Honest money.
Jordan, Jerry L.
This article addresses some of the recent proposals for the conduct
of monetary policies in the post-bubble environment. Advocacy of higher
inflation targets is analyzed, and the challenge of maintaining monetary
discipline in the face of massive fiscal deficits and mounting
government debts is presented. Proposals for reforms of monetary
arrangements must be based on consensus regarding the objectives of such
reforms. The article concludes with some suggestions for near- and
intermediate-term changes to present arrangements, as well as ideas for
longer-term reforms.
The Psychology of Money
For several years now I have been seeking to change the
conversation we have about money--not to something new, but to something
old. John Stuart Mill ([1848] 1987: 488) wrote,
There cannot ... be intrinsically a more insignificant thing,
in the economy of society, than money; except in the character
of a contrivance for sparing time and labour. It is a
machine for doing quickly and commodiously, what would
be done, though less quickly and commodiously, without it:
and like many other kinds of machinery, it only exerts a
distinct and independent influence of its own when it gets
out of order.
I welcome very much James Buchanan's recent remarks that
"members of the public, all of whom are transactors in money
values, must come to trust the value of money as iconically sacrosanct.
The whole psychology of money in modern times must become
different" (Buchanan 2010: 257-58).
As we continue to debate the issue of asset bubbles mad monetary
policy, we should keep in mind the importance of honest money and
"not waste this set of crises by exclusive recourse to jerry-built
efforts to patch up the failed monetary anarchy we have witnessed"
(Buchanan 2010: 288).
Unfortunately, in my view, too much of the conversation about
monetary policy has been about the strategies and tactics for the
formulation and implementation of discretionary monetary policy, and not
near enough on reforms of monetary arrangements that might assure a
constant monetary yardstick. To be fruitful, a dialogue about possible
reforms must be preceded by development of a consensus about the
objectives of constitutional monetary arrangements.
I will first comment on some of the proposals for conducting
discretionary monetary policy, and then turn to my views on what should
be the objectives of monetary reform and how we might realize those
objectives.
Misguided Policy Prescriptions
In the wake of the 2008-09 financial crisis, there have been
numerous proposals for enhancing the effectiveness of monetary and
fiscal policies. Most of these proposals have dealt with reducing the
"pain of hangovers." They prescribe greater policy activism
and, thus, even more discretion for policymakers to address the
aftermath of bursting bubbles. This approach is in sharp contrast to F.
A. Hayek's idea that the best way to avoid the pain of recession is
to prevent monetary distortions in the first place.
The most dangerous suggestion with regard to monetary policy is
that central banks should target higher inflation by allowing prices to
rise, on average, by more than the conventionally accepted 2 percent.
Inflation "doves" acknowledge that debasing the currency is a
form of taxation, yet they defend higher inflation by saying that it is
no worse than other forms of taxation.
Economists who advocate inflation--as a way out of
recession--assume that monetary policy works solely, or at least
primarily, through interest rates, and they fret about the "zero
boundary problem." The argument is that since nominal interest
rates can't go below zero, the Federal Reserve should target
inflation at more than 2 percent to ensure that nominal rates include an
inflationary premium and are at a level that would allow the Fed to cut
rates when necessary.
The central idea is that if aggregate nominal demand for output
declines for any reason, a judicious reduction of interest rates by
monetary authorities will spur consumers and businesses to spend more,
thus sowing the seeds of recovery. The claim is that if the crisis is
severe it takes larger cuts in interest rates to reverse the contraction
in aggregate demand, so higher interest rates to begin with the result
of higher inflation--give the policymakers a bigger weapon.
In the case of the Great Recession of 2008-09, this policy
prescription is misguided; it is the result of a faulty diagnosis. The
error stems from having concluded that the trigger for the crisis was a
contraction in the financial sector--credit availability shrank, so
household and business demand for output fell. Policy activists want
more powerful monetary and fiscal tools to address such conditions.
That diagnosis fails to consider that what has been characterized
as a "housing bubble" was not sufficient to cause the economic
damage we have seen. Neither the dot-com bubble of the 1990s nor the
rapid increases of house prices in Canada or other countries were
followed by widespread declines in output and employment as well as
banking failures. The key to the differences is what was happening on
the other side of the balance sheet. Asset price increases need not be
accompanied by debt increases, but when they are then the subsequent
declines in asset prices have much broader implications.
