Understanding the interventionist impulse of the modern central bank.
Lacker, Jeffrey M.
The financial crisis of 2007 and 2008 was a watershed event for the
Federal Reserve and other central banks. The extraordinary actions they
took have been described, alternatively, as a natural extension of
monetary policy to extreme circumstances or as a problematic exercise in
credit 'allocation. I have expressed my view elsewhere that much of
the Fed's response to the crisis falls in the latter category
rather than the former (Lacker 2010). Rather than reargue that case, I
want to take this opportunity to reflect on some of the institutional
reasons behind the prevailing propensity of many modern central banks to
intervene in credit markets.
The Impulse to Reallocate Credit
There is widespread agreement among economists that a vigorous
monetary policy response can be necessary at times to prevent a
contraction from becoming a deflationary spiral. Financial market
turmoil often sparks a flight to monetary assets. In the 19th and 20th
centuries, this often took the form of shifts out of deposits and into
notes and specie. Under a fractional reserve banking system, this
necessitates a deflationary contraction in the overall money supply
unless offset through clearinghouse or central bank expansion of the
note supply. In modern financial panics, banks often seek to hoard
reserve balances, which again would be contractionary absent an
accommodating increase in the central bank reserve supply. In both
cases, the need is for an increase in outstanding central bank monetary
liabilities.
The Fed's response during the financial crisis was not purely
monetary, however. In the first phase--from the fall of 2007 through the
summer of 2008--its credit actions were sterilized, lending through the
Term Auction Facility and in support of the merger of Bear Stearns and
JPMorgan Chase was offset by sales of U.S. Treasury securities from the
Fed's portfolio. (1) It wasn't until September 2008 that the
supply of excess reserves began to increase significantly. This
expansion was accomplished through the acquisition of an expanding set
of private assets--loans to banks and other financial institutions and
later mortgage-backed securities and debt issued by Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac. While some observers describe this phase of the Fed's
response as a standard monetary expansion in the face of a deflationary
threat, the Fed's own characterization often emphasized instead the
intent to provide direct assistance to dysfunctional segments of the
credit markets. Clearly, an equivalent expansion of reserve supply could
have been achieved via purchases of U.S. Treasury securities--that is,
without credit allocation. Like the Fed, the European Central Bank and
other central banks have "also pursued credit allocation in
response to the crisis.
The impulse to reallocate credit certainly reflects an earnest
desire to fix perceived credit market problems that seem within the
central bank's power to fix. My sense is that Federal Reserve
credit policy was motivated by a sincere belief that central banks have
a civic duty to alleviate significant ex post inefficiencies in credit
markets. But credit allocation can redirect resources from taxpayers to
financial market investors and, over time, can expand moral hazard and
distort the allocation of capital. This implies a difficult and
contentious cost-benefit calculation. But no matter how the net benefits
are assessed, central bank intervention in credit markets will have
distributional consequences.
The Threat to Central Bank Independence
Central bank credit allocation is therefore bound to be
controversial. Indeed, the actions taken by the Fed over the last few
years have generated a level of invective that has not been seen in a
very long time. Critics have sought to exploit the resentment of credit
market rescues for partisan political advantage. While it is easy to
deplore politically motivated attempts to influence Fed policy, we need
to recognize the extent to which some measure of antagonism is an
understandable consequence of the Fed's oval credit policy
initiatives.
The inevitable controversy surrounding central bank intervention in
credit markets is one reason many observers have long advocated keeping
central banks out of the business of credit allocation (see Goodfriend
and King 1988, Hetzel 1997, Goodfriend and Lacker 1999, Goodfriend 2001,
and Broaddus and Goodfriend 2001). Central bank lending undermines the
integrity of the fiscal appropriations process, and while U.S. fiscal
policymaking may not inspire much admiration these days, it is subject
to the cheeks and balances provided for by the Constitution. Contentious
disputes about which credit market segments receive support, and which
do not, can entangle the central bank in political conflicts that
threaten the independence of monetary policymaking.
The independence that the modern central bank has to control the
monetary policy interest rate emerged in stages following the end of
World War II. The Treasury-Fed Accord of 1951 freed the Federal Reserve
from the wartime obligation to depress the Treasury's borrowing
costs. The collapse of the gold standard in the early 1970s and the
attendant bouts of inflation led the Fed in 1979 to assert
responsibility for low inflation as a long-term objective of monetary
policy (Broaddus and Goodfriend 2001: 8). The independent commitment of
central banks to low inflation provides a nominal anchor to substitute
for the anchor formerly provided by the gold standard.
The substantial measure of independence central banks have been
given was a key element in their relative success at sustaining low
inflation over the last few decades. In fact, many countries have
adopted frameworks that hold their central banks accountable for a price
stability goal, while allowing them to set interest rate policy
independently in pursuit of their goals. This instrument independence
has been critical to insulating monetary policymaking from
election-related political pressures that can detract from longer-term
objectives.
The cornerstone of central bank independence is the ability to
control the amount of the monetary liabilities it supplies to the
public. But as a by-product, many central banks retain the ability to
independently control the composition of their assets as well. For many
modern central banks, standard policy in normal times is to restrict
asset holdings to their own country's government debt. Some hold
gold as well, a vestige of the gold standard. In addition, many make
short-term loans to banks, either to meet temporary liquidity needs or
as part of clearing and settlement operations, both vestiges of the
origin of central banks as nationalized clearinghouses.
