The coming fiat money cataclysm and the case for gold.
Dowd, Kevin ; Hutchinson, Martin ; Kerr, Gordon 等
An almost hysterical antagonism toward the gold standard is one
issue which unites statists of all persuasions. They seem to sense ...
that gold and economic freedom are inseparable.
Alan Greenspan (1966)
The Age of Chartalist or State Money was reached when the State
claimed the right to declare what thing should answer as money to the
current money-of-account--when it claimed the right not only to enforce
the dictionary but also to write the dictionary. Today all civilised
money is, beyond the possibility of dispute, chartalist.
John Maynard Keynes (1930)
A recurring theme in monetary history is the conflict of trust and
authority: the conflict between those who advocate a spontaneous
monetary order determined by free exchange under the rule of law and
those who wish to meddle with the monetary system for their own ends.
This conflict is perhaps most clearly seen in the early 20th century
controversy over the "state theory of money" (or
"chartalism"), which maintained that money is a creature of
the state. The one side was represented by the defenders of the old
monetary order--most notably by the Austrian economists Ludwig von Mises
and Friedrich Hayek, and by the German sociologist Georg Simmel. The
other side was represented by the German legal scholar Georg Friedrich
Knapp and by John Maynard Keynes. They argued that on monetary matters
the government should be free to do whatever it liked, free from any
constraints of law or even conventional morality.
States have claimed the right to manipulate money for thousands of
years. The results have been disastrous, and this is particularly so
with the repeated experiments with inconvertible or fiat paper
currencies such those of medieval China, John Law and the assignats in
18th century France, the continentals of the Revolutionary War, the
greenbacks of the Civil War, and, most recently, in modern Zimbabwe. All
such systems were created by states to finance their expenditures
(typically to finance wars) and led to major economic disruption and
ultimate failure, and all ended either with the collapse of the currency
or a return to commodity money. Again and again, fiat monetary systems
have shown themselves to be unmanageable and, hence, unsustainable.
The same is happening with the current global fiat system that has
prevailed since the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in the early
1970s. The underlying principle of this system is that central banks and
governments could boost spending as they wished and ignore previous
constraints against the overissue of currency and deficit finance;
implicitly, they could (and did) focus on the short term and felt no
compunctions whatever kicking the can down the road for other people to
pick up. Since then loose monetary policies have led to the dollar
losing over 83 percent of its purchasing power. (1) A combination of
artificially low interest rates, loose money, and numerous incentives to
take excessive risks--all caused, directly or indirectly, by state
meddling--have led to an escalating systemic solvency crisis
characterized by damaging asset price bubbles, unrepayable debt levels,
an insolvent financial system, hopelessly insolvent governments, and
rising inflation. Yet, instead of addressing these problems by the
painful liquidations and cutbacks that are needed, current policies are
driven by an ever more desperate attempt to postpone the day of
reckoning. Consequently, interest rates are pushed ever lower and
central banks embark on further monetary expansion and debt
monetization. However, such policies serve only to worsen these problems
and, unless reversed, will destroy the currency and much of the economy
with it. In short, the United States and its main European counterparts
are heading for a collapse of their fiat money regimes. (2)
The Impact of a Low Interest Rate Policy
The impacts of state intervention in the monetary and financial
system are subtle and profound, but also highly damaging and often
unforeseen. A good place to start is Hayek's well-known analysis of
the impact of a lower interest rate policy in Prices and Production in
1931. Hayek focuses on the "malinvestments" created by such
policies--the unsustainable longer-term investments that would not
otherwise have taken place that are eventually corrected by market
forces that manifest themselves in a recession in which earlier
malinvestments are abandoned and the economy goes through the necessary
but inevitable painful restructuring (see also O'Driscoll 2011).
Low interest rate policies not only set off a malinvestment cycle
but also generate destabilizing asset price bubbles, a key feature of
which is the way the policy rewards the bulls in the market (those who
gamble on the boom continuing) at the expense of the sober-minded bears
who keep focused on the fundamentals, instead of allowing the market to
reward the latter for their prudence and punish the former for their
recklessness. Such intervention destabilizes markets by encouraging herd
behavior and discouraging the contrarianism on which market stability
ultimately depends. A case in point is the Fed's low interest rate
policy in the late 1990s: this not only stoked the tech boom but was
maintained for so long that it wiped out most of the bears, who were
proven right but (thanks to the Fed) too late, and whose continued
activities would have softened the subsequent crash. The same is
happening now but in many more markets (financials, general stocks,
Treasuries, junk bonds, and commodities) and on a much grander scale.
Such intervention embodies an arbitrariness that is wrong in principle
and injects a huge amount of unnecessary uncertainty into the market.
Another unexpected and almost unnoticed effect of artificially low
interest rates has been to replace labor with capital, leading to
unemployment and attendant downward pressure on wage rates. This effect
is very apparent if one contrasts recent low interest rates with the
very high interest rates of the Volcker disinflation 30 years ago:
* Then, high real interest rates reduced the level of capital
applied to the economy and made obsolete a high proportion of the
existing capital stock. However, demand for labor remained high in the
areas of the country that were not suffering from bankruptcy of their
capital stock, in particular on the East and West coasts. Once the
recession lifted, therefore, job creation was exceptionally buoyant.
* With recent low interest rates, on the other hand, it is labor
that is substituted out: hence, job loss levels in the winter of 2008-09
were far above those of any recession since the early 1930s, and the
level of long-term unemployment is far above that of the early 1980s,
especially when one takes into account the legions of discouraged
workers who have exhausted their benefits and dropped out of the
unemployment statistics.
This effect is overlooked by Keynesians who maintain that lower
interest rates lead to lower unemployment via greater spending, and is
another example of the need to take account of relative prices and not
just focus on aggregates alone.
A related effect is to encourage excessive outsourcing, as capital
is excessively substituted for overseas labor and jobs and even
innovation are moved offshore. Outsourcing a product or service to Asia
not only makes it cheaper but also increases the capabilities of the
overseas workforce, raising its capability still further and making it
competitive in more sophisticated products and services. To some extent,
outsourcing is a natural and beneficial aspect of globalization, but
excessively low interest rates push this process too far. This happens
in part by making capital too cheap, leading to too much overseas
investment and excessive substitution of overseas for U.S. labor. This
also happens by depressing yields, which leads yield-seeking investors
into higher-risk investments such as emerging markets. If Vietnam, for
example, can then raise money almost as easily as Ohio, then capital
will be diverted to lower-cost Vietnam and manufacturing jobs that would
otherwise have remained in the United States will migrate with it. This
latter channel is a perfect example of the law of unintended
consequences that illustrates how subtle the damaging consequences of
low interest rate policies can be.