Some 20 years ago, mortgage equity withdrawals (MEWs) during
refinancing had been only 1 to 2 percent of personal disposable income.
However, by the 2004-06 period MEWs reached 9 percent of disposable
income, which was enough to drive consumption spending in the national
economy from about 65 percent of GDP to 70 percent. That increase in a
$14 trillion economy fueled an extraordinary boom in auto sales,
furnishings, appliances, consumer imports of all kinds, as well as
remittances to other countries.
Between 2001 and 2007, Americans extracted several trillion dollars
from the equity of their homes during refinancing. For far too many
families, the expression, "my home is my ATM" had real
meaning. Current consumption spending was being financed by debt. Then,
quite suddenly, in the summer of 2008, it was no longer possible to
refinance, house prices plunged, and there was no more equity to
withdraw.
What followed were misguided policies of government to maintain the
bubble-level of household consumption spending through transfer
payments--distribution of the proceeds from the issuance of massive
amounts of new government debt. New borrowing by government replaced
borrowing by households, total national debt continued to grow while
household balance sheets shrank, Fiscal policy actions became part of
the problem, not the solution, and monetary policies cannot correct the
mistakes of the rest of government.
Instead of greater latitude for discretion in the use of monetary
and fiscal policies for "pump-priming" nominal demand, we
would have been better off to allow real estate and other asset prices
to adjust to the underlying supply and demand conditions without the
issuance of massive new claims on future taxpayers. The inherent
resiliency of a market economy would then have begun to restore
prosperity based on economic fundamentals, not "bubblenomics."
Instead, the lack of fiscal discipline has undermined confidence that
policymakers will succeed in maintaining monetary discipline.
Inflation: The Unlegislated Tax
Other advocates of targeting higher inflation do so as a
consequence of the enormous budget deficits and the piling up of
unsustainable levels of national debt. Such advocacy reflects a
defeatist outlook with regard to the prospects for reaming to adequate
fiscal discipline. But, even if one is resigned to long-term fiscal
irresponsibility, public editorializing and blogging about the
desirability of greater inflation--at least compared to the alternative
policy options--dilutes their own case.
We know that it is unanticipated inflation that is an effective
tax, so denying the intent to reinflate while actually pursuing
inflationary policy actions would more effectively achieve their
purpose. We also know that a theoretical fully anticipated inflation can
never be achieved--especially because of the very large stock of
non-interest-bearing currency that is held by someone. However, the
degree to which individuals and businesses can take actions to protect
themselves from greater expected inflation reduces the effectiveness of
this type of taxation.
Lyndon Johnson deliberately chose inflation as the expedient way to
transfer resources to the government because he did not want Congress to
debate the merits of the Vietnam War versus the Great Society programs.
For President Johnson, the "tax no one has to vote for" was a
way to avoid the constitutional requirement that taxes had to originate
in the Ways and Means Committee of the U.S. House of Representatives.
Today, one motivation for advocating the inflation tax is that it
is a way to impose taxation on the very large share of the population
that is exempt from the income tax, while at the same time asserting
that a political pledge of "no tax increases for low-income
people" has been kept. This cynical cop-out will be successful in
forestalling fiscal disaster only to the extent that the public at large
is surprised by the timing and extent of the acceleration of inflation.
Proponents of higher U.S. inflation are either unaware or
unconcerned about the effects of debasement of the world's primary
reserve currency on other countries. As we saw in the highly
inflationary period of the failed presidency of Jimmy Garter in the late
1970s, the persistent appreciation of currencies that seek to maintain
low inflation compared to the United States creates political problems
in those other countries, especially the smaller open economies that are
heavily dependent on international trade.
No doubt some advocates of higher inflation recognize that current
foreign holders of longer-term government debt will suffer both capital
losses as interest rates rise and an erosion of purchasing power through
inflation, the same as domestic holders. I doubt that troubles them.
They may not understand that the resulting depreciation of the
international value of the dollar also will impose exchange translation
losses on foreign holders, both private and official. They might even
welcome such a tax imposed on foreigners--clearly a case of taxation
without representation. The inflation tax is not only dishonest, it is
regressive, divisive, and leaves us poorer as a nation.
