Red Ink: Inside the High-Stakes Polities of the Federal Budget.
Mitchell, Daniel J.
Red Ink: Inside the High-Stakes Polities of the Federal Budget
David Wessel
New York: Crown Business, 2012, 224 pp.
If you want a primer on fiscal policy issues that gives you an
establishment perspective, David Wessel's Red Ink should be your
cup of tea. If you thought the 1990 budget deal was a good thing and if
you want something similar today, you should read Red Ink to have your
views reinforced.
But if you want to understand anything about the economics of
fiscal policy, and you get irked by mistakes that conveniently promote a
more statist narrative, then you probably shouldn't read the book.
Let's start with the good news. Red Ink is very readable,
logically organized, and it includes numerous interesting vignettes (I
didn't realize that the social disaster we call Prohibition was
made possible in the 1920s only because the economic disaster we call
the income tax was imposed in 1913).
Moreover, if you read Red Ink, you will be better informed than 98
percent of the population. You will know lots of details about defense
spending, tax collections, entitlement programs, and the 1974
Congressional Budget Act. I'm not sure that will make you a welcome
guest at dinner parties, but at least you'll sort of understand how
much the government is spending and how fiscal policy is decided in
Washington.
Wessel is not polemical. There's no shrillness and you
won't feel that he's trying to enlist you in a campaign. But
here's the bad news: You won't have much understanding of good
fiscal policy after you finish the book. Indeed, you may be lured into
thinking that the main problem is excessive deficits and that raising
taxes is the "responsible" solution. Except, of course, when
deficits are too small and spending should be increased.
For better or worse, Red Ink reflects the establishment consensus.
Based on what Wessel has written, he would make a perfect press
spokesman for the Congressional Budget Office, the Committee for a
Responsible Federal Budget, or the International Monetary Fund.
Best of all, the press releases almost write themselves. If the
economy is weak, you simply insert phrases such as "targeted
spending increases to stimulate the economy." And you'll never
go wrong if you use terms such as "revenue enhancement for fairness
and balance." The fact that establishment thinking has not worked
very well--whether in Japan, Europe, or the United States--doesn't
seem to matter.
Is this an unfair portrayal? Well, let's just examine some of
Wessel's assertions. He writes, "Today's budget deficit
is not an economic problem--tomorrow's is." Setting aside the
fact that he's focusing on the symptom of government borrowing
rather than the underlying disease of government spending, what
he's really saying is that the right fiscal policy today is
Keynesian "stimulus."
To show this is no exaggeration, Wessel also writes, "Running
bigger deficits in a deep recession and sluggish recovery is still
Economics 101." In other words, Wessel is embracing the thinking
that the Obama administration used in 2009 (and the Bush administration
used in 2008) to justify bigger government.
And what about the fact that the economy has suffered the worst
recovery of any business cycle since the end of World War II? Wessel
wants us to believe that the economy would have been in far worse shape
without Obama's so-called stimulus, asserting that "the
argument that such massive spending had no impact on the economy at all
hasn't much merit."
Presumably he would also say the stagnation of the 1930s was the
result of inadequate stimulus, even though Hoover increased the burden
of spending by about 50 percent in just four years and Roosevelt then
doubled the budget in the next eight years. Likewise, the pervasive
stagnation of the Japanese economy for the past two decades somehow
would be unrelated to its dozen or so Keynesian packages.
To be lair, libertarians, small-government conservatives, and
classical liberals would agree that massive government spending has an
impact. But they would argue that the impact is negative. Beyond the
outlays necessary to finance core public goods, government expenditures
generally undermine economic performance by misallocating labor and
capital.
But it's not just the pro-Keynesian bias that makes this book
disappointing. Like almost everyone else in the establishment, Wessel
assumes that the nation's main fiscal problem is red ink and that
tax increases should be part of any supposed solution.
That presumption is annoying for those who those of us who think
good fiscal policy is achieved by reducing the burden of government
spending. And it is irritating that he blithely assumes that higher
taxes are the right approach when this misidentifies the problem,
assumes projected revenue increases will materialize, and overlooks the
incentive of politicians to spend any additional revenue.
One doesn't get the sense that Wessel is pushing an
ideological agenda or that he's driven by animosity to the notion
of limited government. It's more as if he's spent too much
time reading CBO reports, CRFB statements, and IMF studies and
doesn't realize there are alternative viewpoints.