Artificially low interest rates also reduce the productive
efficiency of the U.S. economic engine by adversely affecting
productivity and the rate at which technological advance translates into
living standards. This effect shows up clearly in the multifactor
productivity data. The most recent data show that during 2005-09 annual
average multifactor productivity grew by only 0.2 percent, well below
the post-1948 average of 1.17 percent. Had multifactor productivity in
2005-09 risen at its long-term rate, output in 2009 would have been
perhaps 5 percent higher.
Taking these effects together, we can see that lower interest rates
have damaging effects on capital accumulation, output, and living
standards. These effects come through (1) the misallocations of capital
and long-term decapitalization associated with repeated destabilizing
boom-bust cycles; (2) the damaging effects of policy-induced
uncertainty; (3) the loss of capital, jobs, and innovation overseas; (4)
reductions in productivity growth; and (5) reduced savings rates which
discourage the accumulation of capital in the first place (see Dowd and
Hutchinson 2011).
State Intervention and the Financial System
State intervention also has a profoundly damaging effect on the
financial system. Government deposit insurance, for example, creates a
well-known moral hazard that encourages banks to take more risks than
they would otherwise take and increase their leverage, which weakens the
whole banking system. Less well understood is that it creates a race to
the bottom, in which banks take more and more risks and become ever more
leveraged over time, culminating eventually in the collapse of the
banking system. These problems are aggravated further by other policies
to support the banking system such as a central bank lender of last
resort, the anticipation of bailouts and, of course, "too big to
fail" (TBTF).
The standard response to these problems is capital adequacy
regulation to force banks to observe minimum capital requirements that
will, allegedly, protect their Financial health. However, capital
regulation does not work: the Basel system of international bank capital
regulation has shown itself to be a total failure (Dowd et al. 2011,
Kerr 2011b). The system itself is easily captured and manipulated by the
banking industry. At the most basic level, this is because the rules are
poorly designed by officials who do not understand the banking system:
the rules themselves often make no sense, and are easily gamed (3) and
often counterproductive.
To give just one example, the rules give sovereign debt a zero
weight based on the underlying assumption that sovereign debt is free
from default risk. This is self-evident nonsense, as the examples of
Greece and many other eurozone countries demonstrate. It is also
counterproductive, because it incentivizes banks to hold government debt
in preference to, say, commercial debt or loans to small business, and
this is a critical factor driving the current eurozone crisis. This
example illustrates how an obscure regulation might receive little
attention when first installed but can help produce an immense crisis 20
years later. Furthermore, this distorted incentive will increase sharply
when Basel III raises capital weights from 8 percent to about 15
percent.
The result of these and other state interventions is a highly
dysfunctional and overpaid banking system, especially as regards the
biggest banks:
* Lending is no longer the banks' core activity. Instead,
banks make most of their income from trading--for example, in 2010, the
six largest bank holding companies generated 74 percent of their pretax
income from trading (Wilmers 2011) and yield-curve riding courtesy of
the Fed. (4)
* Bankers are overcompensated. To illustrate: the average
investment banking compensation at four of the top banks was at least
six times that of the average American worker, and the CEOs of the top
six bank holding companies were paid 516 times U.S. median household
income and 2.3 times the average total CEO compensation of the top
Fortune 50 nonbank companies (Wilmers 2011).
* The banks enjoy unique privileges (lender of last resort support,
massive bailouts, and TBTF) all underwritten by the state, and are
hopelessly dependent on the continuation of current low interest rates
policies.
* Confidence in the banks has long since evaporated; unsecured
interbank lending has all but vanished; and the banks are kept going
only by state support.
It is important to appreciate that the main driving factor here is
the deterioration and ultimately collapse of effective corporate
governance in banks, all ultimately due to state intervention (Dowd and
Hutchinson 2010). The result is a situation in which the bankers have no
serious stake in the long-term survival of their own banks; instead,
they have become entirely fixated with their own short-term
compensation, and if their efforts to make a quick buck bring down their
banks, then someone else can sort that out later and the banks can count
on another bailout anyway. This incentive structure is the single most
important direct cause of the crash.
In essence, the task of the modern investment banker is to
construct a personally lucrative witch's brew, encouraged by
accounting and regulatory rules designed by scrutineers with little
understanding of the financial system. Such concoctions may comprise
some or all of the following ingredients:
* Financial models that underestimate the risks involved (e.g.,
portfolio credit-risk models that ignore or underestimate correlations).
* Financial engineering (e.g., collateralized debt obligations or
CDOs, in which claims against underlying pools of loans or bonds are
tranched or ranked by seniority and sold off), and derivatives
(especially credit derivatives, e.g., credit default swaps or CDSs, or
bets on credit events such as downgrades and defaults) designed to slice
and dice risks to maximum personal advantage. Particularly helpful in
this regard are synthetic positions (e.g., synthetic CDOs that are even
more highly leveraged and in which little or no cash changes hands up
front). These include CDOs-squared (i.e., CDOs in which the underlying
pools of loans or bonds are replaced with CDOs) and even CDOs-cubed (in
which the underlying pools are replaced with CDOs-squared). A remarkable
example of the economically most destructive engineering was the
synthetic CDOs designed to keep the subprime machine going. Hedge funds
that were betting on the collapse were buying CDS from investment banks
who in turn were laying off this risk primarily with AIG. When the
underlying subprime borrowing market reached its capacity, the banks
responded by creating synthetic subprime which was then sold off to
unwitting investors (Lewis 2010). (5) This explains why the eventual
subprime losses suffered by the banking system were substantially
greater than the volume of the subprime market itself.
* Accounting and regulatory capital practices that allow for
fictitious model-based valuations that have no relationship with actual
market prices.
