiscal Imbalances in Europe and the United States
Prospects of future fiscal policy changes must be evaluated
relative to payment obligations that governments have assumed and the
resources available to pay them. Unfortunately, most European countries
and the United States are facing large debt overhangs that extend well
beyond their officially recognized financial liabilities. Government
obligations to pay include not just official explicit (or contractual)
debt, but also noncontractual promises to pay retirement, health, and
other benefits to citizens under today's laws governing public
social security and health insurance programs. Significant unfunded
obligations on account of these programs arise, in part, from their
demographic profiles, with large cohorts of baby-boomer scheduled to
enter retirement within a few years. Figure 9 shows the demographic
profiles in the EU and the United States. The solid black line refers to
the population's age distribution during 2010 ("today")
and the light solid line shows the projected age distribution in 2040.
Figure 9 shows large increases in the population share of older
individuals, implying higher costs of funding old-age retirement and
health care benefits. It is noteworthy that among EU nations, the
population share of younger individuals is depressed in Spain, Greece,
Germany, and Italy whereas it remains high in the UK, United States,
France, and Ireland (data not shown).
The extent of population aging depends on mortality improvements
and the rates of fertility declines in various countries. The fertility
rates shown in Figure 10 indicate that many developed economies are now
experiencing fertility rates well below the replacement fertility rate of 2.1 children per woman. Among the countries shown in Figure 10,
Germany, Spain, Italy, and Greece have among the lowest fertility rates
and the EU average is also not close to the replacement fertility rate.
The one heartening feature for European countries, however, is that
fertility rates have been trending upward during the decade of the
2000s. Figure 10 shows that fertility in the United States is very close
to replacement, implying that even a small rate of immigration would
ensure positive population growth in the future.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
Rapid population aging from lifespan extension and low
(below-replacement) fertility rates contribute toward increased fiscal
burdens on future generations who must remain productive to fund old-age
consumption of retired boomers. However, other factors also contribute
to high prospective fiscal burdens on younger cohorts.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
One is the share of the budget allocated to generational transfer
programs. Another is the intensity of generational transfers within each
such program (how highly skewed benefit awards are toward retirees and
how steep are taxes on younger workers relative to older ones). Yet
another factor is the rate of growth of the economy and whether
generational transfer benefits are linked to economic growth and
inflation. If they are linked, faster economic growth may translate into
larger fiscal burdens on the young, especially when population aging is
rapid (see Gokhale 2007). All of these factors are estimated by
combining budget data and micro-survey data (separately for each nation)
to measure their collective effect in determining each nation's
fiscal imbalance.
Estimated fiscal imbalances are reported in Figure 11 as ratios to
the present value of future GDP separately for EU-25, the United States,
and for 25 European Union countries. The figure reports the implicit and
explicit debt ratio components separately, with the sum of the two
equaling the fiscal imbalance ratio. As Figure 11 shows, the fiscal
imbalance ratio for the United States (calculated as of 2012) equals 9
percent of the present value of U.S. GDP and 9.9 percent for the EU-25
as a ratio of the present value of EU-25 GDP. These ratio values are
deceptively small because most tax bases are much smaller than GDP. For
example, the U.S. payroll tax base equals slightly less than one-half of
U.S. GDP, implying that the 15.3 percent U.S. payroll tax rate would
have to be more than doubled to resolve the U.S. fiscal imbalance.
The EU-25 benchmark fiscal imbalance ratio of 9.9 percent of the
present value of future EU-25 GDP is the consequence of a stronger
population aging process and more generous social insurance programs
favoring older generations in Europe compared to the United States. With
such large imbalances looming for even the strongest EU nations (with
both German and French fiscal imbalance ratios exceeding 10 percent), it
is difficult to argue in favor of significant additional deficit
financed economic stimulus policies with the hope of speeding up
economic growth. A better way to improve the economic and policy
environment is to restructure social protection programs by reducing
benefit growth and to stimulate private investment by maintaining low
and stable tax rates.
