Limits of monetary policy in theory and practice.
Reinhart, Carmen M. ; Reinhart, Vincent R.
The Federal Reserve's conduct of monetary policy casts a spell
over market participants, commentators, and academics. The pages of
financial newspapers parse subtle differences among the comments of Fed
officials and delve deeply into potentially multiple meanings of
official statements. Academic discussions argue that the path of the
policy rate may (as in Taylor 2009) or may not (as in Bernanke 2010, and
Greenspan 2010) have fueled a home-price bubble in the United States.
The view that modest alterations to monetary policy have vast
consequences for national economies would seem to be inconsistent with
theory and evidence. Most modem economic models (represented
authoritatively by Woodford 2005) offer limited scope for policy
surprises. The basic logic is that spending depends on decisions
capitalized over the longer term, and small perturbations in the level
of the short-term interest rate do not matter much to those values. More
fundamentally, the prominence accorded to authorities controlling
nominal magnitudes seems to undervalue the resilience of market
economies, which are supposed to be efficient in grinding out
appropriate relative prices so as to employ resources efficiently. In
other words, if central bankers are crucial to moderating the operations
of capitalist economies, then capitalist economies may have serious
drawbacks.
We will argue that this fascination with the Fed is also at odds
with the evidence by taking a close look at the responses of asset
markets to changes in the short-term interest rate since the founding of
the Fed in 1914. In fact, there are no apparent effects on either
long-term interest rates or housing prices. We will also show that the
policy rate more recently had no systematic relationship with long-term
interest rates. A global view of capital markets casts doubt on those
arguing that a different policy path might have crucially mattered.
The conclusion is similarly wary of outsized expectations of
monetary policymakers and explains why pride goes before a fall.
Saying that modest changes in monetary policy would not matter much
does not imply that monetary policymakers are irrelevant. They can do
great ill by losing the story line and forgetting their role in
providing a stable backdrop of price stability. Small mistakes also
cumulate. Monetary policy was probably too easy from 2002 to 2006. It
was also too predictable, encouraging a short-termism in financial
markets, and was not sensitive to the dangers posed by a buildup of
credit. But were we able to walk back the path that the world took,
changes to supervision and regulation would most likely loom larger
still in shaping economic outcomes in the 2000s.
Limits of Monetary Policy in Theory
Two properties of most macroeconomic models are especially relevant
to the conduct of monetary policy. First, spending and pricing decisions
are assumed to be based on long-term assessments of real income and real
rates of return. Second, changes in monetary policy can change real
interest rates only temporarily. Ultimately, the forces of productivity
and thrift determine them, not changes in nominal magnitudes on the
central bank balance sheet. (1) Combining the two propositions implies
that the Federal Reserve's interest rate policy, as long as it
stays within the narrow range of experience, would not be expected to
have a significant or long-lasting imprint on markets or activity.
John Taylor (2009), among others, demurs in that view. In
particular, the Federal Reserve is held to have systematically run
policy too loose from around 2002 to 2006, which encouraged the housing
boom and file related financial market excesses. However, the deviations
from Taylor's preferred policy were modest. Such sensitivity of
outcomes to those misses is hard to square with the propositions that
the Fed can only keep the short-term real interest rate low for a
limited time and that it is long-term values that matter.
An example can make the point clearer. Finance theory posits that a
capital asset is valued as the present value of expected future income.
Such assets include homes, long-term government and corporate debt
instruments, and durable goods, but stock prices are file simplest to
model (as explained in Shiller 1989). With equities, the income comes in
the form of dividends, and the discount factor is the real short-term
interest rate plus a risk premium. According to the long-time series
already used and as shown in Table 1, from 1914 to 2006, the real
one-year risk free rate (using the one-year Treasury rate less the
year-ahead percent change in consumer prices as the proxy) averaged 1.27
percent, equities gave a return in excess of that of 7.11 percent, and
real dividends expanded 1.85 percent per annum. Calculating the present
value of equities at those historical averages is straightforward.