Objectives of Monetary Arrangements
Elsewhere (Jordan 2006) I have written at length about the nature
of money and the role of government in the provision of money. I found
it interesting that two highly respected American leaders, James Madison
and Abraham Lincoln, had quite different views about government's
role in the provision of money. In the early 19th century debates about
national banks, Lincoln (1839) was clear in stating, "No duty is
more imperative on that Government, than the duty it owes the people, of
furnishing them a sound and uniform currency."
In contrast, Madison (189.0) thought the challenge was to provide
sound money in spite of government, saying,
It cannot be doubted that a paper currency, rigidly limited in its
quantity to purposes absolutely necessary, may be equal and even
superior in value to specie. But experience does not favor reliance on
such experiments. Whenever the paper has not been convertible into
specie, and its quantity has depended on the policy of the Government, a
depreciation has been produced by an undue increase, or an apprehension
of it [in Padover 1953: 292; see Dorn 1988: 90-91].
I interpret Buchanan (2010: 258) as coming down on the side of
Madison: "The Constitution remains the ultimate sovereign authority
rather than the government." Some 15 years earlier, Buchanan (1994:
4) warned, "It is in the monetary responsibility that almost all
constitutions have failed, even those that were allegedly motivated
originally by classical liberal precepts. Governments, throughout
history, have almost always moved beyond constitutionally authorized
limits of their monetary authority."
The debate about "rules versus discretion" in the conduct
of monetary policy is once again in vogue. My view is simple: Wherever
there is discretion in the conduct of economic policies whether monetary
or fiscal--there is moral hazard. Debate about the role of asset
prices--whether dot-com share prices or residential house prices--in the
formulation and implementation of economic policies will need to strive
for better consensus regarding the objectives of such policies.
No doubt in the years ahead we will also debate and probably test
the hypothesis that monetary policy is a fiscal instrument, a way to
finance government. If indeed the "fiscal dominance
hypothesis" is correct--a society that is unwilling or unable to
achieve fiscal discipline will not maintain monetary discipline--there
will be another financial crisis and another opportunity to implement
institutional constraints on policy discretion. For the debates to be
fruitful, the objectives must be clear.
Several decades ago Henry Wallich, a member of the Federal Reserve
Board, said that a place that tolerates inflation is a place where no
one tells the truth. He understood money in the same way the Framers of
the U.S. Constitution did when they gave authority over money to the new
U.S. Congress. Money is a part of a market economy's information
system; the meaning of a dollar should no more be subject to change than
the number of inches in a foot.
Whatever one thinks of the merits of a specie standard for
currency, Benjamin Franklin (1729) was clear in his reference to "a
Measure of Values," because the sentence giving Congress power over
money also assigns the fixing of weights and measures.
As much as I respect and admire Madison and others that gave us our
Constitution, I regret two instances where they used the word
"regulate" and I firmly believe they had something in mind
quite different from later usage. When they gave Congress the authority
to "regulate interstate Commerce," I am convinced that they
meant "to regularize." The sole purpose of the clause was to
ban the tariff and nontariff barriers that had surfaced among the states
under the Articles of Confederation; it was not to give the Federal
authorities vast control over everyday life of citizens.
The second use of the unfortunate term was "and regulate the
value thereof" regarding the money of the country. Here I am
convinced they meant "specify the units of money and the specie
content thereof." Jefferson preferred the name "dollar"
for the new national currency because a Spanish coin very familiar to
most people was called a "dolar." However, the weight of gold
in a unit of this new money was not the amount of gold in the Spanish
coins of the same name, but was the same as in a British pound. In other
words, the newly independent country would have money that had a
different name than the mother country, but would be equal in value.
In addition to the constitutional basis for seeking institutional
arrangements that provide a money of unchanging purchasing power, there
are strong economic arguments for doing so, as J. S. Mill suggested.
People choose to use as money that entity that economizes best on the
uses of real resources in gathering information about relative values
and conducting transactions. The productivity of money comes from the
liberation of these other resources so that they may be used to produce
the goods and services sought by consumers.