* Accounting standards that allow bankers to record unrealized fake
profits using mark-to-market and mark-to-model valuations and by
front-loading hoped-for future profits into recorded current profits.
* Compensation practices that allow these fake profits to be
distributed as bonuses that cannot later be recovered if valuations were
wrong or hoped-for future profits failed to materialize.
Also helpful in this game are two other factors: ratings agencies
that are just as conflicted as the banks and use the same dodgy models
to assign AAA ratings and hence give apparent respectability to dubious
financial structures and, of course, highly gameable Basel regulatory
capital rules.
The resulting "dark side" financing then enables bankers
to (1) convert almost any toxic rubbish into AAA rated securities (think
subprime and the Gaussian copula, then endlessly recycle such assets
through one CDO securitization 'after another in an alchemical
process that seems to convert more and more lead into gold, but
doesn't); (2) pass risks to counterparties who don't
understand the risks they are taking on (think dozy German Landesbanken
or Norwegian pension funds pre-2007) or insure them with counterparties
that specialize in the business and then fail when all the chickens come
home to roost at the same time (think AIG); (3) transform expectations
of future profits, however unrealistic, into current recorded profits;
(4) run rings around the regulatory system without the latter noticing;
(5) bribe shareholders with high dividends, not to mention buy off
politicians, and run off with the rest of the proceeds--that is, extract
the maximum possible rents not only from the financial system but,
thanks to government guarantees, from the rest of the economy as well.
These activities reached a fever pitch by the eve of the crisis, by
which time banks' profitability appeared to be at an all-time high
and, by Basel standards, the banks were more than adequately
capitalized. The banking system then collapsed like a straw hut in the
wind when market conditions turned down.
Yet to many insiders, it was obvious for some time before the
crisis that the system was heading for collapse. To cut to the chase, if
banker compensation is linked to accounting profit, and if accounting
rules enable bankers to legitimately account for vast amounts of the
cash under their stewardship as profits, then collapse is inevitable.
The only puzzle is why it took so long.
Unfortunately, these practices are still continuing and the
regulatory response to the crisis is encouraging even more. A case in
point is the post-Lehman changes to accounting rules designed to
restrict securitization, which--though few observers have yet realized
it--have backfired spectacularly by giving rise to a slew of new
securitization practices involving innovative collateralized borrowing.
This has been manna from heaven for those banks that cannot raise
unsecured interbank finance, which are typically insolvent and which by
rights should be out of business already.
To give but one example, the "failed sale" arrangement,
This is a repo-like transaction designed to secure finance by granting
counterparties hidden hypothecations of prime bank assets. (6) The deal
is classified as a repo (an innocent transaction), but since all banks
have substantial repo activity going on as normal derivative and hedging
activity, the failed sale deals are very hard to spot individually. With
a failed sale arrangement, the collateral pledged is typically of prime
quality, the poorer quality having already been pledged to central banks
in realm for their funding. (7) This type of transaction is damaging in
at least two ways:
* It deceives other bank counterparties, who do not appreciate that
they cannot recover the prime assets in question even though they still
remain on the bank's balance sheet. A failed sale transaction is
thus essentially fraudulent. Should the bank then fail, creditors
(including taxpayers via deposit insurance and other state guarantees)
would lose almost everything when they found that they had taken
possession of little more than an empty shell.
* The fact that these practices are known to be going on means that
banks' balance sheets cannot be trusted. They could therefore have
been tailor-made to destroy confidence and ensure that the next round of
the crisis will be highly contagious.
Failed sale transactions are now rising strongly while unsecured
interbank lending is disappearing. This is ample indication of the
market's own knowledge as to the insolvency of the banking system.
A related growth industry is in gaming the bailout process itself.
These include banks cooking their books to secure bailouts--which was a
notable feature of the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP)--recycling
their worst assets into securities that can then be sold or repo'd
to the local central bank and manipulating "quantitative
easing" (QE) auctions. After all, from the bankers'
perspective, the bailout process itself is just another opportunity to
make profits.
It follows from all this that another crash is inevitable. The
parlous state of the U.S. banking system is confirmed by Warren
Buffett's recent (August 25, 2011) $5 billion investment in Bank of
America. This deal was widely touted as a "vote of confidence"
by commentators anxious for good news, and Buffett himself portrayed it
in a CNBC interview the same day as a vote of confidence in both the
bank and in the country. It is, in fact, nothing of the sort. Instead,
it is a lender of last resort operation to a desperate TBTF bank from
which he can expect to earn an extraordinary and almost guaranteed
coupon return of 15 percent in an almost zero interest rate environment,
confident in the knowledge that his investment is underwritten by the
prospect of a future government bailout (see Kerr 2011a). If this is
good news, then the United States is in a truly dire state.
It is no wonder that Bank of England Governor Mervyn King was able
to announce a year ago that of all the banking systems it is possible to
have, our present system is surely the worst.
The Response to the Crisis
Once the crisis started, the best response would have been to
liquidate weak institutions. Such a cleansing out should have been
followed by monetary reform (i.e., at a minimum, higher interest rates
and a commitment to hard money) and financial reform (i.e., at a
minimum, the abolition of federal deposit insurance and state
guarantees, and the imposition of extended personal liability for key
decision makers) to address the underlying causes, combined with major
fiscal retrenchment to put public finances in order. These actions would
have restored sound governance structures and reigned in excess
risk-taking.
Instead, the actual policy response was much the opposite: the
authorities did everything possible to stimulate the economy and put off
any unpleasant restructuring. The Fed funds interest rate was pushed
down from 5.26 percent in July 2007 to almost zero in December 2008, a
rate it has since maintained and recently reinforced by a commitment to
keep it there until at least mid-2013. At the same time, the Fed engaged
in massive purchases of bank assets financed by printing money (with the
monetary base growing from around $800 billion before the crisis to
nearly $2.7 trillion, an unprecedented rise of about 330 percent) and
assorted other support to the financial system (e.g., TBTF bailouts, and
qualitative easing), while the government responded with massive fiscal
stimulus and a string of bailouts of its own.