Or perhaps he simply doesn't take those views seriously, which
might be a reasonable assumption since the last two Republican
presidents showed they were very capable of fiscal profligacy.
What irritated me most about Red Ink, though, were the mistakes,
particularly since every mistake seemed to be part of a narrative that
advanced a policy agenda of bigger government.
He wrote, for instance, that in the 1930s, "government
spending pulled the U.S. economy out of the ditch." Yet the economy
suffered a Great Depression for 10 years at a time when government
spending expanded dramatically. At the very least, Wessel should offer
some evidence before making that kind of assertion.
To be sure, he could make the standard Keynesian argument that the
depression would have been deeper. And he could make the case that World
War II was an example of successful Keynesian fiscal policy, while
somehow explaining away the Keynesian predictions that a depression
would reappear once wartime spending was reduced. But he doesn't do
those things. He simply wants us to accept the narrative, perhaps
because he has never thought to investigate alternative viewpoints.
Wessel also seems to have a poor understanding of the Reagan years.
For instance, he writes, "On spending, much of the Reagan cabinet
and a good chunk of the Republican congressional leadership labored to
shield their favorite programs from Stockman's knife. And they
succeeded."
I agree with the first part of that quote, but it would be nice to
know what he means by "they succeeded." Total domestic
spending was reduced by 2.5 percent of economic output during the Reagan
years, a remarkable achievement given the normal tendency of government
to expand.
Wessel also makes the assertion that "when Reagan turned the
presidency over to George H. W. Bush, the deficit was 2.8 percent of
GDP--and rising." This is laughably wrong, as he could have
ascertained by looking at the Congressional Budget Office's
Economic and Budget Outlook for early 1989, which showed that deficits
were supposed to shrink as a share of economic output if Reagan's
policies were left in place.
As one might imagine, Wessel praises various tax increases and
seems very fond of the 1990 budget deal. He writes, "The final deal
cut spending by $2 for every $1 of tax increases." And he favorably
quotes Brace Bartlett's assertion that "the budget surpluses
of the late 1990s owe much to the policies put in place by George H. W.
Bush that his son and party later repudiated."
Having lived through that battle, I can definitely say that
spending was increased rather than decreased. Indeed, a major impetus
for the deal was a desire to cancel the Gramm-Rudman law that would have
imposed genuine spending restraint. The 1990 tax hike enabled bigger
government than would have been the case--much as Obama tried to seduce
Republicans into a tax increase to replace the fiscal discipline of
sequestration.
Unsurprisingly, Wessel also says that Clinton's 1993 tax
increase "worked as promised." Too bad he didn't look at
Clinton's own budget 18 months later, which projected
perpetual--and gradually rising--budget deficits of more than $200
billion. The thing that changed that trajectory was the election of a
fiscally conservative Congress in 1994. Those lawmakers took office in
early 1995 and proceeded to oversee a four-year period where government
spending grew only 2.9 percent annually. That's why projected
deficits turned into surpluses.
Even on little issues, Wessel inevitably embraces a pro-government
narrative. He writes that "Medicare ... has increased the odds that
a sixty-five-year-old will make it to age seventy by about 13
percent." Well, maybe that's true. Life expectancy for the
elderly has increased since Medicare was created. But if he bothered to
look at the long-run data, he would see that life expectancy for the
elderly was increasing at the same rate in the decades before Medicare
was created. This doesn't mean that Medicare didn't have some
positive impact, but it certainly isn't obvious from
life-expectancy data.
Let's close with one of the vignettes that make the book an
interesting read. Wessel quotes Erskine Bowles, who served as President
Clinton's chief of staff, saying that Social Security reform was
virtually a done deal in the late 1990s: "Gingrich wanted to do it.
Clinton wanted to do it. It was a real missed opportunity."
And in contrast to the undesirable options being discussed today,
such as "chained CPI" or means testing, Gingrich and Clinton
were looking at personal retirement accounts. So why didn't it
happen? As Bowles noted, "Monica changed everything" by
creating the conditions that led to impeachment and destroying
bipartisanship.
So now we're stuck with an actuarially bankrupt Social
Security system that is bad for workers and bad for taxpayers, thus
making the incident with Monica the most costly intimate encounter that
ever took place.
Daniel J. Mitchell
Cato Institute