Honest money enhances knowledge about relative values of both goods
and assets, now and far into the future--this is the quality dimension
of money. The frequently referred to but little understood cost of
inflation is the loss of output over time resulting from deterioration
of the quality of money--that is, the reduced reliability of information
available about relative values of factors of production, goods, and
assets.
In societies where changes in money prices are contaminated by the
uncertain and changing purchasing power of money, false signals are sent
to businesses and households. Bad decisions are made, resources are
misallocated, and real incomes fail to rise at their potential rate.
Nominal interest rates respond to shifting expectations about the future
purchasing power of money. Changes in real interest rates are obscured,
so resources are misallocated. Since saving and investment decisions are
affected, growth is impaired. The notion that more employment and output
can be had with a bit more inflation must be soundly rejected.
Ludwig von Mises cautioned about the common misinterpretations of
terms such as inflation and deflation, as well as expressions such as
price level and price stability. Economists disagree about which
consumables to include in price indexes, the appropriate weights, and
which, if any, asset prices to include. However, economists can agree on
the conditions that would prevail in the absence of price-level changes.
Without price-level disturbances, businesses and households would make
all decisions based on the assumption that all price changes currently
observable or expected in the future are relative price changes--that
is, they reflect changes in the underlying real forces of demand and
supply. (1)
Relative price changes in a market economy are signals that
resources are better used by shifting away from lower- to higher-valued
uses. Similarly, when money is stable in value, higher real returns to
real productive capital are clearly reflected in market interest rates,
and not obscured by a changing inflation premium.
The most effective and efficient utilization of a society's
resources is achieved only when all participants in a competitive,
free-market economy can make decisions in the belief that the purchasing
power of money is neither rising nor falling. All price and interest
rate changes are then the result of shifts in the demand for or supply
of goods, services, and productive resources. These conditions yield the
greatest wealth and highest standards of living over time.
Whether one sides with Lincoln, arguing that it is the duty of
government to provide the nation with honest money, or one agrees with
Madison, holding that we must seek institutional arrangements that will
ensure honest money in spite of politicians, there should be no debate
about the objective of providing honest money.
Essentials of Monetary Reforms
A characteristic of flat money arrangements of the past century has
been asset price bubbles that ultimately burst and cause great economic
damage. Some historians assert that the motivation for establishing the
present monetary arrangements in the United States was to avoid repeats
of the 1907 banking panic and earlier episodes of financial instability.
If so, they have not been successful in meeting that objective.
We sometimes have been told that bubbles like the dot-com episode
in the 1990s are inevitable and that the best we can hope to do is
respond in ways that minimize the real economic consequences. We were
even told that it takes a new bubble to cure the problems caused by the
prior bubble. The fallout of the bursting of the housing price bubble of
the past decade showed that to be a mistaken prescription.
Some of the recent past episodes of boom and bust in the United
States and other flat money systems could have been dampened ff the
formulation and implementation of monetary policy actions had more
closely mimicked the rules of a true gold standard with a rule-based
lender-of-last-resort facility. I have written elsewhere (Jordan 2006)
about the implications of the permanent income hypothesis in conjunction
with a Wicksellian natural rate hypothesis in a world of productivity
surprises, and will not repeat those arguments here. However, an
important implication is that a "virtuous deflation"--declines
in prices of current outputs--should not be resisted by monetary
injections.
Relative prices of longer-lived assets versus shorter-lived goods
and services must be free to change. If economic forces are pressing
down on prices of goods and services, but monetary actions are geared to
prevent such declines, then asset prices will inevitably rise more than
otherwise. If misdiagnosed, bubbles occur. Even so, what is happening on
the liability side of household and business balance sheets determines
the extent of economic damage resulting from the decline of asset
prices.
The widespread damage to the U.S. economy in 2008-09 resulted from
the excessive debts incurred by American households. Those debts were
motivated by an institutional structure that encouraged subprime lending
and overconsumption of housing. In contrast, Canada--with its sound
mortgage practices and stable financial institutions--did not have
banking problems, business failures, unemployment, and other shocks to
their economy. Our emphasis should be on institutional arrangements that
will prevent another debt-default cycle.