These measures further distorted asset prices, boosting existing
bubbles in U.S. Treasuries, financial stocks, and the stock market
generally, and creating additional ones in commodities and junk. They
amounted to a huge increase in state intervention in the economy and
prevented the financial system and the broader economy from correcting
themselves. They aggravated the underlying moral hazards that were a
major proximate cause of the crisis. They undermined accountability and
generated massive transfers to those responsible for the crisis (who had
already greatly enriched themselves in creating it) at the expense of
everyone else. Even worse was the response of the political
establishment, repeatedly bailing them out with taxpayer cash, with
further bailouts likely to follow. This goes beyond mere cronyism and
amounts to a takeover by the "banksters" of the political
system itself. The situation in most of Europe is much the same, and in
some countries worse.
The Role of the Federal Reserve
The Fed's policies continue to be dominated by confusion
between causes and solutions, a refusal to face up to structural
problems in the economy, and an obsession with spending and stimulus.
Chairman Bernanke repeatedly maintains that pushing down interest rates
is good for the economy because it encourages investment and boosts
asset prices, which increases confidence, encourages greater spending,
and leads to further economic expansion. He also repeatedly calls for
measures to support the housing market and reduce high unemployment and
endlessly warns of the dangers of deflation.
We would take issue with him on every point:
* Lower interest rates were responsible for one boom-bust cycle
after another since the late 1990s, and each time the Fed's
response to the bust has been to lower interest rates again and create
an even bigger bubble next time around: the Fed seems unable to learn
from its own repeated mistakes.
* Further, continuing for year after year to provide a negative
real risk-free rate of return on savings inevitably reduces saving and
in the long run decapitalizes the economy. We would argue that in the
U.S. decapitalization has now reached an advanced stage, thus ensuring
persistently high unemployment and declining living standards from here
on in.
* Greater spending and borrowing are also not much good if the
spending is on the wrong things--more housing springs to mind--and
excessive.
* As for more "confidence" and "economic
expansion," true confidence needs to be grounded in strong economic
fundamentals and a predictable environment--wild policy swings and vast
amounts of policymaker discretion don't really help much here--and
expansion needs to be in the right areas and sustainable.
* As for unemployment, we agree that this is a real problem, so why
is the Fed creating unemployment with low interest rate policies that
encourage the replacement of labor by capital and the migration of U.S.
jobs overseas?
* Then there is the deflation issue, so why is the Fed, which
claims to support price stability, utterly averse to prices falling but
cavalier about them rising, and where was the evidence that deflation
ever posed a serious danger anyway? Admittedly, there would have been
sharp falls in prices in the early part of the downturn--as in 1921--but
this is part of the natural economic correction process.
In any case, there is the deeper question of why is the Fed trying
to bring about any particular outcomes at all? Issues of prices and
resource allocation should be determined by markets, not by some central
agency: this is the whole point of a market system.
There is also the Fed's own self-interest. Fed chairmen have
an obvious personal interest in getting good headlines, and lower
interest rates are more popular than higher ones--just compare the
opprobrium experienced by Paul Volcker after he hiked interest rates in
late 1979 and 1980 with the glowing approval that followed Alan
Greenspan each time he brought interest rates down. The Fed also has its
own interests in institutional empire-building, avoiding accountability
(8) and exculpating itself when things go wrong, and exploiting crises
to its advantage. Again and again, it has used economic
emergencies--which it has itself helped create--to expand its powers and
responsibilities, which have as a consequence grown enormously since its
inception. This happened most notably in the early 1930s, in the early
1980s (e.g., the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary
Control Act of 1980) and recently (e.g., huge expansion of its balance
sheet and Dodd-Frank). Commenting on the discussions that surrounded the
reforms of the early 1980s, Richard Timberlake (1985: 101) observed:
Fed officials in their testimony to congressional committees
persistently and doggedly advanced one major theme: the
Fed had to have more power--to fight inflation, to prevent
chaos in the financial industry from deregulation, and to act
as an insurance institution for failing banks who might drag
other institutions down with them. By misdirection and subterfuge,
the Fed inveigled an unwary Congress into doing its
bidding.
"The Fed must have more power" was also its major
persistent theme throughout the current financial crisis, and very
effective it was too. Recent events have only reinforced the conclusions
Timberlake (1986: 759) reached a generation ago:
Its [then] 70-year [now almost 100-year] history as a bureaucratic
institution confirms the inability of Congress to bring
it to heel. Whenever its own powers are at stake, the Fed
exercises an intellectual ascendancy that consistently results
in an extension of Fed authority. This pattern reflects the
dominance of bureaucratic expertise for which there is no
solution as long as the [Fed] continues to exist.
One must also take account of the fact that the primary practical
task of any central bank is to protect the financial interest of its
principal client, the government. The government and the Fed have a
close working relationship, and the government has a major say in the
appointment of senior Fed officials and over the legislative environment
in which the Fed operates. Since the government's own interest is
in low borrowing costs and access to debt finance, this gives the Fed
another incentive to lower interest rates. It also makes the Fed the
government's lender of last resort; moreover, it means that if push
ever comes to shove, the Fed will always put its obligation to keep the
government financed above any other consideration.
The Federal Reserve even distorts discussion of the issues
involved, and does so in at least three quite different ways:
* It exploits its advantages of greater research resources and
greater technical knowledge, not to mention its ability to wheel out an
established "party line" that gives it the edge over most
critics in Congress and the press. It also feeds journalists with own
its self-serving spin, throwing bones to those who are sympathetic and
freezing critics out. Indeed, Milton Friedman said a long time ago that
one of the reasons why the Fed received the good press it did is because
it is the source of 98 percent of all that is written about it (Tullock
1975: 39-40).
* It distorts monetary research: a recent study by Lawrence H.
White (2007) suggests that the Fed encourages research favorable to its
interests. It tends to "push" certain research areas and
employs and promotes economists with agreeable views, and discourages
and even censors critical work. (9) Anyone who enters the field soon
learns that criticizing the Fed is unlikely to be career-enhancing and
most steer their writing accordingly. White also reports an apparent
bias towards pro-discretion articles with very few Fed-published
articles arguing for rules: there are almost no favorable published
comments about the gold standard; not a single article calling for the
elimination, privatization, or even restructuring of the Fed; and only
one article (Dowd 1993) that even mentions laissez-faire banking (White
2007: 344).