Conclusion
Demographics appear to be destiny in many European nations and in
the United States. Unless growth of social protection programs
(so-called entitlements) is curbed, higher fiscal burdens on
today's young workers and lucre generations and a spending squeeze
on nonentitlement government operations appear inevitable. (3) In the
United States, which has extensive defense commitments around the globe,
the battle between "guns and butter" could not be more
explicit. At the time of this writing, Congress and the Obama
administration have postponed all spending-related policy actions and
have voted to make G.W. Bush era tax cuts permanent for the vast
majority of taxpayers. European nations do not have similar commitments
abroad, but many of them are clearly overextended in their domestic
social protection commitments. However, the larger fiscal burdens on
younger and future working generations, which such a fiscal policy
stance implies, threaten to sap their productive abilities (education
and skill acquisition) and reduce their incentives to remain attached to
the labor force. The overall resource allocation calculus, for both
Europe and the United States could be shifted, at the margin and in a
budget neutral manner, from entitlements and social protection
expenditures for the elderly to education and job-training initiatives
for employers and younger workers.
References
Feldstein, M. (2005) "The Euro and the Stability Pact."
National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 11249 (March).
Gokhale, J. (2007) "The Connection between Wage Growth and
Social Security's Financial Condition." Cato Institute, Policy
Analysis No. 607 (December).
-- (2013) "Spending beyond Our Means: How We Are Bankrupting
Future Generations." Cato Institute White Paper (February).
Lazaer, E. P., and Spletzer, J. R. (2012) "The United States
Labor Market: Status Quo or New Normal?" National Bureau of
Economic Research, Working Paper No. 18368 (September).
Prescott, E. C. (2004) "Why Do Americans Work So Much More
than Europeans?" Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly
Review 28 (1): 2-13.
Jagadeesh Gokhale is a Senior Fellow, and Erin Partin is a Research
Assistant, at the Cato Institute.
(1) Of course, this is easier said than done because of entrenched political interest groups among current workers, their unions, retirees,
and those wishing to protect against erosion of public pension promises.
However, the reforms mentioned in the text could be introduced
gradually, targeting the longer-term labor-market environment that
today's younger workers will face, allowing them to adjust their
market-supply choices, including migration across EU nations, to achieve
greater labor-market flexibility and a quicker structural response to
cross-country disparities in compensation and work environments--a
condition that is currently lacking among EU countries.
(2) This finding is unlikely to be true for Europe, where labor
laws generate several types of rigidities and retirement and welfare
programs create poor work incentives.
(3) See Gokhale (2013) for more details for the United States.
FIGURE 1
COMPONENTS OF SOCIAL PROTECTION EXPENDITURES IN
THE UNITED STATES AND EMU NATIONS
Percentage of Social Protection Spending
United States EU-27
Health 43.1 29.6
Housing and Welfare 20.4 17.5
Retirement and Disability 36.5 52.9
SOURCE: Eurostat and U.S. Congressional Budget Office.
Note: Table made from bar graph.
FIGURE 2
SOCIAL PROTECTION EXPENDITURE SHARES IN GDP
United States EU-27
Social Protection in 41.9 57.9
Government Spending
Government Spending 36.1 51.0
Share in GDP
Social Protection 15.0 29.5
Spending Share in
GDP
SOURCE: Eurostat and U.S. Congressional Budget Office.
Note: Table made from bar graph.
FIGURE 11
FISCAL IMBALANCE RATIOS IN THE UNITED STATES (2012)
AND EUROPE (2010)
Implicit Debt
Ireland 18.1 0.6
Poland 11.5 1.9
Greece 11.3 2.1
Portugal 10.9 1.4
France 9.5 1.0
Finland 9.9 0.6
The Netherlands 9.4 0.9
Germany 8.9 1.2
Latvia 9.7 0.2
Spain 9.0 0.8
Hungary 9.0 0.8
Austria 8.7 0.9
Slovenia 9.1 0.4
Lithuania 8.9 0.3
Slovak Republic 8.8 0.3
Italy 7.0 2.0
United Kingdom 7.9 0.8
Czech Republic 8.2 0.3
Malta 7.1 1.0
Denmark 7.5 0.6
Belgium 5.5 1.8
Sweden 6.4 0.4
Cyprus 6.0 0.7
Luxembourg 4.9 0.2
Estonia 4.4 0.0
United States 8.0 1.0
EU-25 Benchmark 8.8 1.1
NOTE: The fiscal imbalance equals the government's explicit
debt plus the present value difference between all projected
government receipts and government expenditures under current
fiscal policies.
SOURCE: Author's calculations.
Note: Table made from bar graph.