The entries of Table 1 assess how those present values change if
the real interest rate were 1 percentage point higher than its long-term
average. A permanent increase in real rates has a powerful negative
effect on capitalized values, ranging from - 13.3 percent (if the equity
premium matched its average) to -78.4 percent (if the equity premium
were zero). It is results such as these that create the perception that
the Fed has a powerful lever on the economy.
But the prior from theory is that the Fed's ability to raise
real interest rates is fleeting, at best. As is evident, fighter policy
that succeeded in raising real rates for as long as three years would
reduce the capital value of assets by only 1 to 3 percent. To view that
modest change as a source of policy leverage that could have
significantly influenced events of the past few years is to assume that
the economy is not well anchored by real phenomena.
Limits of Monetary Policy in Practice
If the Federal Reserve served a critical role in stabilizing the
economy, then presumably it should leave a systematic imprint in
financial markets. The data from Shiller (1989 and 2005) provide a
helpful resource for testing this proposition, giving long time series
on Treasury yields, equity and house prices, and consumer prices. Figure
1, from the Shiller dataset, plots annual observations on the 1-year
Treasury rate over the existence of the Federal Reserve, from 1914 to
2010.
We coded these observations, with year-on-year increases of more
than 0.25 percentage point representing a tightening, decreases of more
than 0.25 percentage point representing an easing, and variations in the
0.50 percentage point range bracketing zero representing no change. The
bars in the lower part of Figure 1 show the results, with the top bars
corresponding to tightening and the bottom bars to easing of monetary
policy. This simple rule accords surprisingly well with narrative
information of policy decisions. For instance, the dating from Federal
Reserve correspondence of the tightening cycle from 1988 to 1992 in
Reinhart and Simin (1997) matches the rule-based characterization. There
are about an equal number of easing and tightening episodes (20 of the
former mad 21 of the latter), which also about split up equally the
years of the Fed's existence. In about one-fifth of the years, the
policy stance did not differ materially from the year before. (2)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The five panels of Figure 2 show the cumulative frequency
distributions over the tightening and easing policy stances for nominal
short- and long-term yields and the 1-year realized nominal returns on
long-term Treasuries, the S&P 500 Composite equity index, and home
prices. (3) As is evident and reassuring to the policy identification
strategy, the tightening regimes (the solid lines) are associated with a
higher short-term rate than the easing regimes (the dashed lines). But
there are no significant differences in the outcomes for long-term
Treasuries and home prices. Equity markets do produce outsized returns
in tightening episodes. We may be observing the policy reaction function
of monetary policy restraint in a booming share market, not a changed
inducement to hold equities for different policy rates.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Asserting that monetary policy restraint would be associated with a
notable constriction of asset prices is evidently inconsistent with the
Fed's history. Of course, there are many problems associated with
categorizing outcomes. Keeping in mind the "post hoe, propter
hoe" argument made famous by Tobin (1970), the results are silent
as to causation. Additionally, a policy instrument guided optimally to
offset the effects of random and exogenous shocks of the goal variable
will not be correlated with the goal variable. But the variables shown
in Figure 2 are part of the transmission mechanism and intermediate to
the goal of monetary policy. That is, they are part of channels through
which policy affects the goal and apparently almost all systematically
unrelated to the stance of policy.
The Forgotten Open Economy
The lack of association between the stance of policy and key
financial market outcomes is not an artifact of our near-century-long
comparison. Consider the upper panel of Figure 3, which plots monthly
observations of the overnight federal funds rate, the 10-year Treasury
yield, and the rate on 30-year fixed-rate mortgages from 1972, around
the collapse of the Bretton Woods exchange rate system, onward. For the
first quarter-century of the sample, interest rates moved closely
together.
The two lines in the bottom panel plot the simple correlation of
the changes in the 10-year Treasury yield and the mortgage rate with
changes in the federal funds rate over a 5-year moving window. As is
evident, these correlations were typically close to one-half. In the
latter parts of the 1990s, something happened and these correlations
dropped off sharply. Indeed, for the whole of the period when it is
asserted that the Fed kept financial conditions too accommodative, the
policy rate and the most important market yield were negatively related
(see Greenspan 2010 for a related analysis).