While I am totally in favor of an end to government-sponsored
enterprises (such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac), more needs to be done
to avoid future crises. The root of the U.S. housing problem was the
passage of the Community Reinvestment Act during the failed presidency
of Jimmy Carter in the 1970s, as well as subsequent legislation and
regulation that led to overconsumption of housing. Those problems need
to be corrected.
Furthermore, as long as we continue to have managed fiat monetary
arrangements, we must at least establish some rules that constrain the
discretion in both formulation and implementation of policy actions.
With regard to objectives, we should seek legislation to replace
Humphrey-Hawkins--the Full-Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978,
which mandates simultaneous pursuit of both low inflation and low
unemployment--with the sole objective of price stability to safeguard
the purchasing power of money. Such an objective would not preclude the
movement of some index of current output prices moving inversely with
changes in productivity developments.
In order that discretionary pursuit of financial stability does not
interfere with the primary mission of monetary stability, legislation
should immediately establish strict rules for the lender-of-last resort
facility. While some financial intermediaries are too big to close, none
should be deemed too big to fail--that is, to wipe out equity holders
and unsecured creditors. In fact, bailouts of creditors of both
financial and nonfinancial firms should be banned by law.
In order to permit currency competition, including the eventual
development of private issuance of media of exchange, Congress should
legislate specific performance in contracts. Contracts denominated in
foreign currencies should also be enforceable. The monopoly money aspect
of legal tender laws inhibits innovation and is inconsistent with rights
of individuals and businesses to enter freely into legally enforceable
agreements.
A further step toward institutionalizing monetary discipline would
be to denationalize gold stocks and permit specie-backed privately
issued currencies to compete with domestic and foreign fiat currencies.
Our Daunting Challenge
The United States and other countries, as well as some local and
provincial governments, are now facing massive debt bubbles. Debts
incurred by any level of government are simply claims on future tax
receipts. When the nominal claims to streams-of-interest payments and
eventual return of principal exceed all reasonable expectations of
future tax revenues, it is a bubble--just as certainly as when
homeowners can no longer afford their mortgages.
Holders of the liabilities of governments expect to be repaid in
real purchasing power, even if return of principal is decades in the
future. Yet, they have contractual rights only to nominal units of fiat
money. Whenever the taxing authorities can no longer generate sufficient
nominal money units by imposing ever greater tax burdens on the assets,
labor, and enterprise of citizens, either default on debt or currency
debasement must occur.
Moving toward honest money--and away from discretionary government
flat money--is essential for future prosperity and freedom. Postponing
real reform will only delay the day of reckoning.
References
Buchanan, J. M. (1994) "Notes on the Liberal
Constitution." Cato Journal 14 (1): 1-9.
--(2010) "The Constitutionalization of Money." Cato
Journal 30 (2): 251-58.
Dorn, J. A. (1988) "Public Choice and the Constitution: A
Madisonian Perspective." In J. D. Gwartney and R. E. Wagner (eds.)
Public Choice and Constitutional Economics, 57-102. Greenwich, Conn.:
JAI Press.
Franklin, B. (1729) "A Modest Enquiry into the Nature and
Necessity of a Paper-Currency." (April 3). Available at
http://etext,virginia.edu/users/brock/webdoc6.html.
Jordan, J. L. (2006) "Money and Monetary Policy for the
Twenty-First Century." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review
(November/December): 485-510.
Lincoln, A. (1839) "Many Free Countries Have Lost Their
Liberty." Speech to the Subtreasury, Springfield, Ill. (December
26).
Madison, J. (1820) "Letter to C. D. Williams."
(February). In Padover (1953: 292).
Mill, J. S. ([1848] 1987) Principles of Political Economy. Reprint.
Fairfield, N.J.: Augustus M. Kelley.
Padover, S. K. (ed.) (1953) The Complete Madison: His Basic
Writings. New York: Harper.
(1) Naturally, if all price changes are relative price changes, for
every observed or expected rise or decline in some prices there must be
corresponding declines or rises in other prices (appropriately
weighted).
Jerry L. Jordan is former President of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. He served on President Reagan's Council of Economic
Advisers and the U.S. Gold Commission. He thanks Jim Dora and Denis
Karnosky for useful comments.