The ability of a central bank to intervene in credit markets using
the asset side of its balance sheet creates an inevitable tension. The
desire of the executive and legislative branches to provide governmental
assistance to particular credit market participants can rise
dramatically in times of financial market stress. At such times, the
power of a central bank to do fiscal policy essentially outside the
safeguards of the constitutional process for appropriations makes it an
inviting target for other government officials. Central bank lending is
often the path of least resistance in a financial crisis. The resulting
political entanglements, though, as we have seen, create risks for the
independence of monetary policy.
A Time Consistency Problem
At the heart of this tension is a classic time consistency problem.
Central bank rescues serve the short-term goal of protecting investors
from the pain of unanticipated credit market losses, but they dilute
market discipline and distort future risk-taking incentives. Over time,
small "one-off' interventions set precedents that encourage
greater risk-taking and thus increase the odds of future distress.
Policymakers then feel boxed in and obligated to intervene in ever
larger ways, perpetuating a vicious cycle of government safety net
expansion.
The conundrum lacing central banks, then, is that the balance sheet
independence that proved crucial in the fight to tame inflation is
itself a handicap in the pursuit of financial market stability. The
latitude the typical central bank has to intervene in credit markets
weakens its ability to discourage expectations of future rescues and by
doing so enhance market discipline.
Containing the Interventionist Impulse
Solving this conundrum and containing the impulse to intervene
requires one of two approaches. A central bank could seek to build and
maintain a reputation for not intervening, in much the way the Fed and
other central banks established credibility for a commitment to low
inflation in the 1980s. Alternatively, explicit legislative measures
could constrain central bank lending. The Dodd-Frank Act took steps in
this direction by banning Federal Reserve loans to individual nonbank
entities. But Reserve banks retain the power to lend to individual
depository institutions and to intervene in particular credit market
segments in "unusual and exigent circumstances" through credit
programs with "broad-based eligibility." (2) In addition, the
Fed can channel credit by purchasing the obligations of
government-sponsored enterprises, such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mae.
Constraining central bank lending powers would appear to conflict
with the popular perception that serving as a "lender of last
resort" is intrinsic to central banking. But even here, I think our
historical doctrines and practices should not escape reconsideration.
The notion of the central bank as a lender of last resort derives from
an era of commodity money standard, when central bank lending in a
crisis was the most effective way to expand currency supply to meet a
sudden increase in demand. Indeed, the preamble to the Federal Reserve
Act says its purpose is "to furnish an elastic
currency,'" not to furnish an elastic supply of credit. The
Fed could easily manage the supply of monetary assets through purchases
and sales of U.S. Treasury securities only. (3) While it might sound
extreme, I believe that a regime in which the Federal Reserve is
restricted to hold only U.S. Treasury securities purchased on the open
market is worthy of consideration (see Goodfriend and King 1988,
Schwartz 1999, Goodfriend 2001, and Broaddus and Goodfriend 2001).
It might seem easy to criticize such a regime by reference to what
it would have prevented the Fed from doing in the recent crisis. But
that's the wrong frame of reference, I believe--it's an ex
post, rather than an ex ante, perspective. Such a regime, if credible,
would over time force changes in market practices that would 'alter
the likelihood and magnitude of crises and the behavior of private
market arrangements during a crisis. It would strengthen market
discipline and incentivize institutions to operate with more capital and
less short-term debt funding-changes we are now trying to achieve
through regulatory means. The relative costs and benefits of such a
regime may be difficult to map out conclusively. But I believe this
tradeoff is well worth studying.
Conclusion
My former colleagues M Broaddus and Marvin Goodfriend (2001: 6)
have argued that the design of central bank asset policy is "part
of the unfinished business of building a modern, independent Federal
Reserve." The 1951 Treasury-Fed Accord gave the Fed independent
control of its liabilities, a necessary ingredient in monetary policy
independence. But the accompanying power to use the Fed's asset
portfolio to intervene in credit markets is a threat to that
independence and a threat to financial stability. Sorting out the
conundrum of central bank asset policy should be high on the agenda for
all those interested in improving the practice of central banking.
References
Broaddus, J. A. Jr., and Goodfriend, M. (2001) "What Assets
Should the Federal Reserve Buy.>,' Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Quarterly 87(1): 7-22.
Goodfriend, M. (2001) "Why We Need an 'Accord' for
Federal Reserve Credit Policy: A Note." Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Quarterly 87 (1): 23-32.
Goodfriend, M., and King, R. G. (1988) "Financial
Deregulation, Monetary Policy, and Central Banking." Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 74 (3): 3-12.
Goodfriend, M., and Lacker, J. M. (1999) "Limited Commitment
and Central Bank Lending." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 85 (4): 1-27.
Hetzel, R. L. (1997) "The Case for a Monetary Rule in a
Constitutional Democracy." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 83 (2): 45-65.
Lacker, J. M. (2010) "The Regulatory Response to the Crisis:
An Early Assessment." Speech at the Institute for International
Economic Policy and the International Monetary Fund Institute,
Washington, D.C. (May 26).
Schwartz, A. J. (1992) "The Misuse of the Fed's Discount
Window." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Review 74 (5):
58-69.
(1) Such sterilized actions are equivalent to issuing new U.S.
Treasury debt to the public and using the proceeds to fund the lending.
(2) Such programs now require the approval of the Secretary of the
Treasury.
(3) The market supply of such securities is likely to be quite
ample for some time to come. But even if the supply should shrink, as it
did a decade ago, the Treasury could arrange to issue in sufficient
quantities to allow the Fed to conduct monetary policy on a
Treasuries-only basis. See Broaddus and Goodfriend (9001).
Jeffrey M. Lacker is President of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond. He presented these remarks at the Cato Institute's 29th
Annual Monetary Conference hi Washington, D.C., November 16, 2011. The
views expressed herein are the author's and are not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System. He thanks John Weinberg for his
assistance.