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
There are many potential explanations for this lack of association
and the limited scope for the Fed to have sharply altered the course of
the past few years. The most plausible one to us is that analysts often
focus too intently on the domestic economy. Probably the most dramatic
set of events for emerging market economies in the late 1990s was the
Asian financial crises of 1997 to 1998. The crises were cathartic for
authorities in that region, who apparently as a result put a very high
premium on assuring a reliable export market by managing their U.S.
dollar exchange rates and building up foreign exchange reserves.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The result was a sharp pickup in reserve accumulation, shown for
emerging market and developing economies in Figure 4. The bars provide
the dollar amounts of annual additions to reserves, which peaked at
$1.25 trillion in 2007. As shown by the line, authorities in these
economies were willing to direct the equivalent of around 4 to 7.5
percent of their nominal incomes to reserve accumulation. Indeed, as the
housing bubble inflated from 2002 to 2006, these economies accumulated
$2.25 trillion of reserves or an average of 4.5 percent of their GDP.
Statistics from the International Monetary Fund indicate that about
two-thirds of those purchases were directed to U.S. dollar obligations.
(4)
This willing funding by foreign official accounts altered the
composition of finance and kept the level of long-term interest rates in
the United States low. First, as for the compositional effect, foreign
official entities loaded up on U.S. government securities, leaving
private demands unmet. Into this void, financial engineers constructed
AAA-rated dollar exposure by using housing collateral to create
mortgage-backed securities and collateralized-mortgage obligations. The
top tiers of those payment flows were rated by the rating agencies as
triple-A, meeting the need, particularly, of foreign banks that were
desirous of those securities' special treatment under the Basel II
capital rules.
This posed a problem for the investment banks that put in motion
the process of financial engineering. Underwriting these complicated
securities to meet the demand of foreigners for AAA-rated credit left
them with bits and pieces of securities on the cutting-room floor. This
unwanted residue of their own underwritings represented highly leveraged
bets on file U.S. housing market that proved difficult to remove from
their balance sheets.
The second main consequence of these global savings was to keep
U.S. long-term interest rates lower than they would have been otherwise.
Any analyst pointing to Federal Reserve policy as augmenting the housing
boom must first address how the Federal Reserve might have had the
leverage to do so. In the event, the simple correlation from 2002 to
2006 between its policy instrument and the rate that matters for housing
activity was negative and statistically insignificant from zero. This is
a simple, reduced-form, association between two interest rates that both
respond to and influence many other economic variables. It is possible
that all those other channels in the background happen to offset, on
net, a systematic effect of the policy rate on the market rate. But
perhaps not, or perhaps not in a manner than would have yielded
predictable results from policy changes.
Conclusion
In an open economy, the central bank has less scope to influence
the path of globally traded financial assets. Thus, the lack of
association between the stance of policy and the longer-term rates that
matter for spending--either broadly stated over the past century or
narrowly focused on the past decade--should not come as a surprise. This
does not, however, absolve the Fed from all responsibility.
The free flow of international capital irons out yield
differentials across world markets by facilitating the exchange of
financial obligations. Thus, signals from the market about domestic
imbalances are not in prices but rather in quantities. And there were
signals. In particular, the benign mortgage rate environment of the
2000s was associated with a marked scaling up of household liabilities.
As shown in Figure 5, the total liabilities of the U.S. household sector
rose about 25 percentage points of nominal income from 2002 to 2006,
virtually all of which was accounted for by mortgages.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
The leverage of households was rationalized at the time by the
strong equity component of balance sheets--the housing equity component.
The more than 20 percentage point decline in owners' equity (the
solid line) commencing in 2005 showed the fragility of those
underpinnings. As we demonstrated in Reinhart and Reinhart (2010), a
similar leverage cycle recurred in the 15 most severe financial crises
of the past century. (5)
The United States, by the way, was not alone. Figure 6 plots the
annual pairs of the growth of domestic credit and nominal GDP for 11
advanced economies from 2000 to 2009. About three-quarters of the
observations lie above the 45 degree line, implying sustained and
widespread reliance on leverage. This suggests another avenue that has
been unexplored by those criticizing Fed policy. Many other economies
had systemic banking crises and fell into recession. Some of them had
their own currency and an independent monetary policy (Iceland and the
United Kingdom), and some did not have their own currency (Ireland and
Spain) and had a monetary policy dictated by a foreign capital. How
could Fed decisions have been so central to all those shared
dislocations? Moreover, none of the major economies that exhibit a
"fear of floating" (as in Calvo and Reinhart 2002) and have to
keep their domestic monetary policies aligned with the Fed had systemic
banking crises. Why did the problems attendant to easy monetary policy,
asserted to be central to our imbalances, stop at our borders?