* It invents new justifications for its expanding role. Traditional
central banking was highly conservative, but as its remit has expanded,
the Fed and its foreign counterparts took on a larger and increasingly
activist role, especially post-2007, rewriting the central bank textbook
as it went along with specious arguments to justify its new policy
tools. These included arguments for a zero-interest rate policy, QE, an
expanded lender of last resort function, (10) and macro-prudential
regulation. (11)
We have reached the point where the U.S. central bank has amassed
so much unaccountable discretionary power that its unelected chairman
now has more influence over the economy than the president himself.
Such hegemonic institutions have no place in a free society or a
free market. Many of the Founding Fathers understood this too. That is
why the Constitution did not give the federal government authority to
charter a national bank.
The Fiscal Context
The government's fiscal response to the crisis was also
extreme: it threw all caution to the wind and embarked on a raft of huge
deficit spending programs. In the process, the federal deficit rose from
under 2 percent of GDP before the crisis to over 10 percent now, with
the deficit itself currently running at $1.3 trillion a year; and
government official gross debt levels rose from 64 percent of GDP to
over 93 percent. Such spending is unprecedented in a period in which the
United States is not engaged in a civil or world war. Even in the 1930s,
the federal deficit only peaked at 5 percent of GDP and government debt
in 1940 was only about 50 percent of GDP. The result of this spending
orgy is that U.S. debt is approaching danger levels; this would seem be
confirmed by its recent credit downgrades. (12) A rise in interest rates
or further downgrades could then trigger a major financing and even
solvency crisis as U.S. debt spirals out of control.
And what did all this stimulus achieve? The answer would appear to
be a big stimulus to the government sector and a big crowding out of the
private sector. Net private sector domestic investment fell sharply and
is still under half its 2007 levels, U6 unemployment rose from 7.9
percent from its low point in May 2007 to about 20 percent now, and real
GDP is still below its 2007 levels. Or to put it another way, the
biggest stimulus in history failed to stimulate.
We also have to take account of the longer-term fiscal context. The
official U.S. debt, high as it is, is merely the tip of a much bigger
iceberg: we must also consider the unfunded obligations of the U.S.
government--those future obligations it has entered into but not
provided for. Shortly before the crisis, Lawrence Kotlikoff estimated
these to be a little under $100 trillion, and his most recent estimates
put these at $211 trillion--more than doubling over five years
(Kotlikoff 2011). To put this latter figure into perspective, it is 15
times the official debt, 14 times U.S. GDP, and a debt of $580,000 for
every man, woman, and child in the country--and rising fast.
The Road to Economic Armageddon
To sum up, state meddling in the U.S. economy has gotten the
country to the surreal situation where the banking system is insolvent
and kept going only because it is being propped up the Federal Reserve
and the federal government, but the Fed is also insolvent and kept going
only because it is being propped up by the government, and the
government is itself insolvent. (13) Thus, the whole system is insolvent
and no insolvent system can last indefinitely. Collapse of the system is
inevitable.
The Fed now finds itself in a dilemma of its own making and has
effectively checkmated itself. On the one hand, the Fed can do the
responsible thing from a monetary policy perspective and raise interest
rates to bring inflation under control. However, a rise in interest
rates would bring the whole house of cards down: it would expose all the
unsafe financings of recent years--these would be left high and dry and
quickly fail; it would burst all the bubbles currently in full swing,
inflict huge losses on investors, (14) and trigger a wave of
bankruptcies, especially among financial institutions; and it would set
off an immediate financing crisis for governments at all levels and lead
to a wave of municipal, state, and possibly federal government defaults.
It is, therefore, truly no exaggeration to say that the financial
system, many nonfinancial firms, the Fed, and the government are all now
addicted to cheap money and unable to function without it.
On the other hand, if the Fed persists along its declared path, the
prognosis is accelerating inflation leading ultimately to hyperinflation
and economic meltdown. The United States has already passed the earlier
stages of this process. The first stage involved the central bank
expanding the monetary base and indicating that further expansions are
likely to follow. This sets the central bank firmly on the path to debt
monetization (i.e., printing money to buy debt, in this case not just
government debt but the bad assets of the banking system as well). The
expanding monetary base then feeds through to increasing growth rates of
the broader monetary aggregates. By this point, real interest rates are
in deep negative territory and set to go south, and the public are
visibly losing confidence in inconvertible paper currency.
The next, critical, stage along this path was passed when the Fed
committed itself to hold interest rates down at current levels until at
least well into 2013, followed shortly after by the announcement of
"Operation Twist" to buy up long-dated Treasuries in order to
push long-term rates down. The former reassures bond investors that they
should not fear capital losses in the near future, and the latter
encourages buyers by indicating that long-term bond prices will rise in
the near future. These measures further puff up the already grossly
inflated bond market bubble, but merely buy a little more time at the
cost of making underlying problems even worse. By this point, the only
weapon left in the Fed's armory short of outright monetization is
more of the same the logical extreme being to commit itself to zero
interest rates indefinitely and push the whole Treasury yield curve down
to zero--to encourage investors and prop up the market for as long as
possible (i.e., for the Fed to give the bubble the maximum puff it can).
But whether the Fed gives the bubble one last big puff or not, it is
only a matter of time before the bubble does what bubbles always do: it
will burst.
We therefore have a bond market that is unsustainable and a Fed
that has no exit strategy to safely deflate it. Sooner or later,
investors will refuse to lend to the government for a zero or near zero
return, especially with rising inflation eroding more and more of the
real value of their holdings, and will then want out. More poignantly,
the Fed's zero interest rate policy has created a one-way-bet
scenario reminiscent of a beleaguered currency facing a speculative
attack. At some point, investors will realize that bond prices can
realistically only go down and that the only rational course of action
is to sell and, if nothing else, switch into cash or near-cash
positions. They will then stampede for the exits.
The Fed and the government are defenseless against this prospect,
and once the bond market stirs, its revenge will be most unpleasant. The
last time the bond market was seriously roused, in 1994, interest rates
doubled and the fiscally much sounder Clinton administration received a
severe kicking. Given the much greater scale and higher prices involved,
a collapse in the T-bond market would make the mid-1990s look like a
picnic. Interest rates would then rise sharply and trigger the collapse
of the financial system and of much else besides.
The only way that the Fed could prevent this happening and prop up
the bond market is by resorting to its nuclear option, a desperate
remedy that is worse than the disease, but one that we fear policymakers
would be too weak to resist: it would have to buy up all the federal
debt that investors wish to dump or not take up at current prices (i.e.,
presumably, all of it, once the panic gets going). The Fed would then
soon find itself monetizing the whole of the federal debt, currently
some $14 trillion plus change. This would involve a rapid expansion of
the existing (already overexpanded) monetary base of over $2.7 trillion
to, say, $17 trillion, an expansion of over 600 percent.
Inflation would then rise very sharply and remaining confidence in
the dollar would soon collapse. (15) Foreign holders of both U.S.
dollars and dollar-denominated assets would dump them fast; the huge
overseas holdings of dollars (about $12 trillion) would be repatriated
to add further fuel to the fire; and the dollar would collapse on the
foreign markets--or at least against those foreign currencies that were
not collapsing themselves by then. There would also be a flight from the
dollar within the United States itself as Americans switch to other
means of payment such as foreign currencies and physical assets
including barter. Inflation would then escalate uncontrollably into
hyperinflation and the Fed would soon find itself printing money to
finance not just the government's debt, but even its current
expenditures as rapidly rising inflation destroyed the efficacy of the
government's tax collection apparatus. In the process, much of the
economic infrastructure--the payments system, the provision of credit,
the financial system itself--would disintegrate, and of course the
economy would collapse.
This outcome can be avoided by only a reversal to tight money, and
one naturally thinks of the Volcker disinflation. However, we have
already explained that this would trigger an almighty financial crisis.
The fragility of the system now is far worse than it was then, and the
political will to address the problem nonexistent (see Schlichter 2011:
234-35).
Eventually, a new monetary system would emerge based on a new
currency--most likely a reformed dollar pegged to a hard monetary asset,
most likely gold--and the inflation will at last end.
A New Monetary System
Restore the Gold Standard and End the Fed
A gold standard would impose a much needed discipline on the issue
of currency and on attempts to manipulate interest rates. A gold
standard is not without its flaws, but is vastly better than the
unmanageable fiat system that replaced it. The gold standard has a very
creditable historical track record in delivering longer-term price
stability, and the ultimate endorsement, to our way of thinking, is that
it is anathema to monetary interventionists. The two criticisms usually
made of it are that it did not deliver particularly good short-term
price stability and that it was prone to periods of deflation. Our
response would be that the longer-term price-level it did deliver is
much more important, and that fears of the damaging effects of deflation
are much exaggerated that is, the deflation "problem" is
largely a bugaboo fed by misinterpretations of the 1930s and the earlier
depression that lasted from the 1870s to the mid-1890s.
We would also suggest that the new monetary system needs to be a
fully automated one that manages itself, and this requires putting an
end to the Fed. There would then be no U.S. central bank to undermine
the new gold standard by meddling with it, and the gold market itself
would be completely free.
There is however the difficult question of whether a gold standard
should be adopted unilaterally or collectively. Most likely, as after
Britain's return to the gold standard in 1819 under the great Lord
Liverpool, the adoption of a gold standard by the United States would in
due course lead to its trading partners joining it as they came to
appreciate it benefits, leading in time to a new international gold
standard. However, given the exchange rate disruption that would occur
if the United States adopted a gold standard but its major trading
partners did not, the best way forward would be for the United States to
convene an international conference with a view to restoring an
international gold standard involving all major trading countries. Such
a proposal will inevitably bring to mind the previous such
conference--the Bretton Woods conference in 1944--which laid the
foundations of the eponymous international monetary system that lasted
until the early 1970s. However, the Bretton Woods system was a
(mis)managed system that was a gold standard in name only, with other
currencies tied to the dollar and the dollar to gold; a heavily
regulated gold market; widespread exchange controls; and the
establishment of two international financial agencies, the International
Monetary Fund and the World Bank, whose mandate was to meddle.
By contrast, we are recommending a bona fide gold standard, a free
gold market, no central banks, no exchange controls, and the abolition
of both the IMF and the World Bank, neither of which has any place in a
free market. The role model of this new system is not the failed Bretton
Woods system, which failed precisely because it was a managed system,
but the early free-banking gold standards, such as those of early 19th
century Scotland or Canada a little later, which were effective
precisely because they were close to being free of damaging intervention
by the state and its agencies.
The gold standard not only has a large (and growing) body of
support, but may be inevitable anyway. Indeed, there are numerous
indications that a gold standard is already spontaneously re-emerging.
Banks such as Austria's Raiffesen Zentralbank now offer clients
gold-based accounts and others are offering gold ATM machines. The
obvious next steps are private gold coinage and gold-based electronic
payments media. On the wholesale side, the SWIFT international payments
system now allows payments in gold. The next stage would be gold
invoicing, leading to the development of gold money markets and gold
bond markets reminiscent of the development of the eurodollar markets
half a century ago.
Within the United States, Utah has already passed a law to repeal
its capital gains tax on gold and silver coins, which it will recognize
as legal tender; 12 other states are considering similar laws; and there
is currently before Congress a proposal for a Sound Money Promotion Act
sponsored by Senators Jim DeMint (R-SC), Mike Lee (R-UT), and Rand Paul
(R-KY) that would remove the federal capital gains tax from gold and
silver monetary transactions. In Switzerland, there are moves to
establish a gold Swiss franc and allow free gold coinage. Within the
Islamic world, Indonesia has already reestablished a gold dinar, and in
Malaysia, the states of Kelantan and Perak have reestablished both the
gold dinar and the silver dirhem. And in Zimbabwe, still smarting from
its experience of hyperinflation, the central bank has recently proposed
a gold-backed Zim dollar.
Fixing the Financial System
Also needed are reforms to put the financial system on a sound
long-term basis, and three in particular stand out:
* Reforms to restore effective corporate governance in financial
institutions. At a minimum, these should involve extended liability for
shareholders and extended personal liability for key decisionmakers. The
ideal, however, would be to roll back the limited liability privilege in
banking. Such reforms would rein in most of the currently out-of-control
moral hazards that exist within financial institutions and so restore
tight governance mechanisms and effective risk management.
* The abolition of federal deposit insurance, capital adequacy
regulations, and interventionist agencies such as the Securities and
Exchange Commission. These reforms would establish a free market in
financial services and incentivize financial institutions to maintain
their own financial health, which would rein in moral hazards within the
financial system, encouraging banks to lend conservatively, maintain
high levels of capital, and protect their own liquidity.
* Reformed accounting standards. The United States needs reliable
accounting standards that are principles-based, not the current plethora
of thousands of pages of rules of current U.S. GAAP. The new standards
need to ensure that any reported profits are true realized profits, not
fake profits generated by highly gameable mark-to-model valuations
disconnected from market prices. A good role model here would be UK GAAP
before the UK unwisely adopted IFRS accounting standards in 2006.
A New Constitutional Settlement
Going well beyond such measures is the need for a new
constitutional settlement that reflects the lessons to be learned, of
which the key lesson is simply that governments and money don't
mix. Central to this is therefore the need for a total separation of the
state and the monetary and financial systems. This can be achieved only
by a "free money" constitutional amendment. To quote Henry
Holzer (1981: 202), writing at the height of the last major U.S.
inflation:
To accomplish its purposes, that amendment cannot be a
half-way measure. Either the government can possess monetary
power, or it cannot--and if it cannot, the constitutional
amendment must sweep clean. The monetary powers delegated
to Congress in the Constitution must be eliminated, and
an express prohibition must be erected against any monetary
role for government.
We would go further: this amendment should also prohibit government
bailouts, government chartered financial institutions, and government
financial guarantees of any sort, including those associated with
deposit insurance and pension schemes. This would help prevent the
future reintroduction of deposit insurance and or new intergenerational
Ponzi schemes such as government PAYGO pension schemes or unfunded
commitments like a future Medicare. We would also recommend a balanced
budget amendment to rule out future deficit finance: these reforms would
force governments to live within their current means. (16) We should
heed Thomas Jefferson's advice, "To preserve our independence,
we must not let our rulers load us with perpetual debt."
The medicine might seem strong, but the disease has almost killed
the patient--and history teaches us that anything less would leave in
place the seeds from which a new catastrophe would doubtless emerge in
the future.
As for the controversy over the state theory of money with which we
started, we can surely now regard that as settled. To put Keynes on his
head, we can say--beyond the possibility of dispute--that all civilized
money is a creature of the market and that the only serious threat it
has ever faced is that of predation by the state.
References
Buchanan, J. M.; Wagner, R. E.; and Burton, J. (1978) The Economic
Consequences of Mr. Keynes. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.
Dowd, K. (1993) "Deposit Insurance: A Skeptical View."
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 75 (1): 14-17.
Dowd, K., and Hutchinson, M. (2010) Alchemists of Loss: How Modern
Finance and Government Intervention Crashed the Financial System.
Chichester, UK: Wiley.
--(2011) U.S. Decapitalization, Easy Money, and Asset Price Cycles.
Cato Journal 31 (3): 505-19.
Dowd, K.; Hutchinson, M.; Ashby, S. G.; and Hinchliffe, J. (2011)
"Capital Inadequacies: The Dismal Failure of the Basel System of
Bank Capital Adequacy Regulation." Cato Institute Policy Analysis
No. 681 (29 July).
Greenspan, A. (1966) "'Gold and Economic Freedom."
The Objectivist. Reprinted in A. Rand, Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal.
New York: New American Library, 1967.
Hayek, F. A. (1931) Prices and Production. New York: Augustus M.
Kelly.
Holzer, H. M. (1981) Government's Money Monopoly: Its Source
and Scope, and How to Fight It. New York: Books in Focus.
Kerr, G. A. (2011a) "Buffett's $5 Billion 'Vote of
Confidence' in Bank of America." Available at
www.cobdencentre.org/2011/08/buffettbank-of-america.
--(2011b) "The Law of Opposites." London: Adam Smith
Institute.
Keynes, J. M. (1930) A Treatise on Money. London: Macmillan.
Kling, A. (2010) "The Case for Auditing the Fed Is
Obvious." Cato Institute Briefing Paper No. 118 (27 April 27).
Kotlikoff, L. (2011) Interview with National Public Radio (6
August).
Lewis, M. (2007) Gold: The Once and Future Money. Hoboken, N.J.:
Wiley:
--(2010) The Big Short: Inside the Doomsday Machine. London: Allen
Lane.
O'Driscoll, G. P. Jr. (2011) "Money, Prices, and
Bubbles." Cato Journal 31(3): 441-59.
Schlichter, D. (2011) Paper Money Collapse: The Folly of Elastic
Money and the Coming Monetary Breakdown. New York: Wiley.
Shelton, J. (1994) Money Meltdown: Restoring Order to the Global
Currency System. New York: Free Press.
Timberlake, R. H. Jr. (1985) "Legislative Construction of the
Monetary Control Act of 1980." American Economic Review 75 (2):
97-102.
--(1986) "Institutional Evolution of Federal Reserve
Hegemony." Cato Journal 5 (3): 743-63.
Tullock, G. (1975) "Discussion." In R. T. Selden (ed.)
Capitalism and Freedom: Problems and Prospects; Proceedings of a
Conference in Honor of Milton Friedman. Charlottesville: University
Press of Virginia.
White, L. H. (2007) "The Federal Reserve's Influence on
Research in Monetary Economics." Econ Journal Watch 2 (2): 355-54.
Williams, J. (2011) "Hyperinflation." Special Report No.
357 (15 March). Shadow Government Statistics.
Wilmers, R. G. (2011) "Small Banks, Big Banks, Giant
Differences." Available at www.bloomberg.com.
(1) Using official BLS CPI data. By the same measure, which
actually understates the problem, the dollar has lost 94.2 percent of
its purchasing power since Roosevelt effectively ended the gold standard
in 1934.
(2) For more on the coming fiat money collapse theme, see Shelton
(1994), Lewis (2007), Schlichter (2011), and Williams (2011).
(3) For example, capital regulations are ratings related. So how
should a bank deal with an asset portfolio that has just been
downgraded? Easy. The bank sells the assets to a special purpose vehicle
or SPV that issues two tranches of notes, where the junior piece is
sized sufficient to procure a triple-A rating for the senior tranche,
and will typically be relatively small. The bank then buys both sets of
notes and so re-establishes its AAA rating for most of its portfolio.
(4) The Fed's interest rate policy allows banks to borrow
short-term at close to zero and invest at around 3 percent in long-term
Treasuries and even more in mortgage-backed bonds, which are now openly
guaranteed by the federal government. This enables them to sit back with
3 percent spreads leveraged 15 times or so to make a comfortable 45
percent or more return. Becoming a yield curve player is far more
profitable and avoids all that tiresome bother and risk of lending to
small businesses.
(5) They did this by funneling CDS trades into CDOs which were then
sold as cash investments to investors, with as usual about the first 80
percent rated as AAA risk. The way to understand this is to look at the
cash flows on the original CDS. The investor buys protection from the
investment bank, paying regular premiums in return for a promise of a
payment of principal, should the subprime default, equal to some fixed
amount minus the value of the defaulted loans. These cash flows were
then assigned to a new SPV that issued the same fixed amount of
synthetic subprime CDO whereby the cash flows from the fund mirrored the
cash flows from actual subprime borrowers. The cash CDO investor would
then receive a coupon from the CDS premiums and be exposed to a loss of
the principal minus the value of the reference loans if the loans
defaulted.
(6) This is a repo (a standard form of collateralized loan)
accompanied by the sale of a repurchase option with the sole intent of
hiding the preferment from other bank stakeholders. The trick is that,
under the new rules, the repo'd assets never leave the borrowing
bank's balance sheet--that is, the arrangement does not qualify as
a true sale; hence, the "failed sale" label. So, from the
borrower's perspective, the bank's balance sheet is apparently
unaffected.
(7) This highlights another reason against qualitative easing
(i.e., the central bank lending against poorer-quality assets as
collateral). Had central banks insisted on the best collateral, banks
would not be able to engage in failed-sale type transactions. Thus,
qualitative easing not only leaves the central bank itself vulnerable to
losses but, by allowing failed sales, exposes other parties too--another
instance of the law of unintended consequences.
(8) For example, the Fed fought hard against efforts to audit it on
the self-serving grounds that being audited would undermine its
independence, as if the Fed's momentous decisions during the
financial crisis should be permanently beyond account or as if hiding
its mistakes would somehow serve the public interest (see Kling 2010).
(9) White (2007: 331) cites the case of one academic, whose
criticism of a policy decision 50 years earlier was censored.
(10) The classic Bagehot lender of last resort doctrine maintains
that the central bank should only engage in lender of last resort
support to a (single) distressed financial institution at a penalty rate
of interest on first-class security, and even then only if that
institution is solvent. This doctrine has now been expanded to the point
of utter subversion: modern central banks now claim the justification to
support (that is, bail out) the whole financial system, even if it is
insolvent, with credit provided at below market interest rates against
the flimsiest collateral. The central bank is no longer acting as lender
of last resort but as lender of first resort to the whole financial
system, and it is not so much "lending" to the financial
system as siphoning funds to it in the certain knowledge that it will
take on much of its toxicity and absorb major losses itself.
Bagehot's preferred "first best" solution was no lender
of last resort at all.
(11) This is the idea that regulators can frame regulations to take
account of systemic issues. However, existing proposals are little more
than hot air, and most implicitly suppose that regulators are able to
identify systemic risk problems, second-guess turning points (i.e., beat
the market), and withstand the inevitable lobbying from the industry to
relax standards as the economy booms. In any case, the documented
inability of regulators to impose even "simple" capital
standards effectively hardly inspires confidence that they will succeed
with the extra difficulties associated with macro-prudential regulation.
(12) S&P downgraded the federal government's credit rating
from AAA to AA+ in August 2011. Dagong, the Chinese rating agency,
downgraded the U.S. government's credit rating twice last year and
now gives it a rating of single A.
(13) The size of the Fed's balance sheet is now about $2.7
trillion. With capital at $71 billion, the Fed has a leverage
(assets/capital) ratio of almost 40, which is higher than that of most
banks at the onset of the crisis. Even under the safest market
conditions, this would be regarded as very improvident. The Fed's
capital/asset ratio is therefore just over 2.5 percent. Were the Fed a
regular commercial bank it would be regarded as insolvent under Basel
capital rides. Most of its assets are government bonds, and elementary
analysis shows that if interest rates rise by even a smidgeon the value
of the Fed's bonds will fall by more than 2.5 percent (i.e., the
Fed will be revealed to be insolvent). To illustrate, assume that the
bond holdings have an average duration of 5 years, then a simple
duration analysis suggests that it would take only a 0.5 percent rise in
interest rates to wipe out the Fed's capital. To make matters even
worse, 36 percent of the Fed's assets are not regular bonds at all,
but mortgage-backed securities and similar toxic assets purchased to
bail out the rest of the banking system. Many of these assets are worth
only a fraction of their book values, but remain on the Fed's
balance sheet at book values because they are guaranteed by the federal
government and its agencies, which are also kept afloat by government
guarantees. Consequently, the Fed is already insolvent, even using data
based on its own privileged and unaccountable accounting practices.
(14) To illustrate the potential losses involved just on bonds
alone, the size of the U.S. bond market is $32.2 trillion. Given an
average duration of 5 years, a 1 percent rise in interest rates would
inflict a hit of $1.6 trillion on bondholders. Moreover, this figure
ignores the banks' exposure on their share of the over $400
trillion on interest-rate derivatives, on which the banks have mostly
long positions that will also take losses when interest rates rise.
(15) A possible counterargument is that a rapid rise in inflation
could be avoided by the Fed sterilizing the increase in base money.
However, the Fed would have to sterilize almost all the extra base
money, and it is difficult to envisage how it might practically do so.
It is also difficult to imagine how such a large increase in the base,
sterilized or not, could produce anything but a collapse in remaining
confidence in the dollar.
(16) The dangers and indeed unsustainability of deficit finance
were pointed out long ago in a classic study by Buchanan, Wagner, and
Burton (1978).
Kevin Dowd is a Visiting Professor at Cass Business School, City
University, London, and a Partner with Cobden Partners, a sovereign
advisory company based in London. Martin Hutchinson is a financial
journalist and former London merchant banker. Gordon Kerr is the founder
of Cobden Partners. The authors thank David Blake and John Burton for
helpful comments.