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The historical record does not provide a platform to support an
outsized role for the Federal Reserve in avoiding the financial crisis.
But as financial market prices tend to overshoot, so too do reputations.
The fall in the Fed's standing in the past few years owes
importantly to a correction of its buildup in the years before. In part,
the widespread belief that Fed policy contributed importantly to the
Great Moderation left its reputation vulnerable when the economy left
its sweet spot. After all, pride does go before a fall.
References
Akerlof, G., and Shiller, R. (2009) Animal Spirits. Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Bernanke, B. S. (2010) "Monetary Policy and the Housing
Bubble." Speech at the Annual Meeting of the American Economic
Association, Atlanta, Georgia. Available at
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bemanke20100103a.htm.
Calvo, G., and Reinhart, C. (2002) "Fear of Floating."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 379-408.
Geanakaplos, J. G. (2010) "Solving the Present Crisis and
Managing the Leverage Cycle." Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper
No. 1751.
Greenspan, A. (2010) "The Crisis." Brookings Papers on
Economic Analysis (Spring): 201-46.
Reinhart, C., and Reinhart, V. (2010) "After the Fall."
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Jackson-Hole Symposium.
Reinhart, V., and Simin, T. (1997) "The Market Reaction to
Federal Reserve Policy Action from 1989 to 1992." Journal of
Economics and Business 49: 149-68.
Shiller, R. J. (1989) Market Volatility. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT
Press.
-- (2005) Irrational Exuberance. New York: Broadway Books.
Taylor, J. B. (2009) "The Financial Crisis and the Policy
Responses: An Empirical Analysis of What Went Wrong." NBER Working
Paper No. 14631.
Tobin, J. (1970) "Money and Income: Post Hoc Ergo Propter
Hoc?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 84: 301-17.
Woodford, M. (2005) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of
Monetary Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
(1) Obviously, this is a source of debate among economists. We
follow the textbook presentation along the lines of Woodford (2005) in
which monetary policy has little if any, long lasting effect on real
variables. Akerlof and Shiller (2009) provide a stark counterpoint by
emphasizing confidence effects and market irrationality.
(2) An alternative identification scheme is to code unchanged years
as a continuation of tile prior stance. Nothing that follows would
change had we adopted that rule.
(3) Redoing the figure for real returns produces identical results.
(4) See Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserves
at www.imf.org/external/np/sta/cofer/eng/index.htm.
(5) Geanakoplos (2010) makes a forceful argument for recognizing
the importance of the leverage cycle.
Carmen M. Reinhart is the Dennis Weatherstone Senior Fellow at the
Peterson Institute for International Economics. Vincent R. Reinhart is a
Resident Scholar at the American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy
Research. The authors thank Adam Posen for helpful comments and Rohan
Poojara for his assistance.
TABLE 1
IMPACT OF CHANGES IN REAL INTEREST RATES ON
PRESENT VALUES
Change in Present Value (%)
Years for which the
real short-term Equity premium' is assumed to be:
interest rate is held
1 percentage point Average One-half
higher 1914-2006 the average Zero
1 -0.9 -0.9 -1.0
2 -1.8 -1.9 -1.9
3 -2.6 -2.7 -2.9
4 -3.3 -3.6 -3.8
5 -4.0 -4.4 -4.8
10 -6.8 -8.0 -9.3
permanent -13.3 -25.1 -78.4
Average from 1914 to 2006 (%)
Real short-term interest rate 1.27
Real growth of dividends 1.85
Dividend/price ratio 4.46
Equity premium' 7.11
* Equity premium is the short-tens real return on equity minus the real
short-term interest rate.
SOURCE: Shiller (1989, 2005) and authors